Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-skm99 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T01:46:08.889Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Determinants of Government Membership at the Subnational Level: Empirical Evidence from Large Cities in Germany (1999–2016)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 October 2021

Martin Gross*
Affiliation:
Geschwister Scholl Institute of Political Science, University of Munich, Munich, Germany
*
*Corresponding author. Email: martin.gross@gsi.uni-muenchen.de
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Coalition governments prevail at the European subnational level. Although some studies explain the formation of subnational government coalitions, we know little about the determinants of individual parties' likelihood of joining such coalitions. This article aims to fill this gap in empirical and theoretical ways. It shows that an important institutional constraint matters for political actors' strategies when forming subnational coalitions: the party affiliation of the directly elected head of the executive. Being the party of the head of the executive or being ideologically close to that party significantly increases a party's likelihood of joining a coalition. The empirical evidence results from multinomial choice models using a novel data set on subnational parties' likelihood of joining 92 coalition governments at the local level in Germany between 1999 and 2016. The findings have substantive implications for subnational institutional settings resembling ‘mixed’ political systems (i.e. neither purely presidential nor purely parliamentarian).

Type
Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/), which permits non-commercial re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is unaltered and is properly cited. The written permission of Cambridge University Press must be obtained for commercial re-use or in order to create a derivative work.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Government and Opposition Limited

Explaining government formations is one of the most flourishing research agendas of the last few decades. Scholars of government formations nowadays largely turn their attention to empirically testing hypotheses by combining conceptual, formal models with statistical tests (see most prominently Martin and Stevenson Reference Martin and Stevenson2001, Reference Martin and Stevenson2010). From the early 2000s the research agenda on government formations began to broaden by, first, turning its attention to the application of coalition theories to the subnational level, ranging from analysing the determinants of government formations at the regional and local level (e.g. Bäck Reference Bäck2003a; Bäck et al. Reference Bäck, Debus, Müller and Bäck2013; Skjæveland et al. Reference Skjæveland, Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen2007), to the duration of local government formations (e.g. Blockmans et al. Reference Blockmans, Geys, Heyndels and Mahieu2016) and the termination of governments at the regional level (e.g. Martínez-Cantó and Bergmann Reference Martínez-Cantó and Bergmann2020). Second, and more recently, scholars started to switch their focus from explaining the likelihood of a government to be formed to analysing a party's likelihood of being part of, or heading, a government (Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2011, Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2012; Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015). However, these two strands of the literature have not yet been combined in one single empirical contribution. By applying existing coalition theories and theoretical expectations determining the likelihood of parties' government membership at the subnational level, this article answers the following research question: Who gets into subnational governments and what are the determinants of government membership at the subnational level?

Studies on parties' chances of entering coalition governments are almost exclusively conducted at the national level (e.g. Döring and Hellström Reference Döring and Hellström2013; Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015; Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2011, Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2012; Savage Reference Savage2014; Warwick Reference Warwick1996). Our knowledge regarding the determinants of parties' likelihood of entering coalitions at other political levels is exclusively based on insights from local politics in Sweden and Catalonia. For the Swedish case, Hanna Bäck (Reference Bäck2003a, Reference Bäck2008, Reference Bäck, Giannetti and Benoit2009) shows that a party is more likely to become a member of a coalition the more seats it controls, if it is the median party, and if the party is characterized by low levels of factionalization and intraparty democracy. One major drawback of these findings is the exclusive focus on individual party factors and their effects on a party's likelihood of entering a coalition, without taking into account that a party's probability of joining a coalition does not only depend on its own characteristics but also on the features of the potential coalitions of which the party would be a member (Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015). Studies on parties' likelihood of entering local government coalitions must account for party-level and coalition-level characteristics. In a recent study on local government formations in Catalonian municipalities, Albert Falcó-Gimeno (Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020) adopts this approach and shows that an increase in seat share of a party significantly increases the likelihood that the party will enter local government. Being the incumbent party, however, only increases the chances of re-entering government if the incumbent government coalition can re-form again. Furthermore, a party's likelihood of entering local government increases if the party is ideologically close to the median legislator in the local council.

Yet, I argue that individual parties' likelihood of entering government at the subnational level is influenced not only by classic political actors' policy-, office- and vote-seeking incentives (Müller and Strøm Reference Müller and Strøm1999), but also by an additional institutional constraint not covered in the above-mentioned studies on local government formation in Catalonia and Sweden: the party affiliation of the directly elected head of the executive. The affiliation of this central figure should affect the likelihood that a party will enter subnational government, increasing its chances if the party is the subnational branch of the head of the executive's party or if it is ideologically close to the head of the executive's party. This argument is not restricted to the local level but can also be transferred to the regional level if regional heads of the executives are elected directly by the voters (e.g. in Greece, Indonesia, Italy, Slovakia).

Using a novel data set on local government formations in Germany (1999–2016), the empirical findings show, first, that the party of the directly elected head of the executive – that is, the mayor – has an advantage in the local coalition formation game. The party of the head of the executive is significantly more likely to become a coalition member than other parties. Second, ideological proximity to the head of the executive's party is advantageous for parties if they want to be part of a coalition. Third, other determinants of local government membership resemble the determinants of government membership at the national level – parties with a higher seat share are more likely to become coalition members as well as parties of the incumbent coalition if they can re-form this coalition. The findings highlight the emanating effects of directly electing the head of the executive on individual parties' likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions. Accounting for this additional institutional constraint provides a more nuanced picture of how party- and coalition-level characteristics affect individual parties' chances of entering subnational governments.

Party-level characteristics affecting parties' likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions

Leaving aside the possibility of securing office by obtaining an absolute parliamentary majority, a party's chances of entering government are not only determined by its own characteristics but are also dependent on the characteristics of the potential coalitions to which the party belongs (see Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015). The following theoretical expectations regarding a party's likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions primarily focus on party-level characteristics, whereas expectations regarding the effects of coalition-level characteristics on subnational government formation will be used as control variables and elaborated in the third section of this contribution.

The first expectation considers the specific incentives direct elections of heads of the executive create for subnational political actors to form government coalitions in situations where no single party gained an absolute majority. Regional presidents in Italy (see Schakel and Massetti Reference Schakel and Massetti2018; Wilson Reference Wilson2015) or local mayors in most Western and Eastern European countries play a crucial role at the respective levels of political decision-making. Regularly they are head of the subnational administration, shape the subnational policy agenda and thus have a powerful role in day-to-day governance. Regarding government formation, however, it makes a difference if a head of the executive is directly or indirectly elected. When the head of the executive is elected by local council members (as in Sweden or in Catalonia) or members of the regional parliament, and when no party gains a parliamentary majority, a government coalition forms and subsequently elects as head of the executive a politician who is a member of one of the government coalition parties. No party has a significant institutional advantage in becoming the head of the executive's party. Therefore, what matters in local coalition formation in such ‘quasi-parliamentarian’ systems are a party's seat share and its ideological position or factionalization, among other things (see Bäck Reference Bäck2003a, Reference Bäck2008, Reference Bäck, Giannetti and Benoit2009; Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020).

With the implementation of direct mayoral elections in many European countries, however, mayors can now be considered as ‘functional equivalents’ to popularly elected presidents in presidential, semi-presidential or ‘mixed’ systems, respectively (Bäck Reference Bäck, Haus, Heinelt and Stewart2005; Pilet et al. Reference Pilet, Steyvers, Delwit, Reynaert, Reynaert, Steyvers, Delwit and Pilet2009). These institutional reforms have been accompanied not only by providing directly elected mayors with independent democratic legitimation by voters but also by a strengthening of mayors' powers vis-à-vis local councils (Borraz and John Reference Borraz and John2004; Denters Reference Denters, Bäck, Heinelt and Magnier2006; Ervik Reference Ervik2015). Even though local councils are still relevant players in day-to-day governance (Egner Reference Egner2015), local government systems are now largely ‘characterized by a dual power structure’ with the mayor on one side and the local council on the other (Denters Reference Denters, Bäck, Heinelt and Magnier2006: 271). This changes local government formation considerably. Mayors perceive their influence in local policymaking to be higher when they are backed by a local council majority (Denters Reference Denters, Bäck, Heinelt and Magnier2006), and obtaining a supporting council majority should be easier for a mayor if their party is part of that coalition. Comparable with the strategic thinking of presidents at the national level (Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2011: 939; Kang Reference Kang2009; Strøm et al. Reference Strøm, Budge and Laver1994), directly elected mayors want their party to be represented in local governments, and by publicly declaring their preferences for the outcome of local council coalition-formation processes, mayors can influence coalition formations in the local parliament as ‘powerful players’ (Strøm and Swindle Reference Strøm and Swindle2002). These patterns can also be observed at the regional level in Greece, Indonesia, Italy and Slovakia (see e.g. Marušiak Reference Marušiak2018; Wilson Reference Wilson2015). Consequently, being the party of the head of the executive should be advantageous in subnational government formation and this party should have a higher likelihood of getting into a government coalition than other parties:

Hypothesis 1: The party of the directly elected head of the executive is more likely to enter subnational government coalitions.

Second, day-to-day governance in politics is characterized by many formal and informal negotiations between subnational parliamentarians, members of government factions and the head of the executive. Big differences in policy views between these actors can lead to gridlock in day-to-day governance or, at least, to an increase in bargaining and transaction costs (Borraz and John Reference Borraz and John2004). As at the national level in semi-presidential and presidential systems, this is particularly the case in situations of ‘cohabitation’ (in semi-presidential or mixed democratic regimes) or ‘divided government’ (in presidential systems), respectively: that is, when a permanent majority in the legislature is opposed to the head of the executive and does not include the party of the head of the executive in the coalition (see e.g. Elgie Reference Elgie2001; Kirkland and Phillips Reference Kirkland and Phillips2018). This is a serious threat to day-to-day governance and political actors perceive this peril in advance because ‘workability … turns out to be an important concern in coalition formation’ (Warwick Reference Warwick1996: 499). Similar to the argument regarding parties' ideological proximity to formateurs at the national level (see Savage Reference Savage2014), subnational political actors should also have incentives to decrease the ideological proximity to the head of the executive in order to increase the workability of a coalition and to minimize intra-coalitional conflict. Even if the party of the head of the executive is not part of the coalition, small ideological differences between a coalition party and the head of the executive could prevent high bargaining and transaction costs. Studies on government formation in presidential systems corroborate this expectation by showing that parties are more likely to become a coalition member if they are ideologically close to the president because this gives ‘the government coalition more leeway in policymaking’ (Alemán and Tsebelis Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011: 7).Footnote 1 Hence, I hypothesize that ideological proximity to the head of the executive's party should be advantageous for political actors when forming subnational government coalitions:

Hypothesis 2: Parties that are ideologically close to the party of the head of the executive are more likely to enter subnational government coalitions.

Third, the advantage of being the party of the head of the executive in the subnational government formation game might be reinforced by the fact that parties need to be of a considerable size to be able to win elections determining the head of the executive. For example, small political groups will either not have financial resources to run a candidate for head of the executive elections, or they decide to support candidates of larger parties, at least in the runoff elections between the two candidates who received the most votes. Hence, only large parties have a realistic chance to win these direct elections. The head of the executive, thus, will be a member of a large or even of the largest party in the legislature (see e.g. Steyvers et al. Reference Steyvers2008). But even if a large party is not holding the position of the head of the executive, this party will still have considerable bargaining power in coalition formation processes because a party with a large number of seats inevitably will be part of a larger number of potential coalitions than a smaller party, depending on the legislative party system (Laver and Benoit Reference Laver and Benoit2015). Therefore, I hypothesize that the size of a party affects a party's likelihood of entering a coalition (Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2011; Isaksson Reference Isaksson2005; Savage Reference Savage2014; Warwick Reference Warwick1996):

Hypothesis 3: The larger a party's seat share, the higher the party's likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions.

Fourth, subnational political actors not only strive to hold important offices, they also seek to implement their preferred policy positions in day-to-day policymaking. Therefore, subnational parties' policy positions should matter for their likelihood of joining a government coalition. As shown for the Catalonian and Swedish case on local government formations, parties controlling the median legislator or that are closer to the median position have a higher chance of joining a coalition (Bäck Reference Bäck2003b, Reference Bäck2008, Reference Bäck, Giannetti and Benoit2009; Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020). This is corroborated by findings for national government formations where ‘[h]olding the median ideological position should help a party enter government’ (Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015: 745), and being ideologically close to the median legislator should be advantageous for parties wanting to become coalition members (Döring and Hellström Reference Döring and Hellström2013):

Hypothesis 4: The smaller a party's distance to the median legislator's ideological position, the higher the party's likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions.

Lastly, government experience might be advantageous for parties in the subnational government formation game but only if the previous coalition did not break up due to intra-coalitional conflicts. If a party demonstrated being a constructive and reliable coalition partner, its likelihood of joining the next government coalition should be higher. In contrast, recent research from the national (Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015) and local levels (Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020) suggests that incumbent parties are significantly disadvantaged in negotiations to become coalition members if they are not able to re-form the incumbent coalition, which is highly unlikely if the previous government has been terminated early due to intra-coalitional conflict. Note, however, that this seems to be only valid when regarding the same set of parties in a government coalition, where parties that are responsible for early government termination due to intra-coalitional conflicts are only punished by their previous coalition partners but not by other parties (see Tavits Reference Tavits2008). Notwithstanding these conflicting arguments, I hypothesize the following:

Hypothesis 5: Incumbent parties have a higher likelihood of entering subnational government coalitions.

Case selection, data and methods

The five hypotheses regarding the determinants of individual parties' likelihood to enter subnational government coalitions will be tested by studying 92 coalition formations in 34 cities with more than 100,000 inhabitants in the German states of Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia between 1999 and 2016 (see Table A1 in the Online Appendix). A coalition is defined as any cooperation between at least two political groups where political actors signed a written coalition agreement following a local election.Footnote 2

This case selection has several advantages. Using German local elections allows a direct comparison of the results for individual parties' likelihood of entering coalitions with the findings presented for ‘quasi-parliamentarian’ systems in Sweden (Bäck Reference Bäck2003b, Reference Bäck2008, Reference Bäck, Giannetti and Benoit2009) and Catalonia (Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020) but leverages the fact that the German local institutional setting resembles a ‘mixed’ political system that is neither purely presidential nor purely parliamentarian (Bäck Reference Bäck, Haus, Heinelt and Stewart2005; Debus and Gross Reference Debus and Gross2016; Egner Reference Egner2015; Gross and Debus Reference Gross and Debus2018a). Direct mayoral elections provide an opportunity to include an additional party characteristic and institutional constraint (Strøm et al. Reference Strøm, Budge and Laver1994) in the local coalition formation game – the party of the directly elected mayor (i.e. the head of the executive) – and individual parties' ideological distance from the head of the executive. Direct elections of mayors were introduced in North Rhine-Westphalia in 1999 and in Hesse in 1992, respectively.Footnote 3

Additionally, local councils in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia have considerable rights both in shaping the local policy agenda and in allocating important portfolios (see Egner Reference Egner2015). The functions of a ‘local government’ are performed by the mayor and several other executive officers on an executive board, which resembles a ‘cabinet’, called an ‘administrative board’ in North Rhine-Westphalia and ‘magistrate’ in larger municipalities in Hesse (Egner Reference Egner2015: 184). These executive officers are elected and deselected by the local council. This means: (1) that mayors need to cooperate with local council majorities if they want to work together with politically aligned executive officers; (2) that mayors in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia are not as powerful as in other German states; and (3) that local councillors consider the executive board's influence in local politics as similar to the mayor's influence (Egner Reference Egner2015: 187). The considerable amount of power for local councils in both states regarding the competencies delegated to the administration and the mayor, in combination with the high politicization of local politics, very frequently divides local councils into majority and opposition groups. This creates strong incentives for local political actors to form permanent legislative coalitions and to become part of a coalition. It is quite common for newly established coalitions in local councils in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia to first deselect some members of the executive branch who belong to parties that are not part of the permanent legislative coalition, and then to install their own party members in these offices.

Furthermore, as the number of inhabitants increases, local politics gets more and more politicized by parties (whereas independent local lists play only a minor role) and local councils in large cities are considered as equivalents to national and regional parliaments (Egner Reference Egner2015; Gross and Jankowski Reference Gross and Jankowski2020; Reiser and Holtmann Reference Reiser and Holtmann2008). More than 40% of all cities with more than 100,000 inhabitants in Germany are in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia (see Table A1 in the Online Appendix). The cases under study cover 43.7% of the German population living in such cities in 2019.

To sum up, using local government formations in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia might be considered a ‘most likely case design’ for determining the factors impacting a party's likelihood of becoming a coalition member because both local government settings can be considered ‘prototypes’ of competitive political systems (Holtkamp Reference Holtkamp2008). Yet, in the conclusion I will discuss the potential of transferring the empirical insights to both local and regional politics in other German states and other countries, respectively.

Following the approach of Garrett Glasgow and Sona Golder (Reference Glasgow and Golder2015), I assume that the likelihood of a party becoming a coalition member depends not only on party characteristics, but also on the likelihood of potential coalitions of which the party is a member. Consequently, the empirical analysis takes the potential government formation opportunities into account. I apply conditional logit (CL) regression models to analyse the likelihood of a party becoming a coalition member. Each coalition formation is represented by a ‘choice set’, comprising the coalition that actually formed (coded 1 in the dependent variable choice) as well as all other arithmetically possible combinations of political groups in the local council (coded 0). Since this study deals with the determinants of local coalition membership, all potential single-party governments are excluded from the analysis. The binary independent variables indicate whether a party- or coalition-level characteristic is present (score of 1) or absent (score of 0) for the potential coalition while the size- and policy-related independent variables indicate the amount of the respective variables for the potential coalition.

Two dummy variables indicate whether the mayor's party is part of a potential coalition (mayor's party) and whether a party was part of the previous local government (incumbent party).Footnote 4 In situations where a single party had an absolute majority in the previous local council this variable is coded as 1 for this party only and 0 for all other parties. Assessing the hypothesis that parties with higher seat shares have a higher likelihood of entering local government, one has to consider how a party's seat share affects the characteristics of the potential coalitions of which the party is a member (Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015). A party's seat share should be more decisive for forming a coalition if adding this party to a coalition changes the coalition characteristic from a minority to a majority coalition. However, if a potential coalition already has a majority status, adding an additional party (regardless of the size of the party) turns this coalition to a surplus majority coalition and, thus, should decrease the formation likelihood of this coalition (see Martin and Stevenson Reference Martin and Stevenson2001). Hence, the effect of party size is captured as a curvilinear relationship by including both the size of a coalition (seat share coalition) and the squared value of this variable (seat share coalition squared). Since the mayor's party is also the largest party in 70 out of 92 cases – and to avoid problems of multicollinearity – using a party's seat share instead of a variable indicating the largest party is also a way to control for the effect of party size on individual parties' likelihood to enter local governments (see Bäck Reference Bäck2003b).

