Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-sh8wx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T01:48:52.607Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Strategies of Constitutional Scholarship

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 December 2018

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © American Bar Foundation, 2001 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alt, James E., and Alesina, Alberto. 1996. Political Economy: An Overview. In A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Robert Goodin, E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aranson, Peter H., Gellhorn, Ernest, and Glenn Robinson, O. 1982. A Theory of Legislative Delegation. Cornell Law Review 68:167.Google Scholar
Baum, Lawrence. 1997. The Puzzle of Judicial Behavior. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1973. The Economics of Discrimination. Rev. ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Easterhrook, Frank. 1984. Forward: The Court and the Economic System. Harvard Law Review 98:460.Google Scholar
Ely, John Hart. 1980. Democracy and Distrust: A Theory of Judicial Review. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Lee, and Knight, Jack. 1998. The Choices Justices Make. Washington, D.C.: Congressional Quarterly Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard. 1985. Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, Richard 1987. The Proper Scope of the Commerce Power. Virginia Law Review 73:1387–455.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr. 1991. Overriding Supreme Court Statutory Interpretation Decisions. Yale Law Journal 101:331445.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr., and Ferejohn, John. 1992. The Article I, Section 7 Game. Georgetown Law Journal 80:523–64.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William N. Jr., and Ferejohn, John 1998. Statutory Interpretation and Rational Choice Theories. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, ed. Newman, Peter, 535–40.Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. 1991. Free Speech Without Romance: Public Choice and the First Amendment. Harvard Law Review 105:554–83.Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A. 1992. Economic Analysis and Just Compensation. International Review of Law and Economics 12:125–38.Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel A., and Philip Frickey, P. 1991. Law and Public Choice: A Critical Introduction. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Landes, William, and Richard Posner, A. 1975. The Independent Judiciary in an Interest, Group Perspective. Journal of Law and Economics 18:875901.Google Scholar
Letsou, Peter V. 1995. The Political Economy of Consumer Credit Regulation. Emory Law Journal 44:587677.Google Scholar
Levinson, Daryl J. 2000. Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs. University of Chicago Law Review 67:345420.Google Scholar
Macey, Jonathan. 1986. Promoting Public-Regarding Legislation through Statutory Interpretation. Columbia Law Review 86:223–68.Google Scholar
Mahoney, Paul. Forthcoming. The Political Economy of the Securities Act of 1933. Journal of Legal Studies .Google Scholar
McChesney, Fred. 1997. Money for Nothing: Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Matthew D., Roger Noll, G., and Barry Weingast, R. 1989. Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies. Virginia Law Review 75:431–82.Google Scholar
Miller, Geoffrey P. 1989. Public Choice at the Dawn of the Special Interest State: The Story of Butter and Margarine. California Law Review 77:83131.Google Scholar
Mueller, Dennis. 1996. Constitutional Democracy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. 1997. The Political Economy of the Bankruptcy Reform Act of 1978. Michigan Law Review 96:47126.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. 2000. The Evolution of Constitutions. Typescript.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. 1975. The Social Costs of Monopoly and Regulation. Journal of Political Economy 83:807–27.Google Scholar
Ramseyer, J. Mark. 1994. The Puzzling Independence of Courts: A Comparative Approach. Journal of Legal Studies 23:721–47.Google Scholar
Roin, Julie A. 1988. United They Stand, Divided They Fall: Public Choice Theory and the Tax Code. Cornell Law Review 74:62134.Google Scholar
Romano, Roberta. 1987. The Political Economy of Takeover Statutes. Virginia Law Review 73:111–98.Google Scholar
Spaeth, Harold J., and Jeffrey Segal, A. 1999. Majority Rule or Minority Will: Adherence to Precedent on the U.S. Supreme Court. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Strauss, David. 1996. Common Law Constitutional Interpretation. University of Chicago Law Review 63:877935.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1967. The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft. Western Economic Journal 5:224–32.Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1996. Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives. In A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Robert Goodin, E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar