Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-sh8wx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-18T01:14:15.837Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

On the Contrivances required to render Contingent Reversionary Interests Marketable Securities

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 August 2016

Charles Jellicoe Esq.*
Affiliation:
Institute of Actuaries, &c

Extract

This subject has been so ably treated by Mr. Sang, in the paper transferred by Mr. Thomson’s permission to the pages of this Magazine, that it might seem almost superfluous to revert to it. Nevertheless, there are considerations connected with it which I believe to be of some importance, and which that gentleman has not adverted to; and I am therefore induced to submit the following remarks, by way of pendant to his observations :—

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Institute and Faculty of Actuaries 1852

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

page 161 note * The truth of the several formulæ given in this paper will be obvious on inspection, by bearing this in mind:—Thus, since the purchaser must always have interest on his capital for the year in which the death happens, the advance for £1 must not exceed v or 1–d; in this case, too, he must deduct p, the first year's premium; and since d is the interest upon 1–d, the annuity he should get for 1–dp is (d+p); so that £1 annuity is worth or ; that is to say, the sum to be assured, less the first year's premium and the last year's interest.

page 162 note * Here again the advance for £1 reversion is v or 1–d, in addition to which, the interest upon 1 – d during the life of A has to be provided for. The sum to be given is therefore 1–ddA, or 1–d (1 +A), or vdA.

page 162 note † Here the purchaser, for the same reason as before, must limit his advance for £1 to v; from which he has to deduct the first year's premium p, and the cost of an annuity to provide interest and premium—that is to say, of (d + p)—during the joint-lives. Hence the difference will be 1– dp – (d + p)AB, or 1 – (d + p) (1 + AB). He will thus receive interest, and have the means of paying the premium, while both lives are in being; and should A die first, he will get £1 = v + d, the total outlay, with interest upon it for the last year, from the estate; or should B die first, he will get it from the Assurance Office.

page 163 note * In this case, as in the foregoing ones, the advance must be limited to 1 –d; from which have to be deducted the first year's premium, and the cost of an annuity equivalent to the annual premium and interest, whilst both A and B are living. The sum to be given therefore for a contingent reversionary annuity of p + d, under these circumstances, woul d be 1–dp –(p + d) AB, or 1 – (p + d) (1 + AB). The purchaser would then receive his annuity of (p + d) so long as B is alive,—viz., from the Annuity Company whilst A is living, and from the estate should he die; and at B's death he would recover his capital as before, with interest for the year in which his death occurred. But if p + d annuity is worth 1 – (p + d) (1 +AB), £1 annuity is worth , or , as above given. In this expression, represents the sum to be assured; and in strict analogy with the former cases, is identical with that to be given for such an annuity, after deducting the first year's premium, the last year's interest, an d the sum required to provide both so long as the joint-lives are in being.

page 165 note * These are what may be called practicable rates. To assume ones less costly, or much less costly, would be to build on a false foundation!