The ideological proximity of a party to the mayor's party (distance to the mayor's party) is assessed by using local parties' policy positions that are derived from the policy content of local election manifestos by applying the ‘wordscores’ procedure (see Laver et al. Reference Laver, Benoit and Garry2003). State parties' manifestos for several state elections in Hesse (1991–2009) and in North Rhine-Westphalia (1990–2010) have been retrieved from the Political Documents Archive (Benoit et al. Reference Benoit, Bräuninger and Debus2009; Gross and Debus Reference Gross and Debus2018b) and used as ‘reference texts’. In line with previous research on subnational party positions in Germany, the respective ‘reference scores’ to the ‘reference texts’ are state parties' policy positions on a general left–right dimension (see Bräuninger et al. Reference Bräuninger, Debus, Müller and Stecker2020; Gross and Debus Reference Gross and Debus2018a). Local election manifestos have been retrieved from the Local Manifesto Project (Gross and Jankowski Reference Gross and Jankowski2020).Footnote 5 Distance to the mayor's party is measured by using the mean ideological distance between the coalition members and the mayor's party. If a party adopts an ideological position further away from the mayor's party, the ideological distance to the mayor's party of all coalitions of which this party is a member increases. Hence, parties that are ideologically distant from the mayor's party should be less likely to become coalition members.Footnote 6 Furthermore, a party's ideological distance to the general left–right median is measured by using the mean ideological distance between the coalition members and the left–right median (distance to median).Footnote 7

I control for three main effects of coalition-level characteristics which have been found to play a decisive role in government formation processes (Bäck Reference Bäck2003a; Bäck et al. Reference Bäck, Debus, Müller and Bäck2013; Debus and Gross Reference Debus and Gross2016; Olislagers and Steyvers Reference Olislagers and Steyvers2015; Skjæveland et al. Reference Skjæveland, Serritzlew and Blom-Hansen2007): coalitions are more likely to be formed: (1) if they are minimal winning (minimal winning coalition); (2) if potential coalitions include the smallest number of parties (number of parties in coalition); and (3) if a potential coalition is the incumbent coalition (incumbent coalition). These coalition-level characteristics are captured by using both a continuous independent variable on the number of parties in a coalition and two dummy variables indicating if potential coalitions are minimal winning and if a potential coalition is the same as the previous coalition in the local council.Footnote 8

Empirical analysis

The descriptive information already lends tentative support for the hypotheses that both being the party of the head of the executive and being ideologically close to the party of the head of the executive increase parties' chances of entering subnational government coalitions (see Table A2 in the Online Appendix). The party of the directly elected mayor has been a coalition member in 81 out of 92 cases. The mean ideological distance between coalition members and the mayor's party is unequivocally smaller for the coalitions that actually formed than compared to all potential coalitions.

Three CL regression models have been estimated to assess the determinants of local government membership in Hessian and North Rhine-Westphalian cities (see Table A3 in the Online Appendix for the estimated results of the three models). The first model specifically addresses the hypothesis that the party of the directly elected mayor should have an advantage in becoming part of a coalition. The second model tests whether parties that are ideologically close to the mayor's party are more likely to enter local government.Footnote 9 The third model uses the mean ideological distance between coalition members to the left–right median instead of the ideologically proximity to the mayor's party to test the fourth hypothesis.Footnote 10

The coefficient estimates plotted in Figure 1 show that potential coalitions including the party of the directly elected mayor are significantly more likely than other coalitions.Footnote 11 In terms of individual parties, the mayor's party (i.e. the party of the head of the executive) is significantly more likely to become a coalition member than other parties. This is in line with the theoretical expectation formulated in the first hypothesis.

Figure 1. Determinants of Individual Parties' Local Government Membership

Note: Coefficient estimates from Models 1–3 in Table A3 in the Online Appendix (95% confidence intervals shown).

Second, party size matters. Parties with more seats in the local council have a greater probability of becoming a coalition member, thus supporting the third hypothesis and corroborating empirical findings from the subnational and national levels in different countries (see Bäck Reference Bäck2003b; Döring and Hellström Reference Döring and Hellström2013; Isaksson Reference Isaksson2005; Mattila and Raunio Reference Mattila and Raunio2004; Savage Reference Savage2014). Echoing the results in Glasgow and Golder (Reference Glasgow and Golder2015) and Mattila and Raunio (Reference Mattila and Raunio2004), however, the effect of a party's seat share is weaker the more seats a party obtains.

Third, potential coalitions are significantly less likely to form if their mean ideological distance to the mayor's party increases, thus supporting the second hypothesis. If a party adopts an ideological position further away from the mayor's party, the distance from the mayor's party increases for all potential coalitions of which this party would be a member. Consequently, the further away a party ideologically positions itself from the mayor's party, the less likely it is that this party will join a coalition. Both findings are in line with empirical findings on the likelihood of a president's party entering government and that parties which are ideologically close to the president's or prime minister's party are more likely to become coalition members (cf. Alemán and Tsebelis Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011; Mattila and Raunio Reference Mattila and Raunio2004; Savage Reference Savage2014).

Model 3 takes into account the possibility that parties are minimizing the ideological distance to the median legislator rather than the ideological distance to the mayor's party. The results show, however, that parties that are closer to the ideological median of the local council are not more likely to become part of a coalition (and the fourth hypothesis must be rejected). Hence, it is parties' ideological proximity to the party of the head of the executive that matters in subnational government formation and not their ideological closeness to the left–right median legislator.

Regarding the coalition-level characteristics and the incumbency factor, the findings lend further evidence to recent findings in national and subnational government formation research (cf. Debus and Gross Reference Debus and Gross2016; Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020; Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015; Gross and Debus Reference Gross and Debus2018a; Olislagers and Steyvers Reference Olislagers and Steyvers2015): minimal winning coalitions are more likely to be formed, whereas coalitions are the less likely, the more parties they comprise. Furthermore, incumbent parties have a lesser chance of re-entering government if they are not able to renew their cooperation, because it is the incumbent coalition that has a positive and statistically significant probability of being formed again. If the members of the previous coalition are not able to renew their cooperation, then these parties are less likely to join a coalition.

Two additional specifications of the CL regression models are conducted to test the robustness of the results (see Tables A4 and A5 in the Online Appendix). First, one could argue that some parties have such extreme policy positions that they are excluded from the government formation game by all other parties. Potential coalitions comprising ‘anti-system’ parties (see Zulianello Reference Zulianello2018) thus should be extremely unlikely to be formed (Stefuriuc Reference Stefuriuc2013: 69). Since ‘anti-system’ parties are not part of any of the 92 coalitions that formed, the first robustness check uses a reduced sample of all potential coalitions excluding the ones covering ‘anti-system’ parties. The empirical findings are robust against this alternative specification. Second, local parties might additionally strive for the formation of governments that are congruent – that is, have an identical party combination – to the regional government to use information advantages, to decrease bargaining costs and to avoid sending ‘mixed signals’ to voters, who might become unsettled if their preferred party joins a coalition with Party A at the regional level but with Party B at the local level. The results show that potential coalitions are significantly more likely to be formed if they are congruent to the regional government, thus corroborating findings for local government formations in Flemish municipalities (see Olislagers and Steyvers Reference Olislagers and Steyvers2015). The substantial findings are robust against this specification with one exception: the variable incumbent party now displays a negative and statistically significant effect because controlling for the congruence between local and regional governments reinforces the effect that if incumbent parties are not able to re-form the previous coalition, they have a higher likelihood of being excluded from coalition formations than other parties.

Lastly, is there an explanation for those instances where the head of the executive's party is not part of the legislative coalition supporting the government (‘cohabitation’)? The descriptive information provided in Table 1 shows that mayors' parties had lost seats in 10 out of 11 cases. These seat losses might suggest two reasons why parties of directly elected mayors have not been included in local council coalitions.Footnote 12 First, the fact of losing seats as the mayor's party might be used by rival parties to claim that an electoral ‘loser’ does not deserve to be part of a coalition, or that voters punished the mayor's party on purpose to strengthen local ‘checks and balances’. Second, since local political actors prefer to form minimal winning coalitions, and since mayor parties are usually large parties, seat losses by mayoral parties could render preferred coalition options of the mayor's party arithmetically impossible. This offers rival parties an opportunity to exclude the mayor's party from government by allowing previously unlikely potential coalitions to be formed.Footnote 13

Table 1. Cases of ‘Cohabitation’ in Hessian and North Rhine-Westphalian Cities with at Least 100,000 Inhabitants, 1999–2016

Note: ‘Cohabitation’ describes a situation where the mayor's party is not part of the coalition in the local council. CDU = Christian Democratic Union of Germany; SPD = Social Democratic Party of Germany.

Conclusion

The empirical literature on government formations and individual parties' likelihood of joining a government has grown significantly in the last two decades. Comprehensive studies on the determinants of individual parties' likelihood of entering subnational governments, however, are largely missing, with the exception of studies on Catalonian (Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020) and Swedish municipalities (Bäck Reference Bäck2003b, Reference Bäck2008, Reference Bäck, Giannetti and Benoit2009), two ‘quasi-parliamentarian’ systems. Therefore, I argued that one important institutional constraint at the regional level (e.g. in Greece, Indonesia, Italy and Slovakia) and the local level (most European local government systems) has been overlooked so far: the party affiliation of the directly elected head of the executive and its effect on individual parties' likelihood of entering local government coalitions in such ‘quasi-semi-presidential’ or ‘mixed’ regimes. By using data from 92 local government coalition formations in German municipalities in the states of Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia (1999–2016), I show that the party of the directly elected head of the executive is significantly more likely to join a government coalition. Furthermore, parties that are ideologically close to the party of the head of the executive are also more likely to enter local government coalitions.

To what extent can these theoretical and empirical insights be generalized? Although local coalition formations in large cities in Hesse and North Rhine-Westphalia are ‘most likely cases’, the empirical results could be transferred to local government formations in other German states. For example, it is now quite common to negotiate formal coalitions not only in larger cities but also in smaller municipalities because local party systems become more fragmented, the times of absolute majorities held by a single party are mostly over, and six out of ten councillors in German municipalities (almost nine out of ten in municipalities with at least 10,000 inhabitants) have a party affiliation (Egner Reference Egner2015: 184). Even in a local government setting like Bavaria, which is characterized by a very dominant role for the directly elected mayor and a more ‘consensual’ style of local politics (Holtkamp Reference Holtkamp2008), parties frequently form coalitions in local councils and try to include the party of the directly elected mayor (Pollex et al. Reference Pollex, Block, Gross, Nyhuis and Velimsky2021). This is also the case for coalition formations in larger cities in almost all other German states (Gross Reference Gross2018).

Nevertheless, even though German local councillors in smaller municipalities are also overwhelmingly capable of differentiating between majority and minority groups and in determining who is part of a formal or informal coalition in local councils (see Egner Reference Egner2015), a comparative analysis of local government formations in particular – and the importance of ideology in local politics in general – in municipalities with fewer than 100,000 inhabitants is more than needed. Although recent research indicates that the emergence of the Alternative for Germany is a particular threat to the electoral success of non-partisan local lists in smaller municipalities (Jankowski et al. Reference Jankowski, Juen and Tepe2020), thus raising doubts about the widely held claim that ‘personalities matter more than parties’, we currently lack comparable data on factors influencing voters' decision-making in local elections.

The theoretical argument that being the head of the executive's party and being ideologically close to this party is beneficial for a party's likelihood of becoming a coalition member needs to be tested in other contexts, though. For example, since many local councillors have a party affiliation in many Western and Eastern European democracies – particularly in larger municipalities (Razin Reference Razin, Egner, Sweeting and Klok2013) – and since direct mayoral elections have been introduced in a large number of countries, the theoretical arguments and empirical findings presented here could be studied in other settings. Studies on local politics in Bulgaria (Nikolova Reference Nikolova, Loughlin, Hendriks and Lidström2011), Poland (Swianiewicz Reference Swianiewicz, Loughlin, Hendriks and Lidström2011) and Slovakia (Capková Reference Capková, Loughlin, Hendriks and Lidström2011) indicate that the relationship between directly elected mayors and local council majorities becomes tense when the party of the mayor is not part of the local council majority. Following the argument of the present study, this should create incentives for local councillors to include the party of the head of the executive in local government coalitions. Furthermore, this argument is not restricted to the local level but could also be transferred to the regional level and tested within the empirical framework applied there if citizens directly elect their regional heads of the executive (e.g. in Greece, Indonesia, Italy, Slovakia).

Much further research, however, is required. For example, the empirical findings indicate the need to gain a better understanding of the relationship between the head of the executive and her party (see e.g. McDonnell and Mazzoleni Reference McDonnell and Mazzoleni2014). One important assumption made in the literature on government formations is that the head of the executive adopts the same policy position as her party (see Alemán and Tsebelis Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011; Martínez-Gallardo Reference Martínez-Gallardo2014). Yet, although this might be a plausible assumption if a head of the executive has been running for election on the ticket of one single party, there are numerous cases where she is supported by several parties. Whether she adopts the policy position of her own party or a position that is a compromise between all the positions of the supporting parties still is uncharted territory. Filling this research gap might allow scholars to get a more nuanced picture of government formations in (semi-)presidential systems. Furthermore, in smaller municipalities – but also in some larger cities in Germany – candidates without a party affiliation are winning direct mayoral elections. To what extent these candidates are supported by political parties and if that shapes their policy preferences is still a research question that awaits a scholarly answer.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.41.

Acknowledgements

Previous versions of this article have been presented at the 5th Annual General Conference of the European Political Science Association 2015, and an internal seminar at the University of Oldenburg, 2017. I want to thank Anna Adendorf, Marc Debus, Michael Jankowski, Markus Tepe and three anonymous reviewers for their valuable suggestions and helpful feedback. Further, I thank Anna Adendorf, Yannik Buhl, Hatice Kücük, Samuel Müller, Torben Schütz, Kenneth Stiller and Lea Maria Straßheim for assisting in the preparation of the local election manifestos.

Footnotes

1 This argument is only valid if one assumes that the head of the executive's ideological position is identical to the ideological position of the party to which they belong. Yet, this is a plausible assumption and in line with studies of government formation in (semi-)presidential political systems at the national level (see e.g. Alemán and Tsebelis Reference Alemán and Tsebelis2011; Martínez-Gallardo Reference Martínez-Gallardo2014). Even if candidates are supported not only by their own party but also by other parties, they could not move their policy positions too far away from the policy positions of their own party because this could send ‘mixed signals’ to partisan supporters and traditional voters of the parties on which the candidates have to rely.

2 The coalition agreements can be retrieved from the Local Manifesto Project (Gross and Jankowski Reference Gross and Jankowski2020). Note that theoretically the ‘bindingness’ of a coalition agreement at the local level is somewhat different from the situation at the state or federal level in Germany: if a local coalition breaks up due to intra-coalitional conflicts, then local parties can still work with changing majorities without ‘officially’ declaring the formation of a new government. Yet, empirically Gross (Reference Gross2018) shows for coalitions between the Christian Democrats (CDU) and the Greens that their coalition agreements are as ‘binding’ as the ones at the state and federal level because voting with opposition parties immediately led to the break-up of the coalition and in most cases to the formation of a new coalition. Furthermore, members of local coalitions should have strong incentives to stick to the policy content of the coalition agreement because local councillors overwhelmingly emphasize the importance of implementing their party programme (Egner Reference Egner2015), which is at least partially covered by the coalition agreement.

3 In Hesse mayors are elected for six years, whereas mayoral office terms in North Rhine-Westphalia vary between five and six years due to changing majorities in the state parliament.

4 Except for the two coalition formation situations in Darmstadt 2011 and 2016, where the mayor is a member of the Green Party, all mayors are members of either the CDU or the Social Democratic Party (SPD).

5 See Gross and Jankowski (Reference Gross and Jankowski2020) for a detailed discussion of the validity of using ‘wordscores’ for estimating local party positions in Germany.

6 Using the mean ideological distance between the coalition members and the mayor's party, weighted by the seat share of each coalition party, does not affect the substantial results of the analysis.

7 Including both a measurement identifying the median party and a measurement assessing the ideological distance of parties to the median ‘would introduce multicollinearity, because the latter proxy is a perfect predictor of the former’ (Döring and Hellström Reference Döring and Hellström2013: 689, fn. 2). Additionally, there are several cases where a median party could not be defined unambiguously. Using the weighted mean ideological distance, weighted by the seat share of each coalition member, does not affect the results of the analysis.

8 Note that the latter effect, however, is only conditional and very heterogeneous (Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2012; Martin and Stevenson Reference Martin and Stevenson2010). Incumbent coalitions are much more likely to re-form if an incumbent coalition does not have to resign officially but rather can remain in office (‘continuation rule’), and incumbent coalitions are disadvantaged compared to other potential coalitions if the government has been terminated by intra-cabinet conflict. These two arguments, however, cannot be tested with the existing data set at hand. There exists no ‘continuation rule’ at the German local level. Once a coalition is terminated early, all political groups in the local council can try to form a new coalition, or they can decide to work with alternative and varying majorities. Unfortunately, data on local coalition terminations are not available for the entire data set at hand.

9 To avoid introducing multicollinearity in the model, mayor's party is excluded from the second model because the variable calculating the mean ideological distance between coalition members to the mayor's party would be a perfect predictor of the mayor's party for all potential coalitions that only include the mayor's party (see also Döring and Hellström Reference Döring and Hellström2013: 689, fn. 2).

10 In Models 4–6, I relax the independence of irrelevant alternatives assumption and employ MXL models with random coefficients for a few variables to fit the data better since a McFadden–Train test does support the assumption of independent variables with random normal distributions for some of the independent variables (Glasgow et al. Reference Glasgow, Golder and Golder2012). The results remain substantially the same.

11 Figure 1 is based on the plotplain scheme in Stata version 16.1 (Bischof Reference Bischof2017) and has been created using the user-written command coefplot (Jann Reference Jann2014).

12 By focusing only on party-level characteristics, several studies show that losing seats (or being the biggest loser) decreases a party's probability of becoming a coalition member (see Isaksson Reference Isaksson2005; Mattila and Raunio Reference Mattila and Raunio2004). However, this is not possible to model in the empirical framework applied here (see Falcó-Gimeno Reference Falcó-Gimeno2020; Glasgow and Golder Reference Glasgow and Golder2015).

13 The only case running counter to these two explanations is the case of Moers in 2014. The CDU won the mayoral election in 2014 as well as three additional local council seats. The SPD (still being the largest party in the local council despite its big losses), however, managed to form a coalition with the Greens and members of an independent local list.

References

Alemán, E and Tsebelis, G (2011) Political Parties and Government Coalitions in the Americas. Journal of Politics in Latin America 3(1), 328. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1866802X1100300101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H (2003a) Explaining and Predicting Coalition Outcomes: Conclusions from Studying Data on Local Coalitions. European Journal of Political Research 42(4), 441472. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.00092.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H (2003b) Explaining Coalitions: Evidence and Lessons from Studying Coalition Formation in Swedish Local Government. Uppsala: Acta Universitatis Upsaliensis.Google Scholar
Bäck, H (2005) The Institutional Setting of Local Political Leadership and Community Involvement. In Haus, M, Heinelt, H and Stewart, M (eds), Urban Governance and Democracy: Leadership and Community Involvement. London: Routledge, pp. 65101.Google Scholar
Bäck, H (2008) Intra-Party Politics and Coalition Formation: Evidence from Swedish Local Government. Party Politics 14(1), 7189. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1354068807081818.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bäck, H (2009) Intra-Party Politics and Local Coalition Formation. In Giannetti, D and Benoit, K (eds), Intra-Party Politics and Coalition Governments in Parliamentary Democracies. London: Routledge, pp. 5368.Google Scholar
Bäck, H, Debus, M, Müller, J and Bäck, H (2013) Regional Government Formation in Varying Multilevel Contexts: A Comparison of Eight European Countries. Regional Studies 47(3), 368387. https://doi.org/10.1080/00343404.2012.733072.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, K, Bräuninger, T and Debus, M (2009) Challenges for Estimating Policy Preferences: Announcing an Open Access Archive of Political Documents. German Politics 18(3), 441454. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644000903055856.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bischof, D (2017) New Graphic Schemes for Stata: plotplain and plottig. Stata Journal 17(3), 748759. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1536867X1701700313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blockmans, T, Geys, B, Heyndels, B and Mahieu, B (2016) Bargaining Complexity and the Duration of Government Formation: Evidence from Flemish Municipalities. Public Choice 167(1–2), 131143. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-016-0333-8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borraz, O and John, P (2004) The Transformation of Urban Political Leadership in Western Europe. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 28(1), 107120. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.0309-1317.2004.00505.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bräuninger, T, Debus, M, Müller, J and Stecker, C (2020) Parteienwettbewerb in den deutschen Bundesländern. 2nd edn. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capková, S (2011) Slovakia: Local Government: Establishing Democracy at the Grassroots. In Loughlin, J, Hendriks, F and Lidström, A (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Local and Regional Democracy in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 553574.Google Scholar
Debus, M and Gross, M (2016) Coalition Formation at the Local Level: Institutional Constraints, Party Policy Conflict, and Office-Seeking Political Parties. Party Politics 22(6), 835846. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1354068815576292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denters, B (2006) Duo or Duel? The Relations between Mayors and Councils in Democratic Local Government. In Bäck, H, Heinelt, H and Magnier, A (eds), The European Mayor: Political Leaders in the Changing Context of Local Democracy. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften, pp. 271285.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, H and Hellström, J (2013) Who Gets into Government? Coalition Formation in European Democracies. West European Politics 36(4), 683703. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2013.783347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Egner, B (2015) Parliaments in Disguise? How German Councillors Perceive Local Councils. Local Government Studies 41(2), 183201. https://doi.org/10.1080/03003930.2013.874342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elgie, R (ed.) (2001) Divided Government in Comparative Perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ervik, B (2015) Does the Mayor's Party Brand Matter? The Prospect of Statewide Parties’ Policy in Local Government. Local Government Studies 41(3), 339361. https://doi.org/10.1080/03003930.2013.836493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falcó-Gimeno, A (2020) The Political Geography of Government Formation: Why Regional Parties Join Coalitions. Party Politics 26(2), 91106. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1354068817750865.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasgow, G and Golder, SN (2015) A New Approach to the Study of Parties Entering Government. British Journal of Political Science 45(4), 739754. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123414000015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasgow, G, Golder, M and Golder, SN (2011) Who ‘Wins’? Determining the Party of the Prime Minister. American Journal of Political Science 55(4), 936953. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2011.00524.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glasgow, G, Golder, M and Golder, SN (2012) New Empirical Strategies for the Study of Parliamentary Government Formation. Political Analysis 20(2), 248270. https://doi.org/10.1093/pan/mpr058.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, M (2018) ‘Sowing the Seeds of Love’? Determinants of Local Coalition Formation and Termination between the CDU and the Greens, 1994–2016. German Politics 27(3), 339358. https://doi.org/10.1080/09644008.2017.1337098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, M and Debus, M (2018a) Gaining New Insights by Going Local: Determinants of Coalition Formation in Mixed Democratic Polities. Public Choice 174(1–2), 6180. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-017-0489-x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, M and Debus, M (2018b) Does EU Regional Policy Increase Parties’ Support for European Integration? West European Politics 41(3), 594614. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2017.1395249.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, M and Jankowski, M (2020) Dimensions of Political Conflict and Party Positions in Multi-Level Democracies: Evidence from the Local Manifesto Project. West European Politics 43(1), 74101. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2019.1602816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtkamp, L (2008) Kommunale Konkordanz- und Konkurrenzdemokratie: Parteien und Bürgermeister in der Repräsentativen Demokratie. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.Google Scholar
Isaksson, G-E (2005) From Election to Government: Principal Rules and Deviant Cases. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 40(3), 329357. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1477-7053.2005.00154.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jankowski, M, Juen, C-M and Tepe, M (2020) The Impact of Anti-Establishment Parties on the Electoral Success of Independent Local Lists: Evidence from Germany. Party Politics, published early online, October. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1354068820965430.Google Scholar
Jann, B (2014) Plotting Regression Coefficients and Other Estimates. Stata Journal 14(4), 708737. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1536867X1401400402.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kang, S-G (2009) The Influence of Presidential Heads of State on Government Formation in European Democracies: Empirical Evidence. European Journal of Political Research 48(4), 543572. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2009.00840.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, PA and Phillips, JH (2018) Is Divided Government a Cause of Legislative Delay? Quarterly Journal of Political Science 13(2), 173206. http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/100.00017041.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M and Benoit, K (2015) The Basic Arithmetic of Legislative Decisions. American Journal of Political Science 59(2), 275291. https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M, Benoit, K and Garry, J (2003) Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts Using Words as Data. American Political Science Review 97(2), 311331. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055403000698.Google Scholar
Martin, LW and Stevenson, RT (2001) Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies. American Journal of Political Science 45(1), 3350. https://doi.org/10.2307/2669358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, LW and Stevenson, RT (2010) The Conditional Impact of Incumbency on Government Formation. American Political Science Review 104(3), 503518. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055410000213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez-Cantó, J and Bergmann, H (2020) Government Termination in Multilevel Settings: How Party Congruence Affects the Survival of Sub-National Governments in Germany and Spain. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion and Parties 30(3), 379399. https://doi.org/10.1080/17457289.2019.1666272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez-Gallardo, C (2014) Designing Cabinets: Presidential Politics and Ministerial Instability. Journal of Politics in Latin America 6(2), 338. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1866802X1400600201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marušiak, J (2018) Regional Elections in Slovakia – A New Reformation of the Slovak Political Scene? Contemporary European Studies 1, 2546.Google Scholar
Mattila, M and Raunio, T (2004) Does Winning Pay? Electoral Success and Government Formation in 15 West European Countries. European Journal of Political Research 43(2), 263285. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6765.2004.00154.x.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonnell, D and Mazzoleni, O (2014) Directly Elected Mayors and Their Parties: The Cases of Genoa and Lausanne. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 49(1), 92119. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2013.25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Müller, WC and Strøm, K (eds) (1999) Policy, Office, or Votes? How Political Parties in Western Europe Make Hard Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nikolova, P (2011) Bulgaria: The Dawn of a New Era of Inclusive Subnational Democracy? In Loughlin, J, Hendriks, F and Lidström, A (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Local and Regional Democracy in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 665684.Google Scholar
Olislagers, E and Steyvers, K (2015) Choosing Coalition Partners in Belgian Local Government. Local Government Studies 41(2), 202219. https://doi.org/10.1080/03003930.2014.884496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pilet, J-B, Steyvers, K, Delwit, P and Reynaert, H (2009) The Quasi-Presidentialization of Local Political Systems: Causes and Consequences. In Reynaert, H, Steyvers, K, Delwit, P and Pilet, J-B (eds), Local Political Leadership in Europe: Town Chief, City Boss or Loco President? Bruges: Vanden Broele, pp. 397406.Google Scholar
Pollex, J, Block, S, Gross, M, Nyhuis, D and Velimsky, JA (2021) Ein zunehmend bunter Freistaat: Die Analyse der bayerischen Kommunalwahlen im März unter besonderer Berücksichtigung der kreisfreien Städte. Zeitschrift für Parlamentsfragen 52(1), 7894. https://doi.org/10.5771/0340-1758-2021-1-78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Razin, E (2013) Councillors and Their Parties. In Egner, B, Sweeting, D and Klok, P-J (eds), Local Councillors in Europe. Wiesbaden: Springer VS, pp. 5162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reiser, M and Holtmann, E (eds) (2008) Farewell to the Party Model? Independent Local Lists in East and West European Countries. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.Google Scholar
Savage, LM (2014) Who Gets in? Ideology and Government Membership in Central and Eastern Europe. Party Politics 20(4), 547562. https://doi.org/10.1177%2F1354068811436064.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schakel, AH and Massetti, E (2018) A World of Difference: The Sources of Regional Government Composition and Alternation. West European Politics 41(3), 703727. https://doi.org/10.1080/01402382.2017.1400237.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skjæveland, A, Serritzlew, S and Blom-Hansen, J (2007) Theories of Coalition Formation: An Empirical Test Using Data from Danish Local Government. European Journal of Political Research 46(5), 721745. https://doi.org/10.1080/13572330802442774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stefuriuc, I (2013) Government Formation in Multi-Level Settings: Party Strategy and Institutional Constraints. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steyvers, K et al. (2008) From Princeps to President? Comparing Local Political Leadership Transformation. Local Government Studies 34(2), 131146. https://doi.org/10.1080/03003930701852179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Strøm, K and Swindle, SM (2002) Strategic Parliamentary Dissolution. American Political Science Review 96(3), 575591. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055402000345.Google Scholar
Strøm, K, Budge, I and Laver, M (1994) Constraints on Cabinet Formation in Parliamentary Democracies. American Journal of Political Science 38(2), 303335. https://doi.org/10.2307/2111406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swianiewicz, P (2011) Poland: Europeanization of Subnational Governments. In Loughlin, J, Hendriks, F and Lidström, A (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Local and Regional Democracy in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 481504.Google Scholar
Tavits, M (2008) The Role of Parties’ Past Behavior in Coalition Formation. American Political Science Review 102(4), 495507. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055408080362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Warwick, PV (1996) Coalition Government Membership in West European Parliamentary Democracies. British Journal of Political Science 26(4), 471499. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0007123400007572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, A (2015) Direct Election of Regional Presidents and Party Change in Italy. Modern Italy 20(2), 185198. https://doi.org/10.1080/13532944.2015.1024213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zulianello, M (2018) Anti-System Parties Revisited: Concept Formation and Guidelines for Empirical Research. Government and Opposition: An International Journal of Comparative Politics 53(4), 653681. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2017.12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Determinants of Individual Parties' Local Government MembershipNote: Coefficient estimates from Models 1–3 in Table A3 in the Online Appendix (95% confidence intervals shown).

Figure 1

Table 1. Cases of ‘Cohabitation’ in Hessian and North Rhine-Westphalian Cities with at Least 100,000 Inhabitants, 1999–2016

Supplementary material: PDF

Gross supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Gross supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 189.3 KB