Hostname: page-component-84b7d79bbc-7nlkj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-26T12:05:52.188Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Under-Developed Countries in the World Economy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 November 2014

G. E. Britnell*
Affiliation:
University of Saskatchewan
Get access

Extract

It is with some misgiving that I put forward the suggestion that a Canadian may be in a better position than either an Englishman or an American—despite the experience of the former, the energy of the latter, and the assurance of both—to appreciate the complex problems of under-developed countries. Nevertheless, emboldened by the modest, freely admitted and unhesitating recognition (by Canadians) of Canada's success in the historic role of interpreting the United States to Great Britain and Great Britain to the United States, and undeterred by the somewhat less striking evidence of our capacity to interpret ourselves to one another within the framework of a federal state, I am ambitious to extend the operations of such an honest broker of goodwill to include a more racially variegated, linguistically diversified, and culturally challenging clientele.

The credentials which a Canadian may offer in asking to be considered as a possible interpreter of at least some of the problems of under-developed countries cannot be brushed aside as completely fraudulent. As an expert on under-developed countries has pointed out, “one might almost say that a country is ‘underdeveloped,’ if its government considers development a problem, in a way which calls for positive policy. In this sense, Canada would have been an underdeveloped country throughout the nineteenth century, and might even be considered so to-day, despite its high per capita income and its current rate of economic growth.” Certainly if one of the more important criteria of an under-developed country is a heavy reliance on foreign capital for economic development, Canada may still be looked upon as an underdeveloped country subject to many of the stubborn political and social, no less than economic, problems and frictions which such a position involves.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 1957

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Higgins, Benjamin, Development Financing, reprinted from International Conciliation (Cambridge, Mass., 1955), 277.Google Scholar

2 Measures for the Economic Development of Under-Developed Countries: Report by a Group of Experts appointed by the Secretary-General of the United Nations (New York, 1951), 3.Google Scholar Under-developed areas may, of course, remain in such countries as Canada and the United States, where “one can find regions in which per capita income is so low as to warrant the use of the term ‘under-developed’” ( Higgins, , Development Financing, 276–7Google Scholar).

3 See Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland:Economic Report, 1956 (Salisbury, S.R., 1956)Google Scholar and Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland: Report of the Fiscal Review Commission, 1957 (Salisbury, S.R., 1957).Google Scholar I am indebted to my colleagues on the Fiscal Review Commission for much information on the Federation but I wish to absolve them completely from responsibility for any errors of interpretation or judgment which may appear in this paper.

4 See Britneil, G. E., et al., The Economic Development of Guatemala: Report of a Mission Sponsored by the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development in Collaboration with the Government of Guatemala (Washington, 1951).Google Scholar See also Flan de Desarrollo Economico de Guatemala, 1955-1960 (Guatemala, CA., 1956).Google Scholar

5 See Report of the East Africa Royal Commission, 1953-1955 (London, 1955).Google Scholar

6 See Higgins, Benjamin, The Economic and Social Development of Libya (New York, 1953).Google Scholar

7 See Higgins, Benjamin, Indonesia's Development Plans and Problems, reprinted from Pacific Affairs (Cambridge, Mass., 1956), 107–25Google Scholar; and his Development Financing, 277-9, 310-11.

8 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, The Current Economic Position and Prospects of Guatemala (mimeo., Washington, 1955), 2.Google Scholar

9 Measures for the Economic Development of Under-Developed Countries, chap. XI.

10 Mason, Philip, “Masters or Partners?Foreign Affairs, XXXV, no. 3, 04, 1955, 505.Google Scholar Royal commissions are seldom as laconic, but see Report of the East Africa Royal Commission, 88.

11 Higgins, , Development Financing, 312.Google Scholar See also Diamond, William, “Economic Problems of Foreign Trade and Investment in Underdeveloped Countries,” Ohio State Law Journal, XVII, no. 3, 1956, 254–66.Google Scholar

12 Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland: Economic Report, 1956, 70-5.

13 See International Gold and Dollar Flows” in Federal Reserve Bulletin, XLIII, no. 3, 03, 1957, 249–55.Google Scholar

14 Cairncross, A. R., Home and Foreign Investment, 1870-1913 (Cambridge, 1953), 3.Google Scholar However, for an examination of important differences in the character and direction of American exports of capital today as compared with British overseas investment before the First World War, see Viner, Jacob, “America's Aims and the Progress of Underdeveloped Countries” in Hoselitz, Bert F., ed., The Progress of Underdeveloped Areas (Chicago, 1952), 175202.Google Scholar

15 See Canada, Dominion Bureau of Statistics, Canada's International Investment Position, 1926-1954 (Ottawa, 1956), 947.Google Scholar See also D.B.S., National Accounts: Income and Expenditure, 1950-1956 (Ottawa, 1957), 14-15, 26–8.Google Scholar

16 Higgins, Benjamin, The “Vualistic Theory” of Underdeveloped Areas (Cambridge, Mass., 1955), 19.Google Scholar

17 SirCopland, Douglas, “The Under-Developed Countries and the Structure of the Western Economy” in Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, C, no. 5. 10, 1956, 432–3.Google Scholar

18 Nurkse, Ragnar, Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries (Oxford, 1953), 1.Google Scholar

19 See particularly Hon.Pearson, L. B., Some Aspects of Canadian-American Relations (press release, Dept. of External Affairs, Ottawa, 04 27, 1956)Google Scholar; and Royal Commission on Canada's Economic Prospects: Preliminary Report, December 1956 (Ottawa, 1956), chap. XIV.Google Scholar

20 Canada's International Investment Position, 1926-1954, 61.

21 Measures for the Economic Development of Under-Developed Countries, 28.

22 Ibid., 30.

23 Ibid., 32.

24 Higgins, Benjamin, Economic Development of Underdeveloped Areas: Past and Present (Cambridge, Mass., 1955), 1112.Google Scholar The percentages are from the same source.

25 See Measures for the Economic Development of Under-Developed Countries, 73-4. See also Viner, , “America's Aims and the