Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-45l2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T16:26:23.772Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Untimely destruction: pestilence, war, and accumulation in the long run

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 January 2024

Clive Bell
Affiliation:
University of Heidelberg, Heidelberg, Germany
Hans Gersbach*
Affiliation:
KOF Swiss Economic Institute at ETH Zurich and CEPR, Zurich, Switzerland
Evgenij Komarov
Affiliation:
CER-ETH – Center of Economic Research at ETH Zurich, Zurich, Switzerland
*
Corresponding author: Hans Gersbach; Email: hgersbach@ethz.ch

Abstract

This paper analyses the effects of disease and war on the accumulation of human and physical capital. We employ an overlapping generation framework in which young adults, motivated by old-age provision and possibly altruism, make decisions about investments in schooling and capital. A poverty trap exists for a wide range of constant war losses and premature adult mortality. If parents are altruistic and the sub-utility function for own consumption is more concave than that for their evaluation of their children’s full income in adulthood, the only possible steady-state growth path involves full education. Otherwise, steady-state paths with incompletely educated children may exist. When mortality and destruction rates are stochastic, the initial boundary conditions and agents’ beliefs have a strong influence on the paths generated by a sequence of shocks. Calibrating the model to Kenya, simulations for stochastic settings yield the finding that a trap exists and is always avoided, but the chances of a slow recovery are substantial.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the Annual Growth and Economic Policy Conference, University of Durham Business School, 14–15 May, 2016, the UNU-WIDER Conference on Human Capital and Growth, Helsinki, 6–7 June, 2016, and the University of Durham Business School in 2020. We are grateful to the participants, especially Parantap Basu, for their constructive suggestions. We are also indebted to two anonymous referees and an associate editor for extensive and valuable comments, which have done much to improve the paper. We retain all responsibility for surviving errors of analysis and opinion.

References

Acemoglu, D., Gallego, F. A. and Robinson, J. A. (2014) Institutions, human capital, and development. Annual Review of Economics 6(1), 875912.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A. (2001) The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91(5), 13691401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. A. (2005) Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth. In: Aghion, P. and S. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, pp. 385472. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Aksan, A. M. and Chakraborty, S. (2014) Mortality versus morbidity in the demographic transition. European Economic Review 70, 470492.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Augier, L. and Yaly, A. (2013) Economic growth and disease in the OLG model: The HIV/AIDS case. Economic Modelling 33, 471481.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. and Sala-I-Martin, X. (1995) Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M. and Tamura, R. (1990) Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 98(5), 1237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, C., Bruhns, R. and Gersbach, H. (2006a) Economic Growth, Education, and AIDS in Kenya: A Long-run Analysis. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4025, October.Google Scholar
Bell, C., Bruhns, R., Gersbach, H. and Völker, D. (2004) Economic Growth, Human Capital and Population in Kenya in the Time of AIDS: A Long-Run Analysis in Historical Perspective. Universität Heidelberg.Google Scholar
Bell, C., Devarajan, S. and Gersbach, H. (2006b) The long-run economic costs of AIDS: A model with an application to South Africa. World Bank Economic Review 20(1), 5589. DOI: 10.1093/wber/lhj006.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bell, C. and Gersbach, H. (2013) Growth and enduring epidemic diseases. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(10), 20832103. DOI: 10.1016/j.jedc.2013.04.011.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Spiegel, M. M. (2005) Human capital and technology diffusion. In: Aghion, P. and S. Durlauf. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, pp. 935966. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Bhattacharyya, S. (2009) Unbundled institutions, human capital and growth. Journal of Comparative Economics 37(1), 106120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanning, T. (2008) The Pursuit of Glory: Europe 1648-1815. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Bloom, D. and Canning, D. (2000) Health and the wealth of nations. Science 287, 12071209.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bloom, D., Canning, D. and Sevilla, J. (2001) The Effect of Health on Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence. NBER Working Paper, No. 8587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bloom, D., Kuhn, M. and Prettner, K. (2019) Health and Economic Growth, Oxford Research Encyclopedias. Oxford: Oxford University Press. DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190625979.013.3.Google Scholar
Boucekkine, R. and Laffargue, J. P. (2010) On the distributional consequences of epidemics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34(3), 231245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakraborty, S. (2004) Endogenous lifetime and economic growth. Journal of Economic Theory 116(1), 119137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakraborty, S., Papageorgiou, C. and Pérez-Sebastian, F. (2010) Diseases, infection dynamics and development. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(7), 859872.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakraborty, S., Papageorgiou, C. and Pérez-Sebastian, F. (2016) Health cycles and health transitions. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20(1), 189213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, C. (2013) The Sleepwalkers: How Europe Went to War in 1914. New York: Harper.Google Scholar
Corrigan, P., Glomm, G. and Méndez, F. (2005a) AIDS crisis and growth. Journal of Development Economics 77(1), 107124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corrigan, P., Glomm, G. and Méndez, F. (2005b) AIDS, Human Capital and Growth. Bloomington: Indiana University.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crafts, N. F. R. (1984) Patterns of development in nineteenth century Europe. Oxford Economic Papers 36(3), 438458.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elga, A. (2010) Subjective probabilities should be sharp. Philosopher’s Imprint 10(5), 111.Google Scholar
Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. P. (2015) The next generation of the Penn World Table. American Economic Review 105(10), 31503182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O. (2005) From stagnation to growth: Unified growth theory. In: Aghion, P. and S. Durlauf. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1, pp. 171293. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silianes, F. and Shleifer, A. (2004) Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth 9(3), 271303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gori, L., Lupi, E., Manfredi, P. and Sodini, M. (2020) A contribution to the theory of economic development and the demographic transition: Fertility reversal under the HIV epidemic. Journal of Demographic Economics 86(2), 125155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gori, L., Manfredi, P. and Sodini, M. (2021) A parsimonious model of longevity, fertility, HIV transmission and development. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25(5), 11551174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G. M., Helpman, E., Oberfield, E. and Sampson, T. (2017) Balanced growth despite Uzawa. American Economic Review 107(4), 12931312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C. I. and Scrimgeour, D. (2008) A new proof of Uzawa’s steady-state growth theorem. Review of Economics and Statistics 90(1), 180182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. (2012) AIDS, “reversal” of the demographic transition and economic development: Evidence from Africa. Journal of Population Economics 25(3), 871897.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. and Turan, B. (2011) HIV and fertility revisited. Journal of Development Economics 96(1), 6165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keegan, J. (1990) The Second World War. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Keegan, J. (1998) The First World War. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Kenya. (2020) Kenya’s National HIV Survey Shows Progress Towards Control of the Epidemic. Nairobi: Ministry of Health. https://www.health.go.ke/kenyas-national-hiv-survey-shows-progress-towards-control-of-the-epidemic-nairobi-20th-february-2020/ (accessed 04 September 2021).Google Scholar
Kimalu, P. K., Nafula, N., Manda, D. K., Bedi, A. S., Mwabu, G. and Kimenyi, M. S. (2001) Education Indicators in Kenya. Kenya Institute for Public Policy Research and Analysis, Working Paper Series, WP/04/2001.Google Scholar
Lagerlof, N.-P. (2003) From Malthus to modern growth: Can epidemics explain the three regimes? International Economic Review 44(2), 755777.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D. and Weil, D. N. (1992) A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(2), 407437. DOI: 10.2307/2118477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, E. S. (2002) The fastest killer. The New York Review of Books February, 14, 2224.Google Scholar
O’Connell, S. A. and Ndulu, B. J. (2000) Africa’s Growth Experience – A Focus on Sources of Growth. Swarthmore College.Google Scholar
Pelinescu, E. (2015) The impact of human capital on economic growth. Procedia Economics and Finance 22, 184190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1997) Sources of slow growth in African economies. Journal of African Economies 6(3), 335376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlicht, E. (2006) A variant of Uzawa’s theorem. Economics Bulletin 5(6), 15.Google Scholar
Schmidt, G. (2002) Der Dreissigjährige Krieg, 5th ed. München: Beck.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uzawa, H. (1961) Neutral inventions and the stability of growth equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies 28(2), 117124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigtländer, N. and Voth, H.-J. (2009) Malthusian dynamism and the rise of Europe: Make war, not love. American Economic Review 99(2), 248254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigtländer, N. and Voth, H.-J. (2013) Gifts of Mars: War and Europe’s early rise to riches. Journal of Economic Perspectives 27(4), 165186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wan, H. Y. (1971) Economic Growth. New York: Harcourt, Brace, and Jovanovich.Google Scholar
WHO. (2007) World Health Statistics, 2007. Geneva: WHO. http://www.who.int/whosis/database/life_tables/life_tables.cfm Google Scholar
World Bank. (2007). The World Development Report, 2007: Development and the Next Generation. Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Young, A. (2005) The gift of the dying: The tragedy of AIDS and the welfare of future African generations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(2), 423466.Google Scholar
Young, A. (2007) In sorrow to bring forth children: fertility amidst the plague of HIV. Journal of Economic Growth 12(4), 283327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar