Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-sh8wx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-19T06:54:16.100Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Libertarian Paternalism, Externalities, and the “Spirit of Liberty”: How Thaler and Sunstein Are Nudging Us toward an “Overlapping Consensus”

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 December 2018

Abstract

In their 2008 book Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness, Richard Thaler and Cass Sunstein use research from psychology and behavioral economics to argue that people suffer from systematic cognitive biases. They propose that policy makers mitigate these biases by framing people's choices in ways that help people act in their own self‐interest. Thaler and Sunstein call this approach “libertarian paternalism,” and they market it as “the Real Third Way.” In this essay, I argue that the book is a brilliant contribution to thinking about policy making but that “choice architecture” is not just a solution to the problem of cognitive biases. Rather, it is a means of approaching any kind of policy making. I further argue that policy makers must take externalities into account, even when using choice architecture. Finally, I argue that libertarian paternalism can best be seen as motivated by what Sunstein has celebrated in his work on constitutional theory: a humility about the possibility of policy‐maker error embodied in Learned Hand's famous aphorism about the “spirit of liberty” and an attempt to reduce social conflicts by searching for what John Rawls called an “overlapping consensus.”

Type
Review Essay
Copyright
Copyright © American Bar Foundation, 2011 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

References

Ando, Albert, and Modigliani, Franco. 1963. The Life Cycle Hypothesis of Saving: Aggregate Implications and Tests. American Economic Review 53 (1): 5584.Google Scholar
Arkes, H. R. 1991. Costs and Benefits of Judgment Errors: Implications for Debiasing. Psychological Bulletin 110 (3): 486–98.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth. 1971. Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing. Chicago: Markham Press.Google Scholar
Benartzi, Shlomo, and Thaler, Richard H. 2007. Heuristics and Biases in Retirement Savings Behavior. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (3): 81104.Google Scholar
Boadway, Robin F., and Bruce, Neil. 1984. Welfare Economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Browning, Edgar K. 1999. The Myth of Fiscal Externalities. Public Finance Review 27 (1): 318.Google Scholar
Bureau of Economic Analysis, US Department of Commerce. 2010. Personal Savings Rate. http://www.bea.gov/briefrm/saving.htm (accessed August 20, 2010).Google Scholar
Calabresi, Guido, and Melamed, Douglas. 1972. Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral. Harvard Law Review 85 (6): 1089–128.Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin, Issacharoff, Samuel, Loewenstein, George, O'Donoghue, Ted, and Rabin, Matthew. 2003. Regulation for Conservatives: Behavioral Economics and the Case for “Asymmetric Paternalism. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 151 (3): 1211–54.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D., Rhee, Byung‐Kun, and Rhee, Changyong. 1999. Does Cultural Origin Affect Saving Behavior? Evidence from Immigrants. Economic Development and Cultural Change 48 (1): 3350.Google Scholar
Cellan‐Jones, Rory. 2010. Facebook Reveals “Simplified” Privacy Changes. BBC, May 26. http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/10167143 (accessed August 20, 2010).Google Scholar
Chen, M. Keith, Lakshminarayan, Venkat, and Santos, Laurie R. 2006. How Basic Are Behavioral Biases? Evidence from Capuchin‐Monkey Trading Behavior. Journal of Political Economy 114 (3): 517–37.Google Scholar
Choi, James J., Laibson, David, Madrian, Brigitte, and Metrick, Andrew. 2002. Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Choices, and the Path of Least Resistance. In Tax Policy and the Economy, vol. 16, ed. Poterba, James M., 67113. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Choi, James J., Laibson, David, Madrian, Brigitte, and Metrick, Andrew. 2004. For Better or for Worse: Default Effects and 401(k) Savings Behavior. In Perspectives in the Economics of Aging, ed. Wire, David, 81121. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Cover, Robert M. 1986. Violence and the Word. Yale Law Journal 95 (8): 1601–29.Google Scholar
