Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-qxdb6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T09:07:55.780Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Estimating the social value of higher education: willingness to pay for community and technical colleges

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 May 2015

Paul A. Coomes
Affiliation:
Emeritus in the Department of Economics, College of Business, University of Louisville, Louisville, KY 40292, USA
Christopher Jepsen
Affiliation:
School of Economics and the Geary Institute, University College Dublin, Newman Building, Belfield, Dublin 4, Ireland
Brandon C. Koford
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Weber State University, Ogden, UT 84408-3807, USA
Kenneth R. Troske
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Gatton College of Business and Economics Building, University of Kentucky, Lexington, KY 40506-0034, USA
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract:

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Much is known about private financial returns to education in the form of higher earnings. Less is known about how much social value exceeds this private value. Associations between education and socially-desirable outcomes are strong, but disentangling the effect of education from other causal factors is challenging. The purpose of this paper is to estimate the social value of one form of higher education. We elicit willingness to pay for the Kentucky Community and Technical College System (KCTCS) directly and compare our estimate of total social value to our estimates of private value in the form of increased earnings. Our earnings estimates are based on two distinct data sets, one administrative and one from the U.S. Census. The difference between the total social value and the increase in earnings is our measure of the education externality and the private, non-market value combined. Our work differs from previous research by focusing on education at the community college level and by eliciting values directly through a stated-preferences survey in a way that yields a total value including any external benefits. Our preferred estimates indicate the social value of expanding the system exceeds private financial value by at least 25% with a best point estimate of nearly 90% and exceeds total private value by at least 15% with a best point estimate of nearly 60%.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2014

References

Acemoglu, D., & Angrist, J. (2000). How large are the social returns to education? Evidence from compulsory schooling laws. In Bernanke, B. S. & Rogoff, K. (Eds.), NBER Macroannual 15 (pp. 959). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. J., Solow, R., Portney, P., Leamer, E. E., Radner, R., & Howard, S. (1993). Report on the NOAA panel on contingent valuation. In Federal Register (Vol. 58, Iss. 10, pp. 46024614). Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. M. (2007). Education and consumption: the effects of education in the household compared to the marketplace. Journal of Human Capital, 1(1), 935.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blomquist, G. C., Coomes, P. A., Jepsen, C., Koford, B., Kornstein, B., & Troske, K. R. (2007). The individual, regional, and state economic impacts of Kentucky community and technical colleges. Center for Business and Economic Research, University of Kentucky, http://cber.uky.edu/pdf/CBER_UL_KCTCSReport_10-2007.pdf.Google Scholar
Blumenschein, K., Johannesson, M., Blomquist, G., Liljas, B., & O’Conor, R. (1997). Hypothetical versus real payments in Vickery auctions. Economics Letters, 56(2), 177180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blumenschein, K., Johannesson, M., Blomquist, G., Liljas, B., & O’Conor, R. (1998). Experimental results on expressed certainty and hypothetical bias in contingent valuation. Southern Economic Journal, 65(1), 169177.Google Scholar
Blumenschein, K., Blomquist, G. C., Johannesson, M., Horn, N., & Freeman, P. R. (2008). Eliciting willingness to pay without bias: Evidence from a field experiment. The Economic Journal, 118(525), 114137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boardman, A. E., Greenberg, D. H., Vining, A. R., & Weimer, D. L. (2011). Cost-benefit analysis: concepts and practice. (4th ed.). Boston: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Cain, T. (2011). Individual income tax returns, by state, 2007. Statistics of Income Bulletin, 30(1), 174234.Google Scholar
Card, D. (1999). The causal effect of education on earnings. In Ashenfelter, O. C. & Card, D. (Eds.), The handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3A, pp. 18011863). New York: Elsevier Science, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Carson, R. T., (2012). Contingent valuation: a practical alternative when prices aren’t available. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 2742.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carson, R. T., & Groves, T. (2007). Incentives and informational properties of preference questions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 37(1), 181210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Champ, P. A., & Bishop, R. C. (2001). Donation payment mechanisms and contingent valuation: An empirical study of hypothetical bias. Environmental and Resource Economics, 19(4), 383402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
College Board (2008). Winning the skills race and strengthening America’s middle class: an action agenda for community colleges. New York: College Board. http://professionals.collegeboard.com/profdownload/winning_the_skills_race.pdf.Google Scholar
Cummings, R. G. & Taylor, L. O. (1999). Unbiased value estimates for environmental goods: a cheap talk design for the contingent valuation method. American Economic Review, 89(3), 649665.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cutler, D. M. & Lleras-Muney, A. (2008). Education and health: Evaluating theories and evidence. In House, J., Schoeni, R., Kaplan, G. & Pollack, H. (Eds.), Making Americans healthier: social and economic policy as health policy (pp. 2960). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Dee, T. S. (2004). Are there civic returns to education? Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10), 16971720.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demming, D. (2011). Better schools, less crime. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(4), 20632115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, R. A. (2003). The regrettable necessity of contingent valuation. Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3), 259274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Glaeser, E. L. & Saks, R. E. (2006). Corruption in America. Journal of Public Economics, 90(6-7), 10531072.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, M. (2006). Education and nonmarket outcomes. In Hanushek, E. & Welch, F. (Eds.) The handbook of economics of education (Vol. 1, pp. 577633). Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Hanushek, E. A., Yui Leung, C. K., & Yilmaz, K. (2003). Redistribution through education and other transfer mechanisms. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(8), 17191750.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrison, G. W. (2006). Experimental evidence on alternative environmental valuation methods. Environmental and Resource Economics, 34(1), 125162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, J. (2012). Contingent valuation: from dubious to hopeless. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 4356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, R. H. & Wolfe, B. L. (1984). Schooling and economic well-being: The role of nonmarket effects. Journal of Human Resources, 19(4), 378407.Google Scholar
Heckman, J. J., Lochner, L. J. & Todd, P. E. (2006). Earnings functions, rates of return and treatment effects: the Mincer equation and beyond. In Hanushek, E. & Welch, F. (Eds.), The handbook of economics of education (Vol. 1, pp. 307458). Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Hilmer, M. J. (1998). Post-secondary fees and the decision to attend a university or a community college. Journal of Public Economics, 67(3), 329348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, J. R. Jr. (2008). Excess burden of taxation. In Durlauf, S. N. & Blume, L. E. (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics. (2nd ed.). Palgrave Macmillan, The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. 19 June 2013. http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_E000315.Google Scholar
Jacobson, L. S., LaLonde, R. J. & Sullivan, D. G. (2005a). Estimating the returns to community college schooling for displaced workers. Journal of Econometrics, 125(1-2), 271304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, L. S., LaLonde, R. J., & Sullivan, D. G. (2005b). The impact of community college retraining on older displaced workers: should we teach old dogs new tricks? Industrial and Labor Relations Review 58(3), 398415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jepsen, C., Troske, K. R., & Coomes, P. A. (2014). The labor market returns for community college degrees, diplomas, and certificates. Journal of Labor Economics, 32(1), 95121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johansson, P.-O. (1995). Evaluating health risks: an economic approach. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kane, T. J., & Rouse, C. E. (1995). Labor market returns to two-year and four-year schools. American Economic Review, 85(3), 600614.Google Scholar
Kenkel, D. S. (1991). Health behavior, health knowledge, and schooling. Journal of Political Economy, 99(2), 287305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kling, C. L., Phaneuf, D. J., & Zhao, J. (2012). From Exxon to BP: Has some number become better than no number? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26(4), 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, F. & Topel, R. (2006). The social value of education and human capital. In Hanushek, E. & Welch, F. (Eds.), The handbook of economics of education, (Vol. 1, pp. 459509). Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.Google Scholar
List, J. A. & Gallet, C. A. (2001). What experimental protocol influence disparities between actual and hypothetical stated values. Environmental and Resource Economics, 20(3), 241254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Little, J. & Berrens, R. (2004). Explaining disparities between actual and hypothetical stated values: further investigation using meta-analysis. Economics Bulletin, 3(6), 113.Google Scholar
Lochner, L. (2011a). Education policy and crime. In Cook, P. J., Ludwig, J. & McCrary, J. (Eds.), Controlling crime: strategies and tradeoffs (pp. 465515). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lochner, L. (2011b). Non-production benefits of education: crime, health, and good citizenship. In Hanushek, E., Machin, S. & Woessmann, L. (Eds.), The handbook of economics of education (Vol. 4, pp. 183282). Amsterdam: Elsevier, North-Holland.Google Scholar
Lochner, L. & Moretti, E. (2004). The effect of education on crime: Evidence from prison inmates, arrests, and self-reports. American Economic Review, 94(1), 55189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMahon, W. W. (2007). An analysis of education externalities with applications to development in the deep south. Contemporary Economic Policy, 25(3), 459482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMahon, W. W. (2009). Higher learning, greater good: the private and social benefits of higher education. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMahon, W. W. & Oketch, M. (2010). Bachelor’s and short degrees in the UK and US: New social rates of return and non-market effects on development. Centre for Learning and Life Chances in Knowledge Economies and Societies Working Paper 12.Google Scholar
Meghir, C., Palme, M. & Schnable, M. (2012). The effect of education policy on crime: An intergenerational perspective. NBER Working Paper 18145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michael, R. T. (1973). Education in non-market production. Journal of Political Economy, 81(2), 306327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milligan, K., Moretti, E., & Oreopoulos, P. (2004). Does education improve citizenship? Evidence from the United States and the United Kingdom. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9-10), 16671695.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, and earnings. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Moore, M. A., Boardman, A. E., Vining, A. R., Weimer, D. L. & Greenberg, D. H. (2004). Just give me a number! Practical values for the social discount rate. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 23(4), 789812.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moretti, E. (2004a). Estimating the social return to higher education: evidence from longitudinal and repeated cross-sectional data. Journal of Econometrics, 121(1-2), 175212.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moretti, E. (2004b). Human capital externalities in cities. In Henderson, V. & Thisse, J. F. (Eds.), Handbook of urban and regional economics (Vol. 4, pp. 22432291). Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Oreopoulos, P. & Salvanes, K. G. (2009). How large are returns to schooling? Hint: Money isn’t everything. NBER Working Paper No. 15339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oreopoulos, P. & Salvanes, K. G. (2011). Priceless: the nonpecuniary benefits of schooling. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(1), 159184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poe, G. L., Clark, J. E., Rondeau, D. & Schulze, W. D. (2002). Provision point mechanisms and field validity tests of contingent valuation. Environmental and Resource Economics, 23(1), 105131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rauch, J. (1993). Productivity gains from geographic concentration of human capital: Evidence from the cities. Journal of Urban Economics, 34(3), 380400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, S. S. & Strange, W. C. (2008). The attenuation of human capital spillovers. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), 373389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegfried, J. J., Sanderson, A. R. & McHenry, P. (2007). The economic impact of colleges and universities. Economics of Education Review, 26(5), 546558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, C., Tamura, R., Mulholland, S. E. & Baier, S. (2007). Education and income of the United States: 1840-2000. Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), 101158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Bureau of Census (2007). American community survey. Public Use Microdata Sample Files. Population and Housing Records.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Education, National Center for Education Statistics (2008). Digest of education statistics tables and figures. Washington, DC: http://nces.ed.gov/programs/digest/d08/tables/dt08_189.asp.Google Scholar
U.S. National Center for Health Statistics (2006). National vital statistics reports. 54, no. 14, April 19, 2006 (as revised March 28, 2007), http://www.cdc.gov/nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr54/nvsr54_14.pdf. pp. 1013.Google Scholar
Wheeler, C. H. (2008). Human capital externalities and adult mortality in the U.S. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper 2007-045C. St. Louis, MO.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitehead, J. C. (2002). Incentive incompatibility and starting-point bias in iterative valuation questions. Land Economics, 78(2), 285297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winters, J. V. (2012). Human capital externalities and employment differences across metropolitan areas of the U.S. IZA Discussion Paper 6869.Google Scholar
White House (2010). Remarks by the President and Dr. Jill Biden at White House Summit on community colleges (October 5). URL: http://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-office/2010/10/05/remarks-president-and-dr-jill-biden-white-house-summit-community-college Referenced November 22, 2010.Google Scholar
Wolfe, B. L. & Haveman, R. H. (2002). Social and nonmarket benefits from education in an advanced economy. In Kodrzycki, Y. K. (Ed.), Education in the 21st Century: meeting the challenges of a changing world (pp. 97131). Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. http://www.bos.frb.org/economic/conf/conf47/conf47g.pdf.Google Scholar
Yamarik, S. J. (2008). Estimating returns to schooling from state-level data: A macro-Mincerian approach. The B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 8(1) (Contributions), Article 23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar