Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T09:29:49.483Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fully-automated liberalism? Blockchain technology and international cooperation in an anarchic world

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2020

Bernhard Reinsberg*
Affiliation:
School of Social and Political Sciences, University of Glasgow, 40 Bute Gardens, GlasgowG12 8RT, UK Centre for Business Research, University of Cambridge, Cambridge, UK
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: bernhard.reinsberg@glasgow.ac.uk
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

A recent wave of scholarship attests that the liberal world order is under threat. Although there is disagreement about the underlying reasons for this diagnosis, there are few attempts to further our understanding of how the liberal order can be reinvigorated. This paper probes the potential of blockchain technology to promote international cooperation. Blockchain technology is a data structure that enables global governance stakeholders to establish decentralized governance systems which provide high-powered incentives for enhanced cooperation. By outlining the contours of a blockchain-based global governance system for climate policy, the paper illustrates that blockchain technology holds theoretical promise to foster cooperation in three ways: leveraging new sources of information through blockchain-based prediction markets; allaying coordinating problems through reducing the cost of transactions for side payments; and allowing states and other global governance actors to make more credible commitments given guaranteed execution of blockchain-enabled smart contracts. By empowering local knowledge holders and non-state actors that traditionally lacked the means to coordinate efforts to influence global politics, blockchain technology also promises to advance an international order based on liberal values. In actuality, however, emerging blockchain-based global governance systems will fall short of the libertarian ideal of ‘fully-automated liberalism’ as their design and operation will remain under the shadow of power.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2020. Published by Cambridge University Press

Liberalism is a theory of international politics that emphasizes international institutions and global society as facilitators of peace and prosperity.Footnote 1 Although the liberal world order is currently under stress,Footnote 2 there is little hope that this state of nature will change any time soon. International institutions – given the rise of emerging powers – are no longer underpinned by a single hegemon to which all other actors defer. Therefore, they are ever less able to act as focal points and thus fail to reduce the uncertainty that prevents deeper cooperation. Ironically, a return to hegemony would not promote liberal values. Hegemony tends to undermine itself as it creates rules that benefit the hegemon itself and that cannot prevent the hegemon from breaking the rules.Footnote 3 A key challenge in liberal thought therefore is how to promote stability without the need for hegemony.

This paper probes whether recent technological advances – specifically blockchain technology – can promote institutionalized cooperation and whether the creation of blockchain-based governance systems would be normatively desirable from a liberal perspective. A blockchain is a database whose entries are cryptographically linked and which is distributed across participants of a peer-to-peer network. These design principles make a blockchain an incorruptible record of information that network participants can trust even without the existence of a central authority. Although blockchain is merely a data structure, it can be deployed to create so-called ‘smart contracts’. These contracts act autonomously in accordance with pre-coded rules, thereby exerting governance effects and potentially changing how societies interact in fundamental ways.Footnote 4

Using the example of climate change as an issue area, I sketch out the contours of a ‘Decentralized Autonomous Organization’ (DAO) – a virtual entity governed by a set of interrelated smart contracts – that represents a utopian vision of how climate governance would be implemented in a blockchain world. This climate DAO would not only implement key provisions of the Paris Agreement but also be adaptable to changing collective preferences over how global climate policy should be governed.

This example provides the background for subsequent theoretical analysis, which shows that blockchain technology can promote international cooperation, under relatively benign assumptions. In essence, I show that smart contracts provide the building blocks for tapping unmet potential for cooperation in the following three ways: first, they help leverage the wisdom of crowds to validate events in the real world by facilitating prediction markets; second, they help allay distributional problems by automating issue linkage and side payments and realizing transaction cost savings; third, they allow stakeholders to make more credible commitments given the potential for elimination of uncertainty around contract enforcement.

The key theoretical contribution of my paper is to demonstrate how blockchain technology operationalizes the liberal-institutionalist promise of promoting cooperation in an anarchic world.Footnote 5 The hypothetical governance system that I describe here involves global governance actors – states, international organizations, and non-state actors – interacting through interlocking sets of smart contracts. This system promises to promote stability without the need for hegemony, relying on a decentralized system and self-governing contracts that do not require the upfront investment into centralized institutions typically undertaken by a hegemon. Once states submit themselves under such a system, they could reap the benefits of reduced uncertainty around enforcement, provided that they staked resources to underpin their commitments. States would also be able to reduce transaction costs by tapping into new sources of trusted information and settling their contractual obligations more efficiently. By leveraging new sources of information and resources from transnational actors with a staked interest in policy change, blockchain technology could promote cooperation even where opportunities for mutual gains have traditionally not been considered to exist.Footnote 6

Obviously, the ability of states to realize the cooperation benefits of blockchain technology depends on their general willingness to cooperate in pursuit of mutual gains, as presumed by neoliberal institutionalism. Although the effectiveness of blockchain-based global governance hinges upon voluntary participation of state actors, a fundamental challenge is how to incentivize the participation of (especially) powerful states, which face the highest cost of submitting themselves under hard contractual obligations. In line with realist thought, it must be expected that such states would either opt out of blockchain-based governance, or would only make shallow commitments.Footnote 7

And yet, the real benefit of blockchain-based global governance is that buy-in from states is not necessary to promote cooperation among non-state actors toward achieving common objectives. This is because blockchain technology indeed allows any kind of stakeholder to make credible commitments, which generates stable expectations about their future behavior which in turn provides incentives for long-term investments in line with such commitments. I therefore argue that blockchain technology has potential to instantiate decentralized governance platforms that implement liberal ideals of a ‘fully-automated liberalism’ – whereby individual actors and the autonomous contracts that these actors create would work to achieve common objectives. By affording individual actors the possibility to securely transact with each other without the need for central authorities, blockchain technology tends to empower traditionally underprivileged actors. However, the definition of common objectives does not happen in a vacuum but would reflect the pre-existing power distribution. Blockchain technology itself thus has limited potential to fundamentally alter how power is distributed.

My paper makes three additional contributions. The first is to recognize the institution-like properties of blockchain technology. In particular, smart contracts under the aforementioned DAO – by removing uncertainty around enforcement for specific types of conditions – generate fundamentally different expectations about behavior than traditional forms of global governance, thereby meeting the definition of international institutions as sets of interconnected rules that shape actor behavior.Footnote 8 Touching upon issues of contract enforcement, there is substantive literature on international courts.Footnote 9 By examining smart contracts, my paper provides a complementary approach to enforcement and discusses conditions under which they can solve enforcement problems.

In addition, I contribute to a small literature examining the relationship between cooperation dilemmas, international institutions, and technologies.Footnote 10 Specifically, scholarship within Science and Technology Studies has examined how big data changes the nature of International Relations (IR) and related notions of power,Footnote 11 further highlighting that the design of technologies such as the internet is itself subject to global power struggles and mediated by socio-political norms.Footnote 12 Some domestically-focused public policy research examined how technological innovations may disrupt organizational routines,Footnote 13 whereas others emphasized how the growing availability of low-cost information technology facilitated efficiency-driven outsourcing of government services, raising concerns about democratic legitimacy and data protection.Footnote 14 Although these studies have looked at a range of technologies, no study has focused on blockchain technology, let alone attempted to examine whether and how it could help address cooperation dilemmas at the international level.

Finally, my paper is related to scholarly debates on global order.Footnote 15 Here my contribution is to highlight that blockchain technology, specifically through algorithmic governance,Footnote 16 renders the assumption of anarchy in the international system increasingly irrelevant. As McConaughey, Musgrave and Nexon (Reference Musgrave and Nexon2018) noted in this journal already, world politics is best understood as a set of ‘nested governance assemblages’, even though some relations between some actors may remain anarchical. Some blockchains exist and can affect global politics without the possibility of states to censor them, thus establishing governance at levels below the nation-state. In this way, it promises to empower weaker parties – less powerful states, non-government actors, and individuals – providing a tool to make global governance more transparent, if not accessible. Yet, although blockchain technology is considered by its libertarian proponents as an entry point for challenging existing hierarchies, the most-likely context in which it is used in global governance will not radically reconfigure existing hierarchies.

Blockchain technology

What is blockchain technology?

‘Blockchain technology’ has become a catch-all term for what basically is a bundle of pre-existing technologies whose combination gives rise to socially powerful emergent properties. First and foremost, blockchain is a data structure – a digital ledger in which information is stored in blocks and linked to previous blocks.Footnote 17 Blocks are linked via cryptography, allowing participants with read-access rights to verify that a transaction occurred whereas preserving data privacy. Blocks are transmitted to a distributed network of computers, thereby building resilience against attacks. To ensure that the data are synchronized, every blockchain needs a consensus mechanism. If a network participant wants to initiate a new transaction – creating a new block in the blockchain – all network participants must first accept its validity. As the integrity of a participant cannot be readily assumed, the consensus mechanism holds key to the sanctity of the data.

It is important to realize that there is no single type of blockchain. Different blockchains vary with respect to rules of access and scope of distribution. In so-called ‘permissionless blockchains’, everyone can join the blockchain network and write consensus data. Such highly decentralized systems – due to their need for consensus, layers of encryption, and redundancy – reduce the speed with which transactions can be settled.Footnote 18 In so-called ‘permissioned blockchains’, the ability to manipulate the blockchain is restricted to pre-approved participants who need off-network authentication and permission to write.Footnote 19 Permissions can be issued by a central authority; alternatively, consortium systems rely on the collective decision of participants, without involving a central authority. In a permissioned network, the identity of every participant is known. Permissioned blockchain networks do not abrogate the requirement that every node on the network perform all of the computation for the entire network, but they break this computation into particular segments and thereby increase overall performance and reduce transaction costs relative to permissionless blockchains.Footnote 20 An example is a consortium of banks that use a private blockchain to settle derivatives.

In addition, there are differences as to who is authorized to read information from a blockchain. In public blockchains, everyone with an internet-connect device and the related software can read-access the blockchain, whereas private blockchains require authentication for this purpose.Footnote 21 Obviously, there is a correlation in the relationship between write-restriction and read-restriction, although the two design dimensions are analytically separate. Their combination allows for a variety of blockchain designs that can be adapted to the specific nature of the given problems.

For example, Bitcoin – the first and best-known application of a blockchain – uses a public-permissionless blockchain, conceived by its founder as a decentralized alternative to fiat money backed by central banks.Footnote 22 This blockchain design reflects its purpose of enabling direct instantaneous transfer of value among participants in a fully decentralized manner – without the need for participants to trust each other and without a need for a central authority to settle transactions.Footnote 23 The downside of a completely open consensus mechanism is that fraud – in particular double-spending of bitcoins – must be made sufficiently unattractive. Bitcoin solves this by requiring ‘proof of work’ – the costly computation of a complex cryptographic problem – which has been criticized for its high-energy consumption.Footnote 24

Public-permissioned blockchains, which involve an element of authentication, have already been deployed for digital identity services, land registries, supply-chain management, decentralized file storage, and crowdfunding climate finance.Footnote 25 These applications are often built upon EthereumFootnote 26 – a general-purpose blockchain that can settle any kind of digital transactions, not just cryptocurrency transfers. Aside from the proof-of-work consensus mechanism, Ethereum supports ‘proof of stake’, whereby a participant gets chosen to validate a proposed block with probability proportional to its staked deposit. If a proposed block does not get included in the blockchain, a validator loses its staked deposit.Footnote 27 Yet another consensus mechanism – used by the World Bank in its recent sale of a blockchain bond – is ‘proof of authority’, which lets trusted participants (such as the World Bank) manipulate the blockchain.Footnote 28

Blockchain-enabled functionalities

A key blockchain-enabled functionality that merits particular attention – given its potential use for global governance – is the ‘smart contract’,Footnote 29 which facilitates, validates, and records transactions and agreements between multiple parties.Footnote 30 Smart contracts allow many types of contractual clauses to be made self-executing, self-enforcing, or both.Footnote 31 An example is a so-called ‘multi-signature escrow’, whereby a contract executes when a specified quorum of participants have endorsed it through their digital signatures.Footnote 32 In IR, the equivalent of an escrow would be an arbitrator whose consent is required for a bilateral dispute to be settled if the two states disagree. If the contract specifies that a transaction needs to be digitally signed by at least two participants, the arbitrator becomes the pivotal player if only one of two parties has provided its signature.Footnote 33 Smart contracts hold most promise to reduce transaction costs for routine activities, for example to settle market transactions, where a buyer could use a smart contract to automatically release payment to a supplier of a good once the good has arrived at a specified location.Footnote 34

Smart contracts provide the building blocks for so-called decentralized applications (dApps), which essentially combine several smart contracts.Footnote 35 An even more sophisticated application – ‘decentralized autonomous organizations' (DAOs) – link several smart contracts together to form a self-governing system.Footnote 36 A DAO is a virtual entity that has a certain set of members which have the right to modify its code and spend its funds.Footnote 37 For example, DAO members could decide to change quorums required for certain decisions.Footnote 38 DAOs mimic existing collective entities such as international organizations, but use smart contracts for enforcement.Footnote 39 DAOs have come under criticism after the infamous 2016 DAO hack, in which an attacker exploited a loophole in the coding protocol to siphon off DAO funds.Footnote 40 In the DAO hack, no rule was agreed ex ante how to deal with attacks, which led to an ad-hoc human decision to fork the blockchain.Footnote 41 In any DAO, though, parties to smart contracts could agree on how hacks can be addressed, even though these will vary in style.

A common challenge for all smart contracts is that unless information is readily available on the blockchain, as for example for cryptocurrency transfers, they depend on external information feeds – so-called ‘oracles’ – to bring the relevant information on the blockchain. With the rise of the ‘Internet of Things’ (IoT), tamper-proof smart devices are becoming increasingly important technical oracles.Footnote 42 Another kind of oracle, facilitated by smart contracts, are ‘blockchain-based prediction markets’, which aggregate information about the occurrence of events in a non-manipulable way. Although prediction markets have existed long before the arrival of blockchain, they were malfunctioning because no central authority could commit to not exploit sensitive information for its own gain. As a result, reported information was not trustworthy. Blockchain technology, however, supports the proper functioning of prediction markets that leverage the ‘wisdom of crowds’.Footnote 43 The decentralized nature of blockchain-based prediction markets implies that no one effectively controls information whereas information can be shared securely to validate certain events. An internal reputation system – drawn from game-theoretic approaches of mechanism design – incentivizes truthful reporting.Footnote 44 Prediction markets are accurate because market participants stake real money on their predictions, whereas participants report valuable information given guaranteed payments through smart contracts.Footnote 45 Smart contracts thus not only depend on prediction markets for their functionality but also ensure their viability.

Blockchain-based global governance

The central idea of this paper is that blockchain technology – by facilitating transactions between actors and the autonomous contract agents that they create – is a decentralized mechanism for global governance, which can be defined as ‘systems of rule at all levels of human activity – from the family to the international organization – in which the pursuit of goals through the exercise of control has transnational repercussions’.Footnote 46

Although the ability to govern has traditionally been confined to human beings, the rise of information and communication technologies, specifically computer algorithms, has come to challenge this view. Scholars have coined the term ‘algorithmic governance’ to refer to computer programs making authoritative decisions that construct reality and social order, based on predefined code and often using big data as input.Footnote 47 Blockchain governance – as a subset of algorithmic governance – refers to those algorithms that run simultaneously on a distributed network of computers. Algorithmic governance can extend across national boundaries, for instance through algorithmic selection on the internet, or indeed through transnational relations on blockchain platforms.

Competing perspectives exist to understand the implications of blockchain governance for global society. What unites them is their recognition that blockchain technology – by giving rise to autonomous agents who follow encoded scripts – exert a governing effect on social behavior. They can do so at least by altering the relative attractiveness of different behavioral choices, if not by altering preferences toward cooperation themselves, given that actors come to understand that ‘code is law’.Footnote 48

Blockchain governance still is not an entirely accurate label for my subsequent analysis. It may refer to governance by the blockchain (i.e. cooperation between stakeholders through blockchain-based systems) and governance of the blockchain (i.e. how stakeholders take decisions about the rules by which the blockchain operates, the so-called ‘protocol’). To clarify that my main interest in this paper is in the ways in which blockchain technology can be used to further cooperation at the global level – rather than the principles by which blockchains themselves are governed – I henceforth use the term blockchain-based global governance, not blockchain governance.

Blockchain-based global governance for climate policy

Why climate governance?

I demonstrate the implementation of blockchain-based global governance for the issue area of climate change. First of all, the combat against climate change is fraught with a diversity of complex cooperation problems, which allow for probing the different ways in which blockchain technology might help address such problems. In the domain of mitigation, a key challenge is to prevent states from free-riding on emission reductions of other states. In the domain of adaptation, states face an international distribution problem over how to spread the costs of financing the adaptation to the inevitable consequences of global warming. Both domains are not independent – as less ambitious collective mitigation efforts imply a greater need for more adaptation efforts specifically in the most vulnerable countries – which further complicates the bargaining process. Finally, the global fight against climate change also entails a distribution problem at the domestic level. Domestic bargains determine the viability of international bargains on climate policy, but in many countries the prospect for domestic bargains is bleak due to powerful lobbies with vested interests in the carbon economy.

At the same time, the fight against climate change has brought to the fore an unparalleled diversity of actors with the capacity to take globally coordinated action, regardless of concurrent efforts led by national governments. Around the globe, sub-state actors – in particular cities – coordinate their efforts to hasten green urban transformations whereas at the same time lobbying their national governments to embrace de-carbonization.Footnote 49 Cities have institutionalized their climate-related efforts through transgovernmental networks such as the C40 Cities Climate Leadership Group, International Council for Local Environmental Initiatives (ICLEI), and the Coalition for Urban Transitions, which recently published an influential study illustrating how the development of carbon-neutral cities would help solve the climate crisis.Footnote 50 There even is a proposal for a world parliament of cities that deliberates and undertakes to do whatever they are willing to do voluntarily, but under traditional governance this entity would remain under the purview of states.Footnote 51

The climate regime is one that is rife with private-led initiatives using blockchain technology, upon which states could draw to operationalize their climate-related commitments. Besides global emissions trading markets,Footnote 52 an important blockchain-based application is climate-related crowdfunding. WeiFund provides an example of an open crowdfunding platform implemented through smart contracts on the Ethereum blockchain.Footnote 53 Other projects seek to find innovative ways to mitigate the carbon footprint of blockchain technology itself, for instance by using transaction fees in the network to buy real-world carbon credits.Footnote 54 Finally, blockchain technology is already being used for peer-to-peer energy trading. For example, SolarCoin is a community-based solar electricity reward program.Footnote 55 Any solar installation can register with the network and receive SolarCoins for a verified amount of solar electricity produced. Users can spent coins for solar energy within the network or exchange them for fiat currencies.Footnote 56

The blossoming ecosystem of climate initiatives also reminds us that climate change – albeit plagued by cooperation problems among states – is the product of the sum of individual decisions and addressing it would likely require incentive systems that foremost change individual behavior. In the following, I highlight the key provisions of the Paris Agreement – as the most recent accord that will govern climate-related cooperation in the foreseeable future – and describe how bringing them on the blockchain would create the contours of an emerging ‘climate DAO’ that would help stakeholders address underlying cooperation problems.

