Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-17T00:45:13.556Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Estimating the Investment Behavior of Farm Firms Using the Concept of Rational Distributed Lag Functions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2015

Billy J. Trevena
Affiliation:
University of Tennessee
Luther H. Keller
Affiliation:
University of Tennessee

Extract

This study grew out of the need for a more realistic notion concerning the investment behavior of the individual farm firm. Once a stable investment behavior function is identified, it can be incorporated into dynamic growth models to describe and predict farm firm growth. Considerable effort has been devoted to estimating the appropriate investment behavior function for industrial corporations; however, a search of the literature revealed no estimates of such a function for individual farm firms.

The purpose of this study was to estimate the investment behavior function for individual farm firms using the concept of rational distributed lag functions developed by Jorgenson to approximate the time structure of the investment process. To do this, a class of rational distributed lag functions was imposed on a multiple regression equation to obtain the lag distribution that best describes the time path of the investment response to changes in desired capital.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Southern Agricultural Economics Association 1974

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

[1] Almon, Shirley. “The Distributed Lag Between Capital Appropriations and Expenditures.” Econometrica, No. 1, 33: 178196, Jan. 1965.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[2] Bauer, Larry Lee. “The Effect of Technology on the Farm Labor Market.American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 605618, Aug. 1969.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[3] Chenery, H.B.Overcapacity and the Acceleration Principle.Econometrica, 20: 128, Jan. 1952.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[4] Edwards, Clark. “Nonlinear Programming and Nonlinear Regression Procedures.Journal of Farm Economics, Vol. 44, pp. 100114, Feb. 1962.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[5] Grunfeld, Yehunda. “The Determinants of Corporate Investment.The Demand for Durable Goods. Edited by Harberger, A. L.. Chicago, 1960.Google Scholar
[6] Griliches, Zvi. “Distributed Lags: A Survey.Econometrica, No. 1, 35: 1649, Jan. 1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[7] Griliches, Zvi, and Wallace, N.. “The Determinants of Investment Revisited.International Economic Review, 6: 311329, Sept. 1965.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[8] Jorgenson, Dale W.Rational Distributed Lag Functions.Econometrica, No. 1, 32: 135149, Jan. 1966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[9] Jorgenson, Dale W., and Stephenson, James A.. “The Time Structure of Investment Behavior in United States Manufacturing, 1947-1960.Review of Economics and Statistics, 49: 1627, Feb. 1967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[10] Jorgenson, Dale W., and Siebert, Calvin D.. “A Comparison of Alternative Theories of Corporate Investment Behavior.” American Economic Review, 58: 681712, Sept. 1968.Google Scholar
[11] Koyck, L.M.Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis. Boston, Mass.: Mifflin Co., 1965.Google Scholar
[12] Nerlove, Marc. “Estimates of the Elasticities of Supply of Selected Agricultural Commodities.Journal of Farm Economics, 38: 496509, May 1956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
[13] Nerlove, Marc. “Distributed Lags and Estimation of Long-Run Supply and Demand Elasticities: Theoretical Considerations.Journal of Farm Economics, 40: 301311, May 1958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar