Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-45l2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T19:28:52.969Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE ECONOMISTS OF THE LOST CAUSE AND THE MONETARY EDUCATION OF JOHN R. COMMONS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 April 2014

J. Dennis Chasse*
Affiliation:
School of Business Administration and Economics, State University of New York at Brockport, USA. Email: jchasse@brockport.edu

Abstract

Wild price swings following World War I motivated some economists and their allies to start a stable money campaign. John R. Commons joined this campaign, and the story of his participation opens a window into an historical learning episode in which the campaign, though it failed, sparked intellectual efforts and interacted with events in ways that changed beliefs about relations between central bank actions, on the one hand, and unemployment, inflation, and economic growth, on the other. The paper dwells on Commons’ role and on the long learning experience that led participants to conclusions they could not have anticipated when they embarked on their campaign.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Blaas, W. 1982. “Institutional Analysis of Stagflation.” Journal of Economic Issues 16 (4): 955975.Google Scholar
Barber, W. 1996. Designs Within Disorder: Franklin Roosevelt, the Economists, and the Shaping of American Economic Policy, 1933–1945. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barsky, R. B., and Killian, L.. 2000. “A Monetary Explanation of the Great Stagflation.” NBER Working Paper 7547. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Berg, C., and Jonung, L.. 1999. “Pioneering Price Level Targeting: The Swedish Experience 1931–1937.” Journal of Monetary Economics 43 (3): 525551.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M., and Watson, M.. 1997. “Systematic Monetary Policy and the Effects of Oil Price Shock.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 72 (1): 91157.Google Scholar
Blinder, A. 2010. “How Central Should the Central Bank Be?Journal of Economic Literature 48, 1 (March): 123133.Google Scholar
Cassel, G. [1932] 1967. The Theory of Social Economy. Revised edition. Translated by Barron, R. L.. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Cassel, G. [1922] 1972. Money and Foreign Exchange After 1914. New York: Arno Press.Google Scholar
Chandler, L. V. 1958. Benjamin Strong: Central Banker. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1893a. “What Should Congress Do About Money?Review of Reviews 7 (August): 153.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1893b. “Bullion Notes and an Elastic Currency.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science (September): 99101.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1908. “Tariff Revision and Protection of American Labor.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 32 (September): 315320.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1923a. “Price Level Changes through Changes in the Rate of Discount and Rediscount.” In John R. Commons Papers. Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin (microfilm edition), Reel 10.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1923b. “Bank Credit. ” In John R. Commons Papers. Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin (microfilm edition), Reel 10.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1923c. “Inflation and Deflation.” In John R. Commons Papers. Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin (microfilm edition), Reel 10.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1925. “Stabilization of Prices and Business.” American Economic Review 15 (1): 4352.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. [1927] 1997. “Price Stabilization and the Federal Reserve System.” The Annalist 29: 459462. In Rutherford, Malcolm and Samuels, Warren, eds. John R Commons Selected Essays. Frankfort, KY: Routledge: II, 386396.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1928a. “Farm Prices and the Value of Gold I.” North American Review 225 (839): 2741.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1928b. “Farm Prices and the Value of Gold II.” North American Review 225 (849): 196211.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1950. Collective Action. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. [1934] 1964. Myself. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. [1924] 1974. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. Clifton, NJ: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Commons, John R 1982. John R. Commons Papers (microfilm edition). Madison, WI: State Historical Society of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. [1934b] 1990. Institutional Economics. New Brunswick, NJ, and London: Transaction Press.Google Scholar
Commons, John R., and Andrews, John B.. 1916. Principles of Labor Legislation. New York and London: Harper Brothers.Google Scholar
Davis, J. 1971. The New Economics and the Old Economists. Ames, IA: Iowa State University.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression 1919–1939. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Feldstein, M. 2010. “What Powers for the Fed?Journal of Economic Literature 48, 1 (March): 134145.Google Scholar
Fisher, I. 1932. Booms and Depressions: Some First Principles. New York: Adelphi.Google Scholar
Fisher, I., and Cohrssen, H.. 1934. Stable Money: A History of the Movement. New York: Adelphi Company.Google Scholar
Greider, William. 1989. The Secrets of the Temple. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. 1974. The Crisis in Economic Theory. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Johnson, Simon. 2012. “Opening up the Fed.” New York Times, February 23, 2012. Economix.blogs.nytimes.com.2012/02/23. Accessed February 29, 2012.Google Scholar
Kahn, George A. 2009. “Beyond Inflation Targeting: Should Central Banks Target the Price Level?Economic Review (Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City) 94 (3): 3564.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1976Inflation and Recession in the World Economy.” Economic Journal 86, 344 (December): 703714.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, C. P. 1984. A Financial History of Western Europe. London: George Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Knapp, G. F. [1924] 1973. The State Theory of Money. Clifton, NJ: A. M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Meltzer, A. H. 2003. History of the Federal Reserve, Volume I: 1913–1951. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. 1975. John Maynard Keynes. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Minsky, H. 1986. Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Moggridge, D., ed. 1981. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes. London: Cambridge University Press for the Royal Economic Society.Google Scholar
Peterson, W. 1982. “Worker Discontent, Wages, and Stagflation.” Journal of Economic Issues 16 (4): 977984.Google Scholar
Ramstad, Y. 1987. “Free Trade versus Fair Trade: Import Barriers as a Problem of Reasonable Value.” Journal of Economic Issues 21, 1 (March): 532.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1972. “The Second Crisis in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 62 (2): 110.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, R. 1992. John Maynard Keynes, Volume 2: The Economist as Saviour. London: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Stone, N. I. 1945. “The Beginnings of the National Bureau of Economic Research.” In The National Bureau’s First Quarter Century. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, pp. 511.Google Scholar
Strong, B. 1930. Interpretations of Federal Reserve Policy in the Speeches and Writings of Benjamin Strong. Edited by Burgess, W. Randolph. London and New York: Harper Brothers.Google Scholar
Tymoigne, Eric. 2003. “Keynes and Commons on Money.” Journal of Economic Issues 37 (3): 527545.Google Scholar
U.S. House of Representatives. 1927. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency of the House of Representatives 69th Congress, 1st Session on H.R, 7895 February 4, 1927.Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. http://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt?id=mdp.39015038790534. Accessed May 7, 2012.Google Scholar
U.S. House of Representatives. 1928. Hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency of the House of Representatives, 1928. 70th Congress, 1st Session on H.R, 11806. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office. http://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt?u=1&num=22&seq=9&view=image&size=100&id=mdp.39015038790559. Accessed May 17, 2012.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. [1898, 1936] 1962. Interest and Price. Translated by Kahn, R. F.. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Whalen, Charles J. 1992. “John R. Commons and Endogenous Money: A Comment on Niggle.” Journal of Economic Issues 26 (2): 904907.Google Scholar
Whalen, Charles J. 1993. “Saving Capitalism by Making it Good: The Monetary Economics of John R. Commons.” Journal of Economic Issues 27 (4): 11551179.Google Scholar
Whalen, Charles J. 2008. “John R. Commons and John Maynard Keynes on Economics, History, and Policy: The 1920s and Today.” Journal of Economic Issues 42 (1): 225242.Google Scholar
Woodburn, James A. 1893. “The Present Aspect of the Money Question.” Indiana Student (November 21). Cited in Dorfman, Joseph. 1949. The Economic Mind in American Civilization. Vol. 3. New York: Viking Press, p. xxxix, n5.Google Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1982. “The Mysterious Career of Walter W. Stewart 1922–1930.” History of Political Economy 14 (4): 583607.Google Scholar
Yohe, William P. 1990. “The Intellectual Milieu at the Federal Reserve Board in the 1920s.” History of Political Economy 22 (3): 465488.Google Scholar