From the Paris Agreement to the climate DAO

The Paris Agreement – the successor regime of the Kyoto Protocol – marks a momentous turn in the governance of climate change. Unlike the Kyoto Protocol, it does not require states to make binding commitments, but instead takes a bottom-up approach in which states set their own targets – so-called Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) – and communicate them internationally, reviewed by an expert panel.Footnote 57 Hopes are that reputational concerns and network effects would entice states to commit to more ambitious NDCs.Footnote 58

Bringing the Paris Agreement on the blockchain would entail that member states first create a permissioned blockchain. Write-access would be restricted to pre-identified stakeholders such as states themselves and entrusted third parties – international organizations, non-governmental organizations, and expert bodies. States may decide to make some information visible to everyone outside the system. In particular, publicly recording the NDCs would meet the transparency requirements of the Paris Agreement (Article 4). Once the data are recorded on the blockchain, it is extremely hard to forge by anyone. This implies reduced administrative costs by obviating the need for the UNFCCC secretariat to keep a central record of such NDCs.

With the ability to purchase carbon credits in other jurisdictions comes the need for ‘robust accounting’ that seeks to avoid double-counting of emission reductions (Article 6). The transparency-related functionalities of blockchain technology would make it a cost-effective solution to this problem, circumventing the need for a central organization to settle transactions of carbon credits.Footnote 59 In fact, the Pacific Alliance nations are planning to create a blockchain-based monitoring system for emissions.Footnote 60

For other provisions of the Paris Agreement, a more extended use of blockchain technology is necessary. In particular, states would need to intertwine their blockchain with the ecosystem of permissionless blockchains in the climate sector. Technically, this can be implemented through ‘heterogeneous multi-chain frameworks’,Footnote 61 which enable different kinds of consensus systems in a ‘federation’ to have trust-free access to each other. A common natural token, which might be called ‘greencoin’ and which would be created on top of a permissionless blockchain (such as Ethereum), would ensure that different blockchains would be interoperable. For example, states could use tokens to hire other stakeholders to perform certain tasks.

One additional task such a blockchain-based governance system could address is to facilitate ‘results-based payments’ for ‘activities relating to reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation’ (Article 5). To see how this would work in practice, imagine that anyone in a permissionless network connected to the system can earn greencoins by planting treesFootnote 62 (equivalent to ‘mining’ in the Bitcoin system); however, to ensure that greencoins have actual value, states could stake real money on them – through a smart contract residing on the permissioned blockchain that takes a monetary deposit from each state. If states fail to comply with their emission reduction targets, their deposit will be taken and redistributed as greencoins to individuals that have planted trees. Instead of planting trees, individuals could also buy up greencoins to support climate action. By increasing the exchange value of greencoins, these individuals would provide incentives for more rapid tree-planting. Obviously, tree-planting is just one example of climate-related activities; states could agree on a list of potential measures along with ways of verification and the incentive system underlying effective decentralized verification.

Given the elevated role of climate-related information (Article 13), there is a need for robust systems that produce information that can be trusted. Blockchain technology – particularly smart contracts – facilitate information provision by IoT devices and prediction markets, hence contributing to the verification of emission reductions and adaptation measures at the local level. Smart contracts also offer a way to securely reward local information providers with greencoins, thus meeting the Paris Agreement principle of ‘drawing on [the] knowledge of indigenous peoples and local knowledge systems’ (Article 7).

The benefit of a common token in the blockchain system is to allow for a panoply of measures to be rewarded, whereas further promoting climate ambition (Article 6), even at the highest political levels. For example, consider the decision by US president Donald Trump to withdraw from the Paris Agreement, motivated with the expected job losses for carbon-intensive industry workers. Major transnational corporations – including Apple, Google, and Walmart – and even fossil fuel firms such as ExxonMobil, BP, Shell, and other firms outside the USA criticized the decision and reaffirmed their support for the Paris Agreement.Footnote 63 A series of smart contracts could have facilitated the compensation of affected workers using payments from transnational corporations benefiting from the low-carbon transition. Under the existing system, such a complex transnational arrangement would have involved high transaction costs without giving stakeholders the certainty that all transactions would settle.Footnote 64

Last but not least, the above blockchain-based system can be further developed into a climate DAO that would allow participants to alter procedural rules. To be sure, procedural clauses such as the requirement that 55 states representing 55% of global emissions must have ratified the Paris Agreement before it enters into force (Article 21) are easily translated into the language of smart contracts. Clauses such as these could be changed by self-modifying pieces of code. Any country could propose to alter these rules, by releasing a transaction to vote for a proposal. States vote on proposals by spending their tokens on a given proposal. In other words, a token would operationalize a voting mechanism for on-chain governance, such that states would have incentives to invest more tokens for proposals about which they care more.

The here-described climate DAO is a self-governed organization controlled by an incorruptible (yet collectively adjustable) set of rules, implemented as a set of smart contracts. Some encode contractual relationships between states, international organizations, and non-state actors. Once established by stakeholders, smart contracts interact with each other and with other stakeholders according to their predefined code, without the need for human triggers.Footnote 65 For example, some contracts may pay smart devices for feeding critical information into the system. In the same way, smart contracts can be fully self-executing, thereby punishing state behavior that violates a previously made commitment. International cooperation would thus come about through the interaction of (in many cases fully autonomous) smart contracts.

Theoretical implications

Having laid out the principal design of blockchain-based global governance with an illustration of a climate DAO, I now discuss the implications of such a governance system for international cooperation, normative issues, and global order.

Cooperation

Blockchain technology promises to promote international cooperation in three ways. First, it could address information problems by leveraging distributed consensus to generate reliable information. Second, it would offer a secure and efficient way of making side payments as part of agreements, hence allaying distribution problems. Third, blockchain technology could enhance the credibility of state commitments by allowing for guaranteed execution of intergovernmental contracts under certain conditions. I discuss each of these promises in more detail below.

Leveraging new information: Blockchain technology may be deployed to alleviate information problems, given the way it represents data and the difficulty to tamper with the data. In general, blockchain technology is particularly useful where participants need to access, verify, send, or store information securely, but where a trusted central authority for that purpose is not readily available.Footnote 66 It also holds significant promise wherever verification that an event happened is necessary but prohibitively costly.

Although information that has once been recorded on the blockchain is resistant to manipulation, a remaining challenge is how to ensure the accuracy of such information in the first place. The usefulness of blockchain technology in this regard depends on the type of information to be stored. Efficiency gains are largest for ‘on-chain events’ – the ones that occur within the blockchain system, such as transfer of digital currency. The more challenging case refers to ‘off-chain events’ – those that occur in the real world but are not yet represented on the blockchain. To verify off-chain events, states can use oracles. For instance, satellite imagery is a technological oracle that can verify preservation of rain forest areas that countries might have promised to undertake. A blockchain-based prediction market is another type of oracle, allowing participants to ascertain the probability that a specified event happened. As the international system is characterized by a paucity of information that is often untrustworthy, states which have the most interest in accurate information will act as market makers and provide liquidity to initiate a prediction market.

One might contend that there are enough trusted parties who facilitate state cooperation by serving as mediators, validators, and knowledge producers.Footnote 67 However, stakeholders may not want to delegate authority to such parties, as those may abuse this power to advance their own agendas. For instance, as noted by principal–agent literature, international organizations, if endowed with too much delegated authority, can overstep their mandates and be prone to uncontrolled budget growth.Footnote 68 In such contexts, oracles such as IoT devices and decentralized prediction markets provide an alternative source of trusted information.

And yet, for a range of information types, there is a continued need for trusted third parties, such as international organizations, non-governmental organizations, and expert bodies.Footnote 69 Traditional third parties may be superior to decentralized information providers specifically for highly technical issues, such as monetary policy-making, where it is unlikely that public prediction markets will have many reporters because individuals lack the expertise to make informed bets. In this case, a technocratic international organization may be the better choice.Footnote 70

Allaying distribution problems: If – as some scholars argue – distributional problems are the main impediment to cooperation, the primary role of institutions is not to prevent cheating (because a once-chosen equilibrium is self-enforcing) but to help states choose among multiple equilibria with different distributional implications.Footnote 71 As argued by neoliberal institutionalists, institutions help states to do so by facilitating issue linkage and side payments.Footnote 72

Blockchain technology, particularly smart contracts, can be used to streamline these processes. Each state would encode in a smart contract what it would be willing to surrender in exchange for some benefit that another state would grant. The blockchain as a decentralized ledger of such commitments would then serve as ‘market maker’ – like a trading computer on the stock market – and identify the Pareto-optimal allocation of benefits. Presumably, the efficiency gains from using blockchains for this purpose are not large but increasing in the extent to which state bargaining follows a standardized protocol, occurs rather frequently, and involves easily traceable or digital assets. Multilateral trade negotiations provide a case in point. These negotiations have long followed an informal procedure by which the most powerful states define the agenda and reach agreement in informal minilateral settings that they seek to extend to the membership at large. As the ambassador of Costa Rica to the WTO stated, trade policy ‘is still being negotiated in a […] widely inefficient manner’Footnote 73 – as it fails to search the bargaining space for globally optimal deals that make all countries better off. Just like trade negotiations, climate-related negotiations are complex and the unmet potential for Pareto-increasing policy choices is relatively high.

Blockchain technology can also solve gridlock between states by breaking up the domestic bargains that constrain governments to commit to cooperative policies at the international level.Footnote 74 This is particularly relevant when non-state actors – specifically the ones that reside in other jurisdictions – have significant resources available to incentivize pro-cooperation behavior of domestically-constrained governments, as the earlier thought experiment on the US exit from Paris illustrated. By allowing transnational actors to devise smart contracts that promise to pay states for compliance, the resulting blockchain ecosystem would address the staking problem by contributing money from sources other than states.

In sum, blockchain technology has potential to allay distributional problems by offering a way to organize issue linkage and side payments more efficiently through smart contracts. In the context of coordination problems, the rigidity of such contracts is advantageous because once they settle a proposed transaction, states have no incentives to rewind it. In addition, a blockchain-based governance ecosystem promises to shift the Pareto frontier by making available financial resources from non-state actors to incentivize government cooperation.

Making commitments more credible: A final promise of blockchain technology is to allow states to make credible commitments – as states would be able to design contracts whose execution is guaranteed. There are two reasons to believe that states have interests to do so. First, governments – especially those with limited tenure such as democratically elected ones – have incentives to lock in policy. By adopting institutions from which exit is costly, they can effectively tie the hands of their successors and limit policy reversals – a strategy that is well known in the context of delegating monetary policy to an independent central bank.Footnote 75 Second, the lack of enforcement creates incentives to renege on commitments, which undermines their strength.Footnote 76 Guaranteed enforcement allows states to make more credible commitments to each other because uncertainty around enforcement is removed. As smart contracts can be programed not to enter into force until a quorum of states complies with them, any state wishing to make a stronger commitment does not inevitably expose itself to undue risk of being exploited by other states.Footnote 77

This is a potential advantage over currently existing institutions. Even international organizations – the most centralized entities in world politics with considerable degrees of delegated authority – are far from being direct enforcers of rules but do so indirectly by relying on incentives, persuasion, and learning.Footnote 78 International organizations often serve as commitment devices ex ante, for instance through costly accession procedures,Footnote 79 which are effectively realized costs. International organizations also have limited capacities to enforce state commitments ex post, whereas smart contracts allow for guaranteed punishment when a state violates a previously made commitment.

For smart contracts to effectively enhance the credibility of commitments, states must have staked resources upon them that states would lose if they did not follow through on their promises. For incumbents who contemplate about a commitment, the ability of the smart contact to hold funds securely in custody should reassure them to make a deposit that it might otherwise not be willing to make vis-à-vis a less trustworthy intermediary.Footnote 80 Future incumbents who inherit a stake from their predecessor are effectively constrained by the smart contract because non-compliance will lead to loss of deposit. Full automation of the commitment–compliance process requires that contract conditions can be unambiguously evaluated, which however is the case only for blockchain events (although the rise of IoT devices and prediction markets facilitated by smart contracts enlarges the set of contract conditions that are interpretable). Under such conditions, problems of moral hazard would be eliminated, and costs of verification and enforcement of promises would be reduced.

If enforcement problems and the related lack of credible commitment inhibit intergovernmental cooperation, blockchain technology, and particularly smart contracts, hold promise to promote cooperation. From a merely technical perspective, the effectiveness of many smart contracts may be limited by their reliance on real-world authorities and their own contractual rigidity that is essential for their efficiency. The first problem may become more manageable in the future, considering the increasing availability of smart devices and blockchain-based prediction markets, which serve as information input devices to the blockchain. A crucial task though would be to increase the resilience of these input devices to manipulation, as they are the key ‘infostructures’ of the blockchain age.Footnote 81

The second problem is more severe. In fact, there is an inherent tradeoff between efficiency afforded by a smart contract and the flexibility that the language of ambiguous contracts provides.Footnote 82 Smart contracts are fully efficient only if they can execute automatically. To that end, they must be ‘complete contracts’Footnote 83 – specifying all possible contingencies upfront. Even if this was feasible, it would be costly for complex issues, thus increasing the cost of ex ante contract design. More importantly, complete contracts may not be collectively desirable. Governance actors may not want to be collectively bound by a formal treaty provision if circumstances change unexpectedly.Footnote 84 Indeed, many international agreements include escape clauses, treaty reservations, non-legally binding provisions, and procedural standards that need further interpretation. This is not accidental but a deliberate design choice by states which desire flexibility, especially when uncertainty about the state of the world is high.Footnote 85

Where blockchain transactions require enforcement in the real world, the blockchain is as ineffective as conventional international law if powerful states renege on their promises in the absence of a world government. And even where execution is possible as in the case of on-chain events, the strength of guaranteed execution might actually turn into a weakness: states anticipating guaranteed punishment for reneging might be unwilling to make ambitious commitments in the first place. This implies that state commitments under smart contracts will likely be trivial, or participation in blockchain-based governance would be limited to states that are willing to comply or that expect to comply with contract obligations.Footnote 86

Cross-cutting considerations: Albeit analytically distinct, the above mechanisms through which blockchain technology can enhance cooperation are interrelated. Smart contracts are key for the effective functioning of oracles, specifically prediction markets. Oracles are sources of new information that would help enlarge the set of self-executing smart contracts, thus promoting cooperation by eliminating enforcement uncertainty and realizing gains from reducing the costs of settling contracts. For complex multilateral bargaining situations where states have not identified Pareto-optimal policy outcomes, smart contracts residing on the blockchain could help states to identify mutually preferable bargaining outcomes, thereby reducing transaction costs of policy bargaining and streamlining agreement execution. This suggests that blockchain technology may enhance cooperation by altering state preferences over strategies.Footnote 87

An even more important benefit of blockchain technology is its potential to alter state preferences over outcomes. In some issue areas, there are (resourceful) domestic stakeholders with pro-cooperation preferences who can use blockchain technology to incentivize recalcitrant governments to cooperate, or, failing that, circumvent them altogether. This is important as it shows that – given the technology – there is no longer a need for a hegemon to uphold cooperation. At the same time, cooperation would become truly transnational, thus coming close to the ‘open liberal order’ that liberal observers have envisioned.Footnote 88 A good example to illustrate this is the recent announcement by Microsoft to invest USD 1 billion over the next decade to become a ‘carbon-negative enterprise’.Footnote 89 To help underpin the credibility of this statement, Microsoft could encode this commitment in a smart contract with an appropriate stake. This would make powerful players such as Microsoft truly accountable, whereas providing certainty for other (less powerful) actors to make long-term investments into technologies that would help Microsoft achieve its commitment.

Normative implications: power and legitimacy

Even if blockchain technology could help promote cooperation, a remaining issue is whether its use would be normatively desirable. Liberalism provides a normative standard against which to judge blockchain-based global governance imaginaries. As a tradition of thought, liberalism emphasizes individual freedom of choice, equality of individuals, and protection against abuse of power. Early liberal thinkers such as Immanuel Kant argued that if it was not for autocratic rulers, human beings and their nation-states would live in harmony with each other. Following from thinkers such as Abbé Saint-Pierre,Footnote 90 Giuseppe Mazzini,Footnote 91 and Woodrow Wilson,Footnote 92 liberalists posit that rulers could bind themselves using international institutions,Footnote 93 which exist to promote economic prosperity and sustain peace and thus make everyone better off.

Blockchain technology seems to be well-placed to promote ‘fully-automated liberalism’ – a state of nature where participants undertake mutually beneficial transactions whereas furthering the collective goals of global society.Footnote 94 Its normative appeal is that all actors, even the most powerful ones, would be constrained by their own promises encoded within smart contracts. The fundamental problem obviously is how to incentivize powerful actors to make such hard commitments. Aside from the technical difficulties to generate self-enforcing contracts discussed earlier, blockchain-based global governance would unlikely be egalitarian but imbued by pre-existing power asymmetries. Similar to other technologies, blockchains are agnostic about the content of the computer code that runs on them. As technologies are always embedded in specific social contexts, blockchain technology, too, will be deployed in ways that reflect existing power structures. Thus, as I will argue, even if a blockchain-based governance system like the climate DAO were to be implemented, it would fall short of liberal ideals as it cannot fundamentally change the pre-existing power distribution.

That said, fully-automated liberalism could help make global governance more liberal. Even permissioned blockchains, controlled by centralized actors, can empower traditionally underprivileged groups through the broadened set of opportunities for low-cost transnational interactions. For instance, blockchain-based remittance payments are cheaper than traditional payment systems.Footnote 95 The related transaction cost savings generate real income growth that might empower marginalized actors. As described in the example of the climate DAO, marginalized actors will also be empowered through greencoin rewards for their local actions to further collective climate goals. As bearers of local knowledge, marginalized groups would also be empowered as they hold relevant information on which blockchain-based prediction markets depend. Yet, the possibility to earn greencoins is predisposed on aligned interests of states or other resourceful actors that establish such high-powered incentive schemes.

Permissionless blockchains even promise to directly empower individual citizens by disintermediating the roles of centralized actors and processes that traditionally underpin global governance. Blockchain may offer an entry point for weaker actors – specifically non-state actors – to challenge existing hierarchies, because it affords them a coordination device to organize decentralized action toward a collective goal without relying on recalcitrant governments. Such disintermediation, however, may not be normatively desirable if states are benevolentFootnote 96; however, it would be desirable if states failed to be responsive to citizens, who then would need to rely on the blockchain as an alternative decentralized governance mechanism to affect global politics. Global carbon emissions trading market provides a case in point. Even without institutional support from governments, non-state actors would be able to trade carbon emissions through a blockchain-based governance system, although the system would be more effective with government support.

Despite some undeniable benefits in terms of empowering non-state actors, blockchain technology is unlikely to overcome existing hierarchies in the international system. In effect, it may even produce new kinds of power asymmetries. Blockchain technology will challenge neither the primacy of states in global governance nor the preponderance of powerful states within the state community. If all states were to voluntarily participate in blockchain-based global governance, they would devise contracts with little obligation, as they must fear guaranteed punishment by smart contracts finding states to be violating their commitments.Footnote 97 If the DAO only entailed contracts with hard obligations, (especially) powerful countries would not be willing to join the DAO, thus limiting its overall effectiveness. The promise of harder commitments that smart contracts can afford thus has the drawback of leaving those states out of its jurisdiction which would need to be constrained the most. The only way to incentivize participation by powerful states – aside from collective mechanisms to allow them to renege on their commitmentsFootnote 98 which are not easily achieved under crypto-law – is to unlock additional benefits for them, such as credible commitments for burden-sharing investments into the liberal order from non-state actors.

At the organization level – pertaining to the governance of blockchains – an increasing use of blockchain technology for global governance creates new power imbalances. The blockchain protocol is often hard-wired by developers, without much input from end-users. Knowledge to set up blockchain platforms is concentrated in the hands of a limited number of tech-savvy people, who can use it to their advantage on design issues – similar to how international bureaucrats can exploit their expertise for their own gain when designing new institutional progeny for member states.Footnote 99 Hence, growing demand for blockchain-empowered systems to govern global challenges will likely empower a transnational elite of software developers at the expense of other societal groups.Footnote 100

One might be tempted to argue that whether blockchain technology will alter the distribution of power in the international system crucially depends on their design. Permissionless blockchains promise to empower non-state actors by disintermediating central actors, although non-state actors can benefit even more from a hierarchically ordered governance system that intertwines these blockchains with permissioned blockchains that central actors would create to harness incentivized individual action within the framework of promoting international cooperation. For permissioned blockchains – typically controlled by central actors like states – the level of empowerment of non-state actors is likely to be limited. A unique focus on design for assessing power issues is limiting nonetheless because the design of blockchains occurs in the shadow of power and therefore will reflect existing hierarchies, with limited potential to make global politics more egalitarian. Considering the implications of blockchain technology for global order, it therefore seems that – as a new technology for decentralized governance – blockchain technology somewhat flattens hierarchies by allowing new actors to influence global politics more effectively than under current arrangements; however, states maintain the ability to control global governance by co-opting the technology to advance their own ends. Therefore, it seems that the rationalist view – expecting blockchain technology to be used by powerful actors to advance their predetermined interests – is not fully convincing. Instead, in line with a constructivist view, governance by blockchain acts to reshape that activity and its meaning.Footnote 101 This coincides with a co-evolutionary perspective on technological change, which argues that technology is not just formed by society but can also be active as structure, institution, or actor.Footnote 102

Conclusion

This paper probed whether and how blockchain technology could enhance global governance, with an illustration for climate governance. Although existing studies emphasize the apparent benefits of the technology related to information-sharing within traditional global governance structures,Footnote 103 this paper sketched out the contours of a DAO comprising various sets of stakeholders interacting through smart contracts to achieve policy goals and to define the process by which future policy decisions will be made. Such a DAO would be implementable with available blockchain technology.

My theoretical analysis has shown that blockchain-enabled functionalities such as smart contracts could be deployed to promote cooperation in three ways: first, by leveraging collective information feeds, thereby helping resolve uncertainty about the state of world and state behaviors; second, to allay distribution problems in an efficient manner; and third, to allow states and other global governance actors to make more credible commitments to each other. Blockchain technology promises to offer new avenues for states to enlarge the set of circumstances under which they are willing to cooperate given ex ante preferences, for instance by leveraging new sources of information and by reducing downstream transaction costs that free up resources to allay distribution problems. Hence, even where scholars have traditionally thought that prospects of cooperation are grim – where states already live on the ‘Pareto frontier’Footnote 104 – a once-established blockchain-based global governance system with the aforementioned functionalities could enlarge the scope for cooperation.

My paper also interrogated whether blockchain-based global governance would be desirable. Although over-optimism that blockchain governance could instill liberal ideals into global politics must be dampened, there are undeniable benefits of blockchain-based governance compared to traditional global governance. The benefits of a blockchain-based governance system would be enhanced public accountability, through unrestricted read-only access to the blockchain, as well as increased democratic legitimacy, by including relevant stakeholders (such as NGOs) as participants in the consensus mechanism and by facilitating the transition from the current system in which power is distributed according to (largely non-transparent) lobbying contributions toward blockchain-based governance where parties stake publicly for their interests. In addition, traditionally underprivileged stakeholders would likely be empowered as they hold important local information that would feed the oracles on which smart contracts depend to settle transactions. Blockchain technology also affords these stakeholders an opportunity to securely transact with each other, without relying on central authorities for this purpose. The costs of blockchain-based global governance are related to the well-known IR result that institutional design occurs in the shadow of power. States have incentives to establish some blockchain-based governance systems given that they can be designed not to threaten their own survival.Footnote 105 This suggests the continued relevance of the liberal-institutionalist argument that a functional theory of cooperation is incomplete without consideration of political structures, specifically the distribution of power. It also suggests that blockchain-based global governance is unlikely to fulfill the normative ideal of ‘fully-automated liberalism’ in the shape under which it would ever come to fruition.

Although my case study considered climate policy, it might be useful to probe its generalizability to other issue areas. In many issue areas, blockchain-based governance would run counter to the interests of powerful actors, specifically influential states that would lose opportunities for power exercise if global affairs were governed by crypto-law. In some instances, smart contracts may also be collectively unprofitable because states would face high costs from the inflexibility that they imply – especially under conditions of uncertainty about the state of the world. Climate governance – given favorable conditions such as issue complexity and unmet potential for cooperation, resourceful domestic stakeholders with pro-cooperation preferences, and a need for information systems that can validate climate-related events and policy measures – thus seems to be a most-likely case where a blockchain-based system is not completely out of question. Other issue areas with similar features and thus similar amenability to blockchain-based governance include trade, finance, and development.

Four issues merit particular attention in future research. First, who benefits and who loses from adopting blockchain-based global governance? A detailed answer to this question would provide further indication of how likely such adoption is under the given power distribution. The distributional consequences for states are not obvious, not least because they would hinge on the initial allocation of voting rights in blockchain-based governance systems. A once-established blockchain-based governance system would make the abuse of power more costly, whereas allowing for bottom-up governance by weaker actors, like developing countries and non-governmental organizations, through smart contracts. A related issue is how blockchain-based governance affects principal–agent relationships between international organizations and member states.Footnote 106 Blockchain technology could affect these relationships in multiple ways, depending on which functionalities are adopted. At the very least, international organizations would become more accountable to states to the extent that states would be able to more easily monitor the work of these organizations if they recorded their operations on the blockchain. At the extreme, under fully-automated liberalism, international organizations would be tasked primarily with validating external events and providing technical assistance, at the expense of fiduciary oversight roles and (possibly) policy coordination, which would be handled more efficiently through smart contracts. Clearly, this disintermediation potential of blockchains would raise opposition from international organizations.

A second issue – related to the first one – pertains to the governance of blockchain protocols.Footnote 107 For example, whereas the Bitcoin network implies fully decentralized governance, the governance of the Bitcoin protocol is highly centralized – controlled by its developersFootnote 108 – and the Bitcoin consensus mechanism incentivizes the creation of centralized mining pools. The DAO represents a departure from centralized control over the blockchain protocol. Its internal governance rules can be altered through quasi-democratic consensus – with voting rights depending on the ownership of tokens. For some, the 2016 DAO hack proved the failure of the DAO concept,Footnote 109 whereas for others, the resorting to off-chain solutions represented a ‘meta-governance structure’ that was ‘off-chain’ but ‘bound by the design of the technology’.Footnote 110 Ultimately, the responsibility rests with actors collectively to decide through which mechanisms governance rules can be adapted. In this context, more research would be necessary to explore what kind of quorum is needed to simultaneously avoid control of the network by a cartel of powerful participants, whereas also preventing deadlock where a minority of nodes censor all new members.

A third area is challenges arising from the lack of interoperability with the off-chain world. A key challenge is that many oracles are centralized, which makes them vulnerable as single points of failure whereas potentially undermining the veracity of data input to the blockchain. However, there are promising attempts to solve the ‘oracle problem’. For example, Chainlink orchestrates a decentralized network of oracles relying on multiple sources of external information to evaluate queries from smart contracts in a trustworthy manner.Footnote 111 Even if the oracle problem can be solved, there remains the question of how to constrain abusive uses of ‘predictive analytics’ afforded by the growing availability of ‘big data’ from the blockchain. This issue tends to be overlooked by scholarship hailing the ever-closer integration of blockchain with IoT devices.Footnote 112 Although appropriate blockchain designs can likely mitigate this problem, more research is necessary.

A final area of inquiry would take up the challenge of developing metrics on the relative effectiveness of blockchain-based global governance against its present alternative. Such an analysis will remain impossible pending the actual use of blockchain and the generation of related data. If blockchain-based global governance were to be implemented, the focus of inquiry would be to explain why some states participate in it whereas other states do not. In this regard, existing research in political economy – notably on the adoption of new technologies such as the internetFootnote 113 – provides testable arguments. Although states cannot prevent individuals from using permissionless blockchains (unless they completely shut down the internet, which could then prompt individuals to use satellite technologies to connect to it), their participation in permissioned blockchains is voluntary. A straightforward prediction would be that demand for permissionless blockchains by non-state actors is higher in autocracies, whereas autocratic governments are less likely to join permissioned blockchains as their disutility of being exposed to transparency is greater. This exemplary discussion shows that the unique features of blockchain technology provide for new avenues of testing pertinent theories of IR and domestic politics.

Acknowledgements

I am particularly grateful to Christian Arnold, Malcolm Campbell-Verduyn, Giorgio Caselli, Simone Dietrich, Liane Hartnett, Robert Keohane, Andreas Kern, Axel Michaelowa, Cian O'Driscoll, Mette Eilstrup-Sangiovanni, Jason Sharman, Ian Shields, Ty Solomon, Tom Wilkinson, Joseph Zammit, Rene Reinsberg, Marek Olszewski, Sep Kamvar, the IT editors, and three anonymous reviewers for fruitful discussions and valuable comments.

Conflict of interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

Footnotes

4 Wright and De Filippi (Reference Wright and De Filippi2015).

9 Abbott and Snidal (Reference Abbott and Snidal2000), Simmons and Danner (Reference Simmons and Danner2010), Voeten (Reference Voeten2014).

11 Zwitter (Reference Zwitter2015).

14 Heeks and Bailur (Reference Heeks and Bailur2007), Zysman and Newman (Reference Zysman and Newman2006).

15 Krisch (Reference Krisch2017), Mattern and Zarakol (Reference Mattern and Zarakol2016), Musgrave and Nexon (Reference Musgrave and Nexon2018).

16 Just and Latzer (Reference Just and Latzer2017).

17 My definition of blockchain technology is deliberately broad and includes what some prefer to call ‘distributed ledger technology’ (DLT), which often entails limited uses of the technology for the purpose of enhancing transparency, typically under the control of centralized actors (Hütten and Thiemann Reference Hütten, Thiemann and Malcolm2018).

19 Valkenburgh (Reference Valkenburgh2016).

21 Valkenburgh (Reference Valkenburgh2016).

22 Nakamoto (Reference Nakamoto2008).

23 Sklaroff (Reference Sklaroff2017).

25 Swan (Reference Swan2015, 22).

26 Buterin (Reference Buterin2014).

28 https://t.co/tieQoQ9uLe (accessed 27 October 2018).

30 Rocamora and Amellina (Reference Rocamora and Amellina2018, 14).

31 There are many blockchain platforms which can implement smart contracts. Ethereum – a generalized blockchain – allows for such applications through the Ethereum virtual machine (EVM) – a computer running on top of the Ethereum blockchain that can both encode programs and execute them (Swan Reference Swan2015, 21). In principle, similar functionality is provided by Hyperledger, an umbrella project of open-source blockchains started by the Linux Foundation and supported by industry (Tapscott and Tapscott Reference Tapscott and Tapscott2017).

32 Diedrich (Reference Diedrich2016).

33 Tapscott and Tapscott (Reference Tapscott and Tapscott2016, 104).

35 DApps can be built on the EVM. By running on a blockchain (such as Ethereum) they import its desirable properties such as pseudonymity, censor-proofness, auditability, and transparency (Swan Reference Swan2015).

37 The simplest DAO design involves a piece of self-modifying code that changes if a qualified majority of members agree on a change. Although code is theoretically immutable, it can be de-facto muted by having chunks of the code in separate contracts, and having the address of which contracts to call stored in the modifiable storage.

38 DAOs would be governed by three transaction types, distinguished by the data provided in the transaction: proposal transactions, transactions to vote for a proposal, and transactions to finalize a transaction provided enough votes were made (Buerger Reference Buerger2016).

39 There also is a literature on how DAOs can maintain the social contract within nation-states (Atzori Reference Atzori2015). This is the application of my argument that blockchains can deliver solutions to collective action problems without a hegemon to the national level.

41 For some, this reliance on a ‘hard fork’ as a form of meta-governance represents a deliberate governance decision, showing that the DAO was in fact viable (Zwitter and Hazenberg Reference Zwitter and Hazenberg2020).

42 In practice, smart devices may be tamper-proof only under certain conditions. Consider a solar sensor that could be manipulated by shining an UV lamp on it. And yet, decentralized oracle networks such as the ones afforded by ChainLink are a first good attempt to address the ‘oracle problem’ (Orcutt Reference Orcutt2018).

44 In the case of Augur, described below, reporters receive half of the fees in the system multiplied by the token shares they own. Because participants of the prediction market have an incentive to not undermine the value of the token, they have incentives to truthfully report.

45 At least two blockchain-based prediction markets are operational. The first is Augur (https://augur.net/, accessed 22 October 2017) a decentralized prediction market which runs on a network of servers and cannot be manipulated. All participants report on the outcome using a consensus-based mechanism. Safe payment is ensured via smart contracts. A second is Gnosis (https://gnosis.io/, accessed 21 January 2018), which operates ‘prediction market platforms allow[ing] anyone to utilize customized forecasting applications [using] an entirely new asset class: conditional tokens, which make event outcomes tradeable and are also a powerful tool for information discovery’.

46 Rosenau (Reference Rosenau1995, 1).

47 Just and Latzer (Reference Just and Latzer2017).

49 Barber (Reference Barber2013), Baumann (Reference Baumann2018), Bulkeley et al. (Reference Bulkeley2014).

54 See http://carbongrid.io (accessed 10 May 2018). Also, www.cleancoins.io (accessed 10 May 2018) is a project to assess the carbon footprint of blockchains and scout solutions to reduce their emissions.

55 www.solarcoin.org (accessed 10 May 2018). A similar project is LO3 energy (Aganaba-Jeanty et al., Reference Aganaba-Jeanty, Anissimov and Fitzgerald2017).

56 Wigley and Cary (Reference Wigley and Cary2017, 28).

58 Falkner (Reference Falkner2016).

59 UNFCCC (2017).

60 Wigley and Cary (Reference Wigley and Cary2017, 28).

62 In fact, research shows that tree planting has enormous potential to capture emissions (https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2019/jul/04/planting-billions-trees-best-tackle-climate-crisis-scientists-canopy-emissions, accessed 5 July 2019) although other measures could be eligible.

63 The Guardian, ‘Donald Trump confirms US will quit Paris climate agreement’, accessible via https://www.theguardian.com/environment/2017/jun/01/donald-trump-confirms-us-will-quit-paris-climate-deal (23 May 2018).

64 Staking of deposits is another possibility to tie the hands of future governments to exit from the Paris Agreement. If then-US president Barack Obama had staked money on the agreement, the effect of the subsequent US exit could have been fully neutralized as the staked deposit would have been channeled to the Green Climate Fund to support adaptation projects.

65 De Filippi and Hassan (Reference De Filippi and Hassan2016).

66 Wigley and Carey (Reference Wigley and Cary2017).

67 Abbott and Snidal (Reference Abbott and Snidal1998), Dietrich and Murdie (Reference Dietrich and Murdie2017), Lundgren (Reference Lundgren2016).

69 Arruñada (Reference Arruñada2018), GSMA (2017), Sklaroff (Reference Sklaroff2017).

70 Another issue is that blockchain-based prediction markets also need to be regulated by central authorities to prevent their use for clandestine purposes – for example, betting on the assassination of a democratic incumbent (Sklaroff Reference Sklaroff2017).

72 Keohane (Reference Keohane1984).

77 Similarly, international law stipulates that a treaty commitment is not binding until a sufficient number of states have ratified it. This provision allays concerns about other states obtaining relative gains from delaying ratification. It can be easily implemented in ‘blockchain law’ using multi-party escrows (Diedrich Reference Diedrich2016).

80 An early non-digital analog to staking is royal intermarriage. Blockchains extend this notion further by allowing arbitrary resources to be staked on commitments.

81 Campbell-Verduyn et al. (Reference Campbell-Verduyn, Goguen and Porter2019). Here, a related point would be how to ensure that cryptographic certificates – which are needed to identify parties on a blockchain – would not be stolen. In the event of loss of these keys, there would be no way to differentiate between legitimate and fraudulent transactions. I thank an anonymous reviewer for highlighting this point.

82 Sklaroff (Reference Sklaroff2017). The issue of how to fix coding bugs in smart contracts is discussed among researchers. Some argue that code needs the law as a fallback option, others maintain that rules for contingencies can be agreed upon by parties upfront.

83 Hart and Moore (Reference Hart and Moore1999).

84 The inflexibility of smart contracts also poses elevated transactional risks. Smart contracts – even if they contain programing errors – are unstoppable; human discretion to weed out human errors is not part of their protocol (Sklaroff Reference Sklaroff2017). Although notarial certification could be required for such contracts to execute, this would practically eliminate their efficiency advantages arising from automation.

