Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T12:13:08.062Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Wicksell after Woodford

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Mauro Boianovsky
Affiliation:
Departamento de Economia, Universidade de Brasília, Brasília-DF, 70919–970, Brazil
Hans-Michael Trautwein
Affiliation:
Fak. II-VWL, Carl von OssietzkyUniversität Oldenburg, 26111 Oldenburg, Germany

Extract

The New Neoclassical Synthesis that Michael Woodford puts forward in his Interest and Prices (2003) is primarily a synthesis of New Classical and New Keynesian ideas. Yet Woodford presents it as an encompassing approach that goes much further back in time to integrate the pre-Keynesian macroeconomics of Knut Wickseil and his followers. Starting with the title, the book contains many references to Geldzins und Güterpreise (1898), Wicksell's landmark contribution to monetary theory which was translated as Interest and Prices in 1936. Woodford relates his concept of a “monetary policy without money” to Wicksell's concept of the pure credit system and to Wicksell's proposal to eliminate inflation by adjusting nominal interest rates to changes in the price level—an idea that has much in common with modern policy rules à la Taylor. He presents the core model of the new synthesis (in shorthand: IS + AS + Taylor rule) as a “neo-Wicksellian framework” that serves to analyze the dynamics of interest-rate gaps and output gaps (2003, chapter 4). Referring to the Wicksellians of the 1920s and 1930s (primarily Erik Lindahl, Gunnar Myrdal, and Friedrich A. Hayek), Woodford grounds his advocacy of rules to fight inflation on the potential non-neutrality of monetary policy: “[I]t is because instability of the general level of prices causes substantial real distortions—leading to inefficient variation both in aggregate employment and output and in the sectoral composition of economic activity—that price stability is important” (2003, p. 5). He thus sees his analysis of interest-rate and output gaps as “an attempt to resurrect a view” that the old Wicksellians had developed in their analyses of cumulative processes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth and Hahn, Frank (1971) General Competitive Analysis (San Francisco: Holden-Day).Google Scholar
Böhm-Bawerk, Eugen von (1889) Positive Theorie des Kapitals (Innsbruck: Wagner), translated as Positive Theory of Capital (London: Macmillan, 1890).Google Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro (1995) Wicksell's Business Cycle, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 2 (2), pp. 375411.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro (1998) Real Balances, the Price Level and the Unit of Account: From Wicksell to Patinkin and Beyond, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57 (4), pp. 579612.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro and Erreygers, Guido (2005) Social Comptabilism and Pure Credit Systems: Solvay and Wicksell on Monetary Reform, in: Fontaine, Philippe and Leonard, Robert (Eds) The “Experiment” in the History of Economics (London: Routledge), pp. 98134.Google Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro and Trautwein, Hans-Michael (2001) An Early Manuscript by Knut Wicksell on the Bank Rate of Interest, History of Political Economy, 33 (4), pp. 485516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro and Trautwein, Hans-Michael (2006) Price Expectations, Capital Accumulation and Employment: Lindahl's Macroeconomics from the 1920s to the 1950s, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 30 DOI: 10.1093/cje/bej003.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, Gauti and Woodford, Michael (2003) The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, no. 1, pp. 139233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodhart, Charles (2004) Review of M. Woodford (2003), Journal of Economics, 82 (2), pp. 195200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Frank (1988) On Monetary Theory, Economic Journal, 98 (393), pp 957–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich August (1929) Geldtheorie und Konjunkturtheorie (Vienna: Julius Springer), translated as Monetary Theory and the Trade Cycle (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1933).Google Scholar
Hicks, John (1946) Value and Capital, 2nd edition (Oxford: Clarendon Press).Google Scholar
Hicks, John (1989) A Market Theory of Money (Oxford: Clarendon Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howitt, Peter (1992) Interest Rate Control and Nonconvergence to Rational Expectations, Journal of Political Economy, 100 (4), pp 776800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindahl, Erik (1929) Penningpolitikens mål (Lund: Gleerups).Google Scholar
Lindahl, Erik (1930) Penningpolitikens medel (Lund: Gleerups) translated as Part II in: Studies in the Theory of Money and Capital (London: Allen & Unwin, 1939).Google Scholar
McCallum, Bennett (1986) Some Issues Concerning Interest Rate Pegging, Price Level Determinacy, and the Real Bills Doctrine, Journal of Monetary Economics, 17 (1), pp. 135–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautwein, Hans-Michael (1997) The Uses of the Pure Credit Economy, in: Cohen, Avi, Hagemann, Harald, and Smithin, John (Eds) Money, Financial Institutions and Macroeconomics (Boston: Kluwer), pp. 316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautwein, Hans-Michael (2000) The Credit View: Old and New, Journal of Economic Surveys, 14 (1), pp. 3771.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautwein, Hans-Michael (2004) The Loose Link: Hayek, Lindahl and Myrdal on Money, in: Bellet, Michel, Gloria-Palermo, Sandye and Zouache, Abdallah (Eds) Evolution of the Market Process: Austrian and Swedish Economics (London: Routledge), pp. 94113.Google Scholar
Walsh, Carl (2005) Interest and Prices: A Review Essay, Macroeconomic Dynamics, 9 (3), pp. 462–68.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1898) Geldzins und Güterpreise: Eine Untersuchung über die den Tauschwert des Geldes bestimmenden Ursachen (Jena: Gustav Fischer), translated as Interest and Prices: A Study of the Causes Regulating the Value of Money (London: Macmillan, 1936).Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1907) Krisernas gåta, Statsøkonomisk Tidskrift, 21 (3), pp. 255–84, translated as The Enigma of Business Cycles, International Economic Papers, 3 (1953), pp. 58–74.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1911) Böhm-Bawerk's Theory of Capital, in: Lindahl, Erik (Ed.) Knut Wicksell—Selected Papers on Economic Theory (London: Allen & Unwin) 1958, pp. 176–85.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1915) Föreläsningar i nationalekonomi, II, 2nd ed. (Stockholm: Fritzes Hofbokhandel), translated as Lectures on Political Economy, Vol. II (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1935).Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1919) Riksbanken och Privatbankerna, Ekonomisk Tidskrift, 21 (2), pp. 177–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1922) Vorlesungen über Nationalökonomie, Band 2 (Jena: Gustav Fischer).Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar