Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-q6k6v Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-10T22:54:15.215Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

DYNAMIC EFFECTS OF OIL PRICE SHOCKS AND THEIR IMPACT ON THE CURRENT ACCOUNT

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 March 2013

Stefan F. Schubert*
Affiliation:
Free University of Bozen-Bolzano
*
Address correspondence to: Stefan F. Schubert, Free University of Bozen-Bolzano, School of Economics and Management, Piazza Università 1, I-39100 Bozen-Bolzano, Italy; e-mail: StefanFranz.Schubert@unibz.it.

Abstract

We study the dynamic effects of an oil price shock on key economic variables and on the current account of a small open economy. We introduce time-nonseparable preferences into a standard model of a small open economy, where imported oil is used both as an intermediate input in production and as a consumption good. Using a plausible calibration of the model, we show that the changes in output and employment are quite small, and that the current account exhibits the J-curve property, both being in line with recent empirical evidence. After an oil price increase, employment falls and the current account first deteriorates. Over time, with gradually falling expenditures, the trade balance improves sufficiently to turn the current account into a surplus. The model thus provides a plausible explanation of recent empirical findings.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Agmon, Tamir and Laffer, Arthur B. (1978) Trade, payments and adjustment: The case of the oil price rise. Kyklos 31, 6885.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez-Cuadrado, Francisco, Monteiro, Goncalo, and Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2004) Habit formation, catching up with the Joneses, and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth 9, 4780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
lker Asche, Frank, Gjølberg, Ole, and Völker, Teresa (2003) Price relationships in the petroleum market: An analysis of crude oil and refined product prices. Energy Economics 25, 289301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkeson, Andrew and Kehoe, Patrick J. (1999) Models of energy use: Putty-putty versus putty-clay. American Economic Review 89 (4), 10281043.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, Alan and Kotlikoff, Laurence (1987) Dynamic Fiscal Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Backus, David K. and Crucini, Mario J. (2000) Oil prices and the terms of trade. Journal of International Economics 50, 185213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balke, Nathan S., Brown, Stephen P.A., and Yücel, Mine K. (2008) An international perspective on oil price shocks and U.S. economic activity. Working paper 20, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert J. and Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2003) Economic Growt., 2nd ed.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Barsky, Robert B. and Kilian, Lutz (2004) Oil and the macroeconomy since the 1970s. Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4), 115134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. (1985) Debt, deficits and finite horizons. Journal of Political Economy 93, 223247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. and Galí, Jordi (2010) The macroeconomic effects of oil price shocks: Why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? In Galí, Jordi and Gertler, Mark (eds.), International Dimensions of Monetary Polic. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bodenstein, Martin, Erceg, Christopher J., and Guerrieri, Luca (2011) Oil shocks and external adjustment. Journal of International Economics 83, 168184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardi, Olivier (2007) Another view of the j-curve. Macroeconomic Dynamics 11, 153174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D., Overland, Jody, and Weil, David N. (1997) Comparison utility in a growth model. Journal of Economic Growth 2, 339367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D., Overland, Jody, and Weil, David N. (2000) Saving and growth with habit formation. American Economic Review 90 (3), 341355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D., Slacalek, Jiri, and Sommer, Martin (2011) International evidence on sticky consumption growth. Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (4), 11351145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhawan, Rajeev and Jeske, Karsten (2006) How resilient is the modern economy to energy price shocks? Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Atlant. (Third Quarter), 21–32.Google Scholar
Edenhofer, Ottmar, Bauer, Nico, and Kriegler, Elmar (2005) The impact of technological change on climate protection and welfare: Insights from the model mind. Ecological Economics 54, 277292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elder, John and Serletis, Apostolos (2010) Oil price uncertainty. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (6), 11371159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. (2000) Habit formation in consumption and its implications for monetary-policy models. American Economic Review 90 (3), 367390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruber, Joseph W. (2004) A present value test of habits and the current account. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 14951507.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, James D. (1983) Oil and the macroeconomy since World War II. Journal of Political Economy 91 (2), 228248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, James D. (1996) This is what happened to the oil price–macroeconomy relationship. Journal of Monetary Economics 38, 215220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, James D. (2003) What is an oil shock? Journal of Econometric. 113, 363398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, James D. (2011) Nonlinearities and the macroeconomic effects of oil prices. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15 (Supplement 3), 364378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayashi, Fumio (1982) Tobin's marginal q and average q: A neoclassical interpretation. Econometrica 50, 213224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiménez-Rodríguez, Rebeca and Sánchez, Marcelo (2005) Oil price shocks and real GDP growth—empirical evidence for some OECD countries. Applied Economics 37, 201228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kemfert, Claudia (1998) Estimated substitution elasticities of a nested CES production function approach for Germany. Energy Economics 20, 249264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz (2008) A comparison of the effects of exogenous oil supply shocks on output and inflation in the G7 countries. Journal of the European Economic Association 6 (1), 78121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz, Rebucci, Alessandro, and Spatafora, Nikola (2009) Oil shocks and external balances. Journal of International Economics 77, 181194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kilian, Lutz and Vigfusson, Robert J. (2011) Nonlinearities in the oil price-output relationship. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15 (Supplement 3), 337363.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, In-Moo and Loungani, Prakash (1992) The role of energy in real business cycle models. Journal of Monetary Economics 29, 173189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansoorian, Arman (1998) Habits and durability in consumption, and the dynamics of the current account. Journal of International Economics 44, 6982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (1987) Current account dynamics in a finite horizon model. Journal of International Economics 23, 299313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mork, Knut Anton (1989) Oil and the macroeconomy when prices go up and down: An extension of Hamilton's results. Journal of Political Economy 97 (3), 740744.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakov, Anton and Pescatori, Andrea (2010) Oil and the great moderation. Economic Journal 120, 131156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, William (2007) Who's afraid of a big bad oil shock? Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2), 219238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2004) Oil price developments: Drivers, economic consequences and policy responses. In OECD (ed.), OECD Economic Outlook No. 76, available at http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/19/6/34080955.pdf, Ch. 9, pp. 1–29 (accessed Nov. 11, 2007).Google Scholar
Ortigueira, Salvador and Santos, Manuel S. (1997) On the speed of convergence in endogenous growth models. American Economic Review 87, 383399.Google Scholar
Papageorgiou, Chris (2008) Comment on “Unwrapping some euro area growth puzzles: Factor substitution, productivity and unemployment.'' Journal of Macroeconomics 30, 667670.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parry, Ian W.H. and Darmstadter, Joel (2004) The Costs of US Oil Dependency. Paper prepared for the National Commission on Energy Policy.Google Scholar
Rahman, Sajjadur and Serletis, Apostolos (2011) The asymmetric effects of oil price shocks. Macro-economic Dynamics 15 (Supplement 3), 437471.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rebucci, Alessandro and Spatafora, Nikola (2006) Oil prices and global imbalances. In IMF World Economic Outlook, Ch. 2, pp. 7196.Google Scholar
Ryder, Harl E. and Heal, Geoffrey M. (1973) Optimal growth with intertemporally dependent preferences. Review of Economic Studies 40, 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Serletis, Apostolos and Elder, John (2011) Introduction to oil price shocks. Macroeconomic Dynamics 15 (Supplement 3), 327336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sommer, Martin (2007) Habit formation and aggregate consumption dynamics. B.E. Journal of Macro-economics 7 (1), (Advances), Article 21.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2000) Methods of Macroeconomic Dynamics. 2nd ed.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2002) Knife-edge conditions and the macrodynamics of small open economies. Macroeconomic Dynamics 6, 307335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turnovsky, Stephen J. (2011) On the role of small models in macrodynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35, 16051613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van der Werf, Edwin (2008) Production functions for climate policy modeling: An empirical analysis. Energy Economics 30, 29642979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wei, Chao (2003) Energy, the stock market, and the putty-clay investment model. American Economic Review 93 (1), 311323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar