Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-xfwgj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-25T16:53:27.791Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Is Competition or Collusion in the Product Market Relevant for Labour Markets?*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Fabian Bergès
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics (GREMAQ, INRA, IDEI); UMR 1291,21 Allée de Brienne, F-31000 Toulouse.
Get access

Summary

In non-union models, there is an ambiguous relationship between collusion on the product market and the resulting impact on the labour market. We can derive some conclusions by assuming a dual labour market with qualified and unqualified workers and taking into account the efficiency effect when employing qualified workers. The framework adopted here consists of two firms competing to hire workers on the qualified labour market, and then competing (or colluding) on the product market to sell their production. While qualified workers are heterogeneous in their specialization, firms sell imperfect substitute goods on the product market.

First, if the two firms collude in setting prices on the product market, this leads to an increase in the symmetric equilibrium wage in the qualified labour market, as well as a rise in productivity. Unions are not considered. Second, although the number of unqualified workers hired decreases along with the total employment, the wage bill can rise because of intensified competition on the qualified labour market.

Résumé

Résumé

Dans des modèles où les syndicats ne sont pas présents, le lien entre la collusion sur le marché des biens et son impact sur le marché du travail est ambigu. Considérer un marché dual du travail où se côtoient des ouvriers qualifiés et non qualifiés, en tenant compte de l'accroissement d'efficacité due à la présence d'ouvriers qualifiés dans la firme, permet d'éclairer ce lien et de tirer quelques conclusions. Le cadre d'analyse est composé de deux firmes qui sont en concurrence sur le marché du travail pour le recrutement d'employés, et qui sont en concurrence (ou en collusion) sur le marché des biens pour vendre leur production. Les employés qualifiés sont hétérogènes dans leur spécialisation. Les biens vendus sur le marché final sont imparfaitement substituables. Un premier résultat est que la collusion sur le marché des biens aboutit à un salaire d'équilibre symétrique plus élevé sur le marché du travail (en l'absence de syndicats). Deuxièmement, la collusion favorise le recrutement d'employés qualifiés : les firmes sont incitées à recruter des ouvriers qualifiés pour accroître leur productivité et bénéficier d'économies sur les coûts. Enfin, la collusion sur le marché des biens se fait aux dépens des travailleurs non qualifiés et de l'emploi total ; elle peut cependant augmenter la masse salariale.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 2008 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

We are grateful for remarks from EARIE (2003), Labour Seminar at the University of Warwick, Applied Economics Seminar at Inra-Toulouse (2003) and EALE (2004) participants. This article was finalized while Stephane Caprice was a visiting fellow at the Warwick University during the year 2004-2005.

References

Beffy, M., Buchinsky, M., Fougère, D., Kamionka, T. and Kramartz, F. (2006). “The Returns to Seniority in France (and Why they are Lower than in the United States)”, IZA Discussion Paper # 1935.Google Scholar
Bhaskar, V., Manning, A. and To, T. (2002). “Oligopsony and Monopsonistic Competition in Labor Market”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(2), pp.155174.Google Scholar
Blanchflower, D.G., Oswald, A.J. and Sanfey, P. (1996). “Wages, Profits, and Rent-Sharing”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), pp.227251.Google Scholar
Cahuc, P., Postel-Vinay, F. and Robin, J.-M. (2006). “Wage Bargaining with On-the-job Search: Theory and Evidence”, Econometrica, 74(2), pp.323364.Google Scholar
Combes, P-P. and Duranton, G. (2006). “Labour pooling, Labour poaching and Spatial clustering”, Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36, pp.128.Google Scholar
Davidson, C. (1988). “Multiunit Bargaining in Oligopolistic Industries”, Journal of Labor Economics, 6(3), pp.397422.Google Scholar
Fershtman, C. and Gandal, N. (1994). “Disadvantageous semicollusion”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12, pp.141154.Google Scholar
Fosfuri, A., Motta, M. and R∅nde, T. (2001). “Foreign direct investment and spillovers through workers’ mobility”, Journal of International Economics, 53, pp. 205222.Google Scholar
Fosfuri, A. and R∅nde, T. (2004). “High-tech clusters, technology spillovers, and trade secret laws”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22, pp.4565.Google Scholar
Gersbach, H. and Schmutzler, A. (2003). “Endogenous spillovers and incentives to innovate”, Economic Theory, 21, pp.5979.Google Scholar
Hamilton, J., Thisse, J.-F. and Zenou, Y. (2000). “Wage competition with heterogeneus workers and firms”, Journal of Labor Economics, 18(3), pp.453472.Google Scholar
Horn, H., Lang, H. and Lundgren, S. (1994). “Competition, long-run contracts and internal inefficiencies in firms”, European Economic Review, 38, pp.213234.Google Scholar
Horn, H. and Wolinski, A. (1988). “Bilateral Monopolies and Incentives for Merger”, Rand Journal of Economics, 19(3), pp.408419.Google Scholar
Irmen, A. (1997). “Note on duopolistic vertical restraints”, European Economic Review, 41, pp.15591567.Google Scholar
Lommerud, K.E., Straume, O.R. and S∅rgard, L. (2005). “Downstream merger with upstream market power”, European Economic Review, 49, pp.717743.Google Scholar
Lommerud, K.E., Straume, O.R. and S∅rgard, L. (2006). “National versus international mergers in unionised oligopoly”, Rand Journal of Economics, 37(1), pp.212233.Google Scholar
Manning, A. (2003). “The real thin theory: monopsony in labour markets”, Labour Economics, 10, pp.105131.Google Scholar
Mills, D. and Smith, W. (1996). “It pays to be different: endogenous heter-ogeinity of firms in an oligopoly”, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, pp.317329.Google Scholar
Naylor, R. (2003). “Economic Models of Union Behaviour”, in: Addison, J.T. and Schnabel, C. (eds), International Handbook of Trade Unions, Edward Elgar, chapter 2.Google Scholar
Nickell, S. (1999). “Product markets and labour markets”, Labour Economics, 6, pp.120.Google Scholar
Perrot, A. (2002). “Les frontières entre régulation sectorielle et politique de la concurrence”, Revue française d’économie, XVI(4), pp.81110.Google Scholar
Sattinger, M. (1993). “Assignment Models of the Distribution of Earnings”, Journal of Economic Littérature, 31, pp.831880.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J.A. (1962). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, New York: Harper Torchbooks.Google Scholar
Stewart, M. (1990). “Union Wage Differentials, Product Market Influences and the Division of Rents”, The Economic Journal, 100, pp. 11221137.Google Scholar
Symeonidis, G. (2005). “Collusion, Bargaining and Welfare”, Mimeo University of Essex.Google Scholar
Vives, X. (1989). “Technological competition, uncertainty and oligopoly”, Journal of Economic Theory, 48, pp.386415.Google Scholar
Wauthy, X. and Zenou, Y. (2000). “How the adoption of a new technology is affected by the interaction between labor and product markets?”, in: Norman, G. and Thisse, J-F. (eds), Market Structures and Competition Policy: Game Theory approaches, Cambridge University Press, pp. 271286.Google Scholar