De Serres, Alain, and Pelgrin, Florian. 2003. The Decline in Private Saving Rates in the 1990s in OECD Countries: How Much Can Be Explained by Non‐wealth Determinants? OECD Economic Studies No. 36, 2003/1.Google Scholar
EPIC. 2010. EPIC Facebook Privacy. http://epic.org/privacy/facebook (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Farber, Daniel. 1997. Paradise Lost/Pragmatism Regained: The Ironic History of the Coase Theorem. Virginia Law Review 83 (2): 397428.Google Scholar
Fishhoff, Baruch. 1982. Debiasing. In Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, ed. Kahneman, Daniel, Slovic, Paul, and Tversky, Amos, 422–44. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L. 2006. Paternalism and Psychology. University of Chicago Law Review 73 (1): 133–56.Google Scholar
Gould, William, and Thaler, Richard. 1980. Public Policy toward Life Saving: Maximize Lives Saved vs. Consumer Sovereignty. NBER Working Paper No. 419.Google Scholar
Hand, Learned. 1960. The Spirit of Liberty. In The Spirit of Liberty: Papers and Addresses of Learned Hand, 189–91. New York: Knopf.Google Scholar
Hart, Henry M., and Sacks, Albert M. 1994. The Legal Process: Basic Problems in the Making and Application of Law. New York: Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Jenkins, Ray. 1994. Learned Hand and the Spirit of Liberty. Baltimore Sun. May 18. http://articles.baltimoresun.com/1994‐05‐18/news/1994138163_1_learned‐hand‐speech‐quoted (accessed August 23, 2010.Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine. Forthcoming. Governing America: The Emergence of Behavioral Law and Economics. Max Weber Lecture Series, European University Institute. Draft available: http://www.law.yale.edu/documents/pdf/Faculty/Jolls_TheEmergenceofBehavioralLawandEconomics1.pdf (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine, and Sunstein, Cass R. 2006. Debiasing through Law. Journal of Legal Studies 35 (1): 199241.Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R., and Thaler, Richard. 1998. A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics. Stanford Law Review 50 (5): 1471–550.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1979. Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk. Econometrica 47 (2): 263–91.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1976. Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication. Harvard Law Review 89 (8): 1685–778.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. New York: Harcourt, Brace.Google Scholar
Klick, Jonathan. 2010. Revealing Revealed Preferences. Cato Unbound: The Conversation. April 19. http://www.cato‐unbound.org/2010/04/19/jonathan‐klick/revealing‐revealed‐preferences (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Klick, Jonathan, and Mitchell, Gregory. 2006. Government Regulation of Irrationality: Moral and Cognitive Hazards. Minnesota Law Review 90 (6): 1620–63.Google Scholar
Koh, Benedict S., Mitchell, Olivia S., Tanuwidjaja, Toto, and Fong, Joelle. 2008. Investment Patterns in Singapore's Central Provident Fund System. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance 7 (1): 3765.Google Scholar
Komesar, Neil. 1994. Imperfect Alternatives: Choosing Institutions in Law, Economics, and Public Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Korobkin, Russell. 2009. Libertarian Welfarism. California Law Review 97 (6): 1651–85.Google Scholar
Korobkin, Russell, and Ulen, Thomas S. 2000. Law and Behavior Science: Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics. California Law Review 88 (4): 1051–144.Google Scholar
Larrick, Richard P. 2004. Debiasing. In Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making, ed. Koehler, Derek J. and Harvey, Nigel, 316–37. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence. 1999. Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Madrian, Brigitte C., and Shea, Dennis F. 2001. The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings Behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116 (4): 1149–87.Google Scholar
Mankiw, Gregory N. 2007. Principles of Economics. 4th ed. Mason, OH: Thomson/South‐Western.Google Scholar
McClure, Tim, and Spence, Roy. 2006. Don't Mess with Texas: The Story behind the Legend. Austin, TX: Idea City Press.Google Scholar
Minow, Martha. 1987. Interpreting Rights: An Essay for Robert Cover. Yale Law Journal 96 (8): 1860–915.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Gregory. 2002. Why Law and Economics' Perfect Rationality Should Not Be Traded for Behavioral Law and Economics' Equal Incompetence. Georgetown Law Review 91 (1): 67167.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Gregory. 2005. Libertarian Paternalism Is an Oxymoron. Northwestern University Law Review 99 (3): 1245–77.Google Scholar
New York Times. 2008. Transcript of the Third Presidential Debate. October 15. http://elections.nytimes.com/2008/president/debates/transcripts/third‐presidential‐debate.html (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Obama, Barack H. 2006. The Audacity of Hope. New York: Crown.Google Scholar
Parker, Jonathan A. 2000. Spendthrift in America? On Two Decades of Decline in the U.S. Savings Rate. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1999, ed. Bernanke, Ben S. and Rotemberg, Julio J., 317–70. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. 2003. The Uncertain Psychological Case for Paternalism. Northwestern University Law Review 97 (3): 1165–225.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1993. Political Liberalism. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Reidenberg, Joel. 1998. Lex Informatica: The Formulation of Information Policy Rules through Technology. Texas Law Review 76 (3): 553–93.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. 2002. Rationality and Freedom. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Singel, Ryan. 2009. Public Posting Now the Default on Facebook. Wired, December 9. http://www.wired.com/epicenter/2009/12/facebook‐privacy‐update (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Sloman, Steven A. 1996. The Empirical Case for Two Systems of Reasoning. Psychological Bulletin 119 (1): 322.Google Scholar
Stanovich, Keith. 1999. Who Is Rational? Studies of Individual Differences in Reasoning. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1995a. Democracy and the Problem of Free Speech. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1995b. Incompletely Theorized Agreements. Harvard Law Review 108 (7): 1733–72.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 1999. One Case at a Time. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2001. Republic.com. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2002a. Cost‐Benefit Analysis and the Regulatory State. Chicago: American Bar Association.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2002b. Risk and Reason: Safety, Law, and the Environment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2005. Radicals in Robes: Why Extreme Right‐Wing Courts Are Wrong for America. Cambridge, MA: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2008. On Avoiding Foundational Questions: A Reply to Andrew Coan. Stanford Law Review 60 (1): 241–46.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2009a. A Constitutional of Many Minds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. 2009b. Trimming. Harvard Law Review 122 (4): 1049–94.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R., and Thaler, Richard H. 2003. Libertarian Paternalism Is Not an Oxymoron. University of Chicago Law Review 70 (4): 1159–202.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. 2010. The Argument Clinic. Cato Unbound: The Conversation, April 16. http://www.cato‐unbound.org/2010/04/16/richard‐thaler/the‐argument‐clinic (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H., and Benartzi, Shlomo. 2004. Save More TomorrowTM: Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee Saving. Journal of Political Economy 112 (1): S16487.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H., and Sunstein, Cass R. 2008. Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth, and Happiness. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tom, Sabrina M., Fox, Craig R., Trepel, Christopher, and Poldrack, Russell A. 2007. The Neural Basis of Loss Aversion in Decision‐Making under Risk. Science, January 26, 515–18.Google Scholar
Ubel, Peter A. 2009. Free Market Madness: Why Human Nature Is at Odds with Economics—and Why It Matters. Boston: Harvard Business Press.Google Scholar
Wilkinson, Will. 2008. Why Opting out Is No “Third Way. Reason, October, 6469.Google Scholar
Wortham, Jenna. 2010. Glitch Brings New Worries about Facebook's Privacy. New York Times, May 5. http://www.nytimes.com/2010/05/06/technology/internet/06facebook.html (accessed August 23, 2010).Google Scholar

Statutes Cited

Uniform Commercial Code, section 2‐305.Google Scholar
Uniform Commercial Code, section 2‐306(1).Google Scholar
Uniform Commercial Code, section 2‐308.Google Scholar
Uniform Commercial Code, section 2‐309(1).Google Scholar