87 This terminology is due to Jervis (Reference Jervis1999).

88 Slaughter (Reference Slaughter2016).

89 Microsoft wants to eradicate its carbon footprint by going emissions ‘negative’ by 2030, https://edition.cnn.com/2020/01/16/tech/microsoft-climate-pledge-2030/index.html (accessed 17 January 2020).

91 Haddock (Reference Haddock1999).

93 Ikenberry (Reference Ikenberry2001).

94 Needless to say, full automation is an ideal type here as there will always be some degree of human control retained, even if it is just the option of shutting down the internet.

95 GSMA (2017, 25).

99 Johnson and Urpelainen (Reference Johnson and Urpelainen2014).

101 Campbell-Verduyn (Reference Campbell-Verduyn2018, 8).

102 Dolata and Werle (Reference Dolata and Werle2007).

103 Chapron (Reference Chapron2017), Rocamora and Amellina (Reference Rocamora and Amellina2018), UNFCCC (2017).

104 Krasner (Reference Krasner1991).

105 A permissioned system is fully controlled by states, whereas a permissionless system circumvents them. Whether or not blockchains eliminate the nation-state depends on their designs.

107 Campbell-Verduyn and Hütten (Reference Campbell-Verduyn and Hütten2019).

108 De Filippi and Loveluck (Reference De Filippi and Loveluck2016).

110 Zwitter and Hazenberg (Reference Zwitter and Hazenberg2020).

111 Orcutt (Reference Orcutt2018). The Chainlink system supports many approaches of information aggregation from several oracles and has built-in features to incentivize truthful reporting and preventing coordinated malicious attacks (Ellis et al. Reference Ellis, Ari and Sergey2017).

113 Milner (Reference Milner2006).

References

Abbott, Kenneth W., and Snidal, Duncan. 1998. “Why States Act Through Formal International Organizations.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (1): 332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbott, Kenneth W., and Snidal, Duncan. 2000. “Hard and Soft Law in International Governance.” International Organization 54 (3): 421–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aganaba-Jeanty, Timiebi, Anissimov, Sam, and Fitzgerald, Oonagh E.. 2017. Blockchain ClimateCup Round Table. Toronto.Google Scholar
Andersen, Louise Riis. 2019. “Curb Your Enthusiasm: Middle-Power Liberal Internationalism and the Future of the United Nations.” International Journal 74 (1): 4764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, Benito. 2018. “Impersonal Exchange.” Minnesota Journal of Law, Science, and Technology 19: 55105.Google Scholar
Atzori, Marcella. 2015. “Blockchain Technology and Decentralized Governance: Is the State Still Necessary?SSRN Electronic Journal. http://www.ssrn.com/abstract=2709713. (Accessed 20 July 2018).Google Scholar
Barber, Benjamin R. 2013. If Mayors Ruled the World: Dysfunctional Nations, Rising Cities. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Barnett, Michael N., and Finnemore, Martha. 2004. Rules for the World: International Organizations in Global Politics. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Baumann, Tom. 2018. “Using Blockchain to Achieve Climate Policy Outcomes.” IETA Insights Policy Brief.Google Scholar
Beckert, Jens. 1999. “Agency, Entrepreneurs, and Institutional Change. The Role of Strategic Choice and Institutionalized Practices in Organizations.” Organization Studies 20 (5): 777–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendrath, Ralf, and Mueller, Milton. 2011. “The End of the Net as We Know It? Deep Packet Inspection and Internet Governance.” New Media and Society 13 (7): 1142–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boylan, David. 2001. Defusing Democracy: Central Bank Independence and the Transition from Authoritarian Rule. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Chris, Nardin, Terry, and Rengger, Nicholas. 2002. International Relations in Political Thought: Texts from the Ancient Greeks to the First World War. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buerger, Hans-Helge. 2016. “Ethereum White Paper: A Next-Generation Smart Contract and Decentralized Application Platform.” https://github.com/ethereum/wiki/wiki/White-Paper.Google Scholar
Bulkeley, Harriet et al. 2014. Transnational Climate Change Governance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buterin, Vitalik. 2014. A next-Generation Smart Contract and Decentralized Application Platform.Google Scholar
Campbell-Verduyn, Malcolm. 2018. Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains, and Global Governance. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Campbell-Verduyn, Malcolm, and Goguen, Marcel. 2018. “The Mutual Constitution of Technology and Global Governance: Bitcoin, Blockchains, and the International Anti-Money-Laundering Regime.” In Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains, and Global Governance, edited by Malcolm, Campbell-Verduyn, 6987. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Campbell-Verduyn, Malcolm, Goguen, Marcel, and Porter, Tony. 2019. “Finding Fault Lines in Long Chains of Financial Information.” Review of International Political Economy 26 (5): 911–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell-Verduyn, Malcolm, and Hütten, Moritz. 2019. “Anticipating Decentralization Through Protocological Control: International Organizations and the Standardization of Blockchain Technology within Financial/Security Infrastructures.” University of Groningen.Google Scholar
Chapron, Guillaume. 2017. “The Environment Needs Cryptogovernance.” Nature 545 (7655): 403–5.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Conceição-Heldt, Eugénia da. 2017. “Regaining Control of Errant Agents? Agency Slack at the European Commission and the World Health Organization.” Cooperation and Conflict 52 (4): 469–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dacin, Tina M., Goodstein, Jerry, and Scott, Richard W.. 2002. “Institutional Theory and Institutional Change: Introduction to the Special Research Forum.” The Academy of Management Journal 45 (1): 4356.Google Scholar
Dai, Xinyuan. 2007. International Institutions and National Policies. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Filippi, Primavera, and Loveluck, Benjamin. 2016. “The Invisible Politics of Bitcoin: Governance Crisis of a Decentralized Infrastructure.” Internet Policy Review 5 (4): 132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Filippi, Primavera, and Hassan, Samer. 2016. “Blockchain technology as a regulatory technology: From code is law to law is code.” First Monday, 21(12): https://doi.org/10.5210/fm.v21i12.7113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeNardis, Laura. 2014. The Global War for Internet Governance. New Haven: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diedrich, Henning. 2016. Ethereum: Blockchains, Digital Assets, Smart Contracts, Decentralized Autonomous Organizations. London: Wildfire Publishing.Google Scholar
Dietrich, Simone, and Murdie, Amanda. 2017. “Human Rights Shaming Through INGOs and Foreign Aid Delivery.” Review of International Organizations 12 (1): 95120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, Frank, Simmons, Beth A., and Garrett, Geoffrey. 2007. “The Global Diffusion of Public Policies: Social Construction, Coercion, Competition, or Learning?Annual Review of Sociology 33 (1): 449–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dolata, Ulrich, and Werle, Raymund. 2007. “‘Bringing Technology Back in’: Technik Als Einflussfaktor Sozioökonomischen Und Institutionellen Wandels.” In Gesellschaft Und Die Macht Der Technik: Sozioökonomischer Und Institutioneller Wandel Durch Technisierung, edited by Ulrich Dolata, and Raymund Werle, 1543. Frankfurt: Campus.Google Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Barsoom, Peter N.. 1996. “Is the Good News about Compliance Good News about Cooperation?International Organization 50 (3): 379406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DuPont, Quinn. 2018. “Experiments in Algorithmic Governance: A History and Ethnography of ‘The DAO,’ a Failed Decentralized Autonomous Organization.” In Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains, and Global Governance, edited by Malcolm, Campbell-Verduyn, 157–77. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ellis, Steve, Ari, Juels, and Sergey, Nazarov. 2017. “ChainLink: A Decentralized Oracle Network.” White Paper v1.0. https://crushcrypto.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/09/LINK-Whitepaper.pdf (accessed 1 January 2020).Google Scholar
Falkner, Robert. 2016. “The Paris Agreement and the New Logic of International Climate Politics.” International Affairs 92 (5): 1107–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49 (3): 379414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fu, Bailu, Shu, Zhan, and Liu, Xiaogang. 2018. “Blockchain Enhanced Emission Trading Framework in Fashion Apparel Manufacturing Industry.” Sustainability 10 (4): 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, Erin R. 2015. Money and Multilateralism: How Funding Rules Constitute IO Governance. International Theory 7 (1): 162–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GSMA. 2017. Blockchain for Development: Emerging Opportunities for Mobile, Identity and Aid. London. https://www.gsma.com/mobilefordevelopment/wp-content/uploads/2017/12/Blockchain-for-Development.pdf.Google Scholar
Haddock, Bruce. 1999. “State and Nation in Mazzini's Political Thought.” History of Political Thought 20 (2): 313–36.Google Scholar
Hale, Thomas. 2016. “’All Hands on Deck’: The Paris Agreement and Nonstate Climate Action.” Global Environmental Politics 16 (3): 1222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Moore, John. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 115–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heeks, Richard, and Bailur, Savita. 2007. “Analyzing E-Government Research: Perspectives, Philosophies, Theories, Methods, and Practice.” Government Information Quarterly 24 (2): 243–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hooghe, Liesbet, Lenz, Tobias, and Marks, Gary. 2018. “Contested World Order: The Delegitimation of International Governance.” Review of International Organizations 14 (4): 731–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hütten, Moritz, and Thiemann, Matthias. 2018. “Moneys at the Margins: From Political Experiment to Cashless Societies.” In Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains, and Global Governance, edited by Malcolm, Campbell-Verduyn, 2547. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, John G. 2001. After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order after Major Wars. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ikenberry, John G. 2018. “The End of Liberal International Order?International Affairs 94 (1): 723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jasanoff, Sheila. 2004. States of Knowledge: The Co-Production of Science and the Social Order. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jervis, Robert. 1999. “Realism, Neoliberalism, and Cooperation: Understanding the Debate.” International Security 24 (1): 4263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Tana, and Heiss, Andrew. 2018. “Liberal Institutionalism.” In International Organization and Global Governance, edited by. Thomas, G Weiss and Wilkinson, Rorden, 123–34. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Tana, and Urpelainen, Johannes. 2014. “International Bureaucrats and the Formation of Intergovernmental Organizations: Institutional Design Discretion Sweetens the Pot.” International Organization 68 (1): 177209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Just, Natascha, and Latzer, Michael. 2017. “Governance by Algorithms: Reality Construction by Algorithmic Selection on the Internet.” Media, Culture and Society 39 (2): 238–58.Google Scholar
Kelley, Judith G., and Simmons, Beth A.. 2015. “Politics by Number: Indicators as Social Pressure in International Relations.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (1): 5570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O., and Martin, Lisa L.. 1995. “The Promise of Institutionalist Theory.” International Security 20 (1): 3951.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kern, Andreas, Reinsberg, Bernhard, and Rau-Göhring, Matthias. 2019. IMF conditionality and Central Bank Independence. European Journal of Political Economy 59: 212–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koremenos, Barbara, Lipson, Charles, and Snidal, Duncan. 2001. “The Rational Design of International Institutions.” International Organization 55 (4): 761–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasner, Stephen D. 1991. “Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier.” World Politics 43 (April): 336–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krisch, Nico. 2017. “Liquid Authority in Global Governance.” International Theory 9 (2): 237–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishna, Arvind, Fleming, Martin, and Assefa, Solomon. 2017. “Instilling Digital Trust.” In Digital Revolutions in Public Finance, edited by. Sanjeev, Gupta, Keen, Michael, Shah, Alpa, and Verdier, Geneviève, 173–97. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence. 1999. Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Lundgren, Magnus. 2016. “Which Type of International Organizations Can Settle Civil Wars?The Review of International Organizations 12 (4): 613–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Manulak, Michael W. 2016. “Leading by Design: Informal Influence and International Secretariats.” Review of International Organizations 12 (4): 497522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Lisa L. 2017. “International Institutions: Weak Commitments and Costly Signals.” International Theory 9 (3): 353–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mattern, Janice Bially, and Zarakol, Ayşe. 2016. “Hierarchies in World Politics.” International Organization 70 (3): 623–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 2006. “The Digital Divide: The Role of Political Institutions in Technology Diffusion.” Comparative Political Studies 39 (2): 176–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morrow, James D. 1994. “International Organization Foundation Modeling the Forms of International Cooperation: Distribution versus Information.” International Organization 48 (3): 387423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Musgrave, Paul, and Nexon, Daniel H. 2018. “Defending Hierarchy from the Moon to the Indian Ocean: Symbolic Capital and Political Dominance in Early Modern China and the Cold War.” International Organization, 72 (3), 591–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakamoto, Satoshi. 2008. “Bitcoin: A Peer-to-Peer Electronic Cash System.” https://bitcoin.org/bitcoin.pdf.Google Scholar
Narayanan, A et al. 2016. Bitcoin and Cryptocurrency Technologies: A Comprehensive Introduction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Nielson, Daniel L., and Tierney, Michael J.. 2003. “Delegation to International Organizations: Agency Theory and World Bank Environmental Reform.” International Organization 57 (2): 241–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orcutt, Mike. 2018. Blockchain smart contracts are finally good for something in the real world. MIT Technology Review (19 November 2018).Google Scholar
Parízek, Michal. 2016. “Control, Soft Information, and the Politics of International Organizations Staffing.” Review of International Organizations 12 (4): 559–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pisa, Michael. 2018. Reassessing Expectations for Blockchain and Development. Washington, DC: USAID.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinsberg, Bernhard. 2019. “Blockchain technology and the governance of foreign aid.” Journal of Institutional Economics 15 (3): 413–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reyna, Ana, Martín, Cristian, Chen, Jaime, Soler, Enrique, and Díaz, Manuel. 2018. “On Blockchain and its Integration with IoT. Challenges and Opportunities.” Future Generation Computer Systems 88: 173–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocamora, Alexis, and Amellina, Aryanie. 2018. Blockchain Applications and the Sustainable Development Goals: Analysis of Blockchain Technology's Potential in Creating a Sustainable Future. Kamiyamaguchi.Google Scholar
Rosenau, James N. 1995. “Governance in the Twenty-First Century.” Global Governance 1 (1): 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosendorff, Peter B., and Milner, Helen V.. 2001. “The Optimal Design of International Trade Institutions: Uncertainty and Escape Clauses.” International Organization 55 (4): 829–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ruggie, John Gerard. 1975. “International Responses to Technology: Concepts and Trends.” International Organization 29 (3): 557–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2010. “Treaty Compliance and Violation.” Annual Review of Political Science 13 (1): 273–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A., and Danner, Allison. 2010. “Credible Commitments and the International Criminal Court.” International Organization 64 (2): 225–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmons, Beth A., and Elkins, Z.. 2004. “The Globalization of Liberalization: Policy Diffusion in the International Political Economy.” American Political Science Review 98 (1): 171–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sklaroff, Jeremy M. 2017. “Smart Contracts and the Cost of Inflexibility.” University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Law 166: 263303.Google Scholar
Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2016. “How to Succeed in the Networked World: A Grand Strategy for the Digital Age.” Foreign Affairs 95: 7689.Google Scholar
Stein, Arthur A. 1982. “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World.” International Organization 36 (2): 299324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, Arthur A. 2009. “Neoliberal Institutionalism.” In The Oxford Handbook of International Relations, edited by Christian, Reus-Smit and Snidal, Duncan, 121. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Stone, Randall W. 2011. Controlling Institutions: International Organizations and the Global Economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swan, Melanie. 2015. Blockchain: Blueprint for a New Economy. Sebastopol, CA: O'Reilly Media, Inc.Google Scholar
Szabo, Nick. 1994. Smart Contracts.Google Scholar
Tallberg, Jonas, Sommerer, Thomas, and Squatrito, Theresa. 2016. “Democratic Memberships in International Organizations: Sources of Institutional Design.” Review of International Organizations 11 (1): 5987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tapscott, Don, and Tapscott, Alex. 2016. Blockchain Revolution: How the Technology Behind Bitcoin Is Changing Money, Business, and the World. New York: Penguin Random House.Google Scholar
Tapscott, Don, and Tapscott, Alex. 2017. “Realizing the Potential of Blockchain a Multistakeholder Approach to the Stewardship of Blockchain and Cryptocurrencies.” Available from www.weforum.org.Google Scholar
Troyjo, Marcos, Quintella, Julia, and Da Silva, Fracisco. 2017. Building ITTI: Intelligent Tech & Trade Initiative. Sao Paolo. http://itti-global.org/2017/12/.Google Scholar
Truby, Jon. 2018. “Decarbonizing Bitcoin: Law and Policy Choices for Reducing the Energy Consumption of Blockchain Technologies and Digital Currencies.” Energy Research & Social Science, 44: 399410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UNFCCC. 2017. “How Blockchain Technology Could Boost Climate Action.” https://unfccc.int/news/how-blockchain-technology-could-boost-climate-action (30 March 2018).Google Scholar
Valkenburgh, Peter Van. 2016. Open Matters: Why Permissionless Blockchains are Essential to the Future of the Internet. CoinDesk.Google Scholar
Vaubel, Roland, Dreher, Axel, and Soylu, Ugurlu. 2007. “Staff Growth in International Organizations: A Principal-Agent Problem? An Empirical Analysis.” Public Choice 133 (3–4): 275–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voeten, Erik. 2014. “Does Participation in International Organizations Increase Cooperation?Review of International Organizations 9 (3): 285308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Stein, Jana. 2005. “Do Treaties Constrain or Screen? Selection Bias and Treaty Compliance.” American Political Science Review 99 (4): 611–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wigley, Bob, and Cary, Nicolas. 2017. The Future is Decentralised: Blockchains, Distributed Ledgers, and the Future of Sustainable Development.Google Scholar
Wilson, Woodrow. 2006. Essential Writings and Speeches of the Scholar-President. New York: NYU Press.Google Scholar
Wood, Gavin. 2017. Polkadot: Vision for a Heterogeneous Multi-Chain Framework. https://github.com/w3f/polkadot-white-paper/raw/master/PolkaDotPaper.pdf.Google Scholar
Wright, Aaron, and De Filippi, Primavera. 2015. Decentralized Blockchain Technology and the Rise of Lex Cryptographia.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ying-Hsieh, Ying, Vergne, Jean-Philippe, and Wang, Sha. 2018. “The Internal and External Governance of Blockchain-Based Organizations: Evidence from Cryptocurrencies.” In Bitcoin and Beyond: Cryptocurrencies, Blockchains, and Global Governance, edited by Malcolm, Campbell-Verduyn, 4868. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Zwitter, Andrej. 2015. “Big Data and International Relations.” Ethics and International Affairs 29 (4): 377–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zwitter, Andrej, and Hazenberg, Jilles. 2020. “Decentralized Network Governance: Blockchain Technology and the Future of Regulation.” Frontiers in Blockchain 3: 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zysman, John, and Newman, Abraham L.. 2006. How Revolutionary Was the Digital Revolution?: National Responses, Market Transitions, and Global Technology. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar