Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-skm99 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T18:07:34.163Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

FROM THE ACCOUNTS OF PHILOSOPHIE RURALE TO THE PHYSIOCRATIC TABLEAU: FRANÇOIS QUESNAY AS A PRECURSOR OF NATIONAL ACCOUNTING

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 January 2021

Abstract

François Quesnay’s Tableau, as it appears in Philosophie rurale, is an understandable, robust, and innovative construction despite detail errors. It provides a precise representation of the economic circuit. We introduce the accounts of chapter VII of Philosophie rurale and we explain how Quesnay’s Tableau comes from these accounts. The transposition of the accounts of chapter VII and of the Tableau into two input-output tables shows the balance of resources and uses. In order to shed light on the progress of exchanges along the year, the Tableau is also transposed into three double-entry accountings (proprietors, farmers, and artisans).

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The History of Economics Society, 2021

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Romuald Dupuy: Université de Poitiers; Pierre Le Masne: Université de Poitiers; Philippe Roman: ICHEC Brussels. The authors thank Gabriel Sabbagh (University Paris-Diderot), Séverine Sudron, and Jean-Pierre Tisseur (University of Poitiers), and Françoise Le Masne. The content of the article remains the sole responsibility of the authors.

References

REFERENCES

Barna, Tibor. 1975. “Quesnay’s Tableau in Modern Guise.” Economic Journal 85: 485496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1973. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Second edition. London: Heineman.Google Scholar
Butré[Richard de], Charles. 1759. Essai sur l’administration des terres. Paris: Hérissant.Google Scholar
Butré[Richard de], Charles. 1767. “De la grande et de la petite culture.” Éphémérides du citoyen, t. 9, pp. 581; t. 10, p. 73–134.Google Scholar
Butré[Richard de], Charles. 1781. Loix naturelles de l’agriculture et de l’ordre social. Neuchatel: Société typographique.Google Scholar
Dupuy, Romuald, and Le Masne, Pierre. 2014. “Présentation de la Philosophie rurale .” In Mirabeau, François Quesnay, and [Richard de], Charles Butré, Philosophie rurale ou Economie générale et politique de l’agriculture. Re-edition of the 1763 in-4to edition. Geneva: Slatkine, pp. 935.Google Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 1996. “The Grand Tableau of François Quesnay’s Economics.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 3: 2143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 1998. “The Harrod-Domar Equation from Quesnay to Marx to Harrod and Domar.” In Rampa, Giorgo, Stella, Luciano, and Thirlwall, Anthony, eds., Economic Dynamics, Trade and Growth: Essays on Harrodian Themes. London: Macmillan, pp. 1137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eltis, Walter. 2002. “How Quesnay’s Tableau Économique Offered a Deeper Analysis of the Predicament of France.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24: 3953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gehrke, Christian, and Kurz, Heinz. 1995. “Karl Marx on Physiocracy.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 2: 5390.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlitz, Lars. 1961. “The Tableau économique and the Doctrine of Sterility.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 9: 121150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlitz, Lars. 1996. “From Spending and Reproduction to Circuit Flow and Equilibrium: The Two Conceptions of Tableau économique.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 3: 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuczynski, Marguerite, and Meek, Ronald. 1972. Quesnay’s Tableau Économique. London: Macmillan; New York: Augustus Kelley.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Le Masne, Pierre. 2016. “Tableau de Quesnay et Tableau de Leontief.” Cahiers d’Économie politique 71: 3164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leontief, Wassily. 1941. The Structure of the American Economy 1919–1929. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1972. “Aus der kritischen Geschichte.” In Engels, Friedrich, ed., Anti-Dühring, ch. X, Marx-Engels-Werke . Volume 20. Berlin: Karl Dietz Verlag, pp. 210238.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 2000. Theorien über den Mehrwert . Marx-Engels Werke. Volume 26.1. Berlin: Karl Dietz Verlag.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl, and Engels, Friedrich. 1964. Briefwechsel zwischen Marx und Engels Januar 1860–September 1864 . Marx-Engels-Werke. Volume 30. Berlin: Karl Dietz Verlag.Google Scholar
Meek, Ronald. 1963. The Economics of Physiocracy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Menegatti, Matteo. 2018. “Bon Prix, Profit and Capital Accumulation in Quesnay.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 40 (1): 23–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milanovic, Branko. 2015. “The Level and Distribution of Income in Mid-Eighteenth-Century France according to François Quesnay.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31 (1): 1737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riqueti Victor, marquis de], and Quesnay, François. 1760. Théorie de l’impôt. Google Scholar
Riqueti Victor, marquis de], and Quesnay, François. 1767. Elémens de la Philosophie rurale. La Haye: Les Libraires associés.Google Scholar
Riqueti Victor, marquis de], Quesnay, François, and [Richard de], Butré, Charles. 1763. Philosophie rurale ou Economie générale et politique de l’agriculture. Amsterdam: Les Libraires associés, in-4to.Google Scholar
Riqueti Victor, marquis de], and Quesnay, François. 2014. Philosophie rurale ou Economie générale et politique de l’agriculture. Re-edition of the 1763 in-4to edition by Dupuy, Romuald and Le Masne, Pierre. Geneva: Slatkine.Google Scholar
Perrot, Jean-Claude. 1992. Une histoire intellectuelle de l’économie politique. Paris: Éditions de l’EHESS.Google Scholar
Philipps, Almarin. 1955. “The Tableau Economique as a Simple Leontief Model.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 137144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pressman, Steven. 1994. Quesnay’s Tableau Économique: A Critique and Reassessment. Fairfield: Augustus Kelley.Google Scholar
Quesnay, François. 1767–68. Physiocratie, ou constitution naturelle du gouvernement le plus avantageux au genre humain. Two volumes. Edited by Du Pont, Pierre-Samuel. Leyde and Paris: Merlin.Google Scholar
Quesnay, François. 2005. Œuvres Économiques complètes et autres textes. Edited by Théré, Christine, Charles, Loïc, and Perrot, Jean-Claude. Paris: INED.Google Scholar
Sabbagh, Gabriel. 2015. “The Philosophie rurale of Quesnay, Mirabeau, and Butré, after 250 Years.” Contributions to Political Economy 34: 105124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul. 1982. “Quesnay’s ‘Tableau Economique’ as a Theorist Would Formulate It Today.” In Bradley, Ian and Howard, Michael, eds., Classical Marxian Political Economy. London: Macmillan, pp. 4878.Google Scholar
Schmalz, Théodore. 1826. Economie Politique. Paris: Arthus Bertrand.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1776] 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Volume 1. Edited by Campbell, Richard and Skinner, Andrew. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sraffa, Piero. 1960. Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Studenski, Paul. 1958. The Income of Nations. Part I . New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Steenge, Albert, and van den Berg, Richard. 2007. “Transcribing the Tableau Économique: Input-Output à la Quesnay.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 29 (3): 331358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Touzery, Mireille. 1994. L’invention de l’impôt sur le revenu : la taille tarifée 1715–1789. Paris: Ministère de l’Économie.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1988. Éléments d’Économie politique pure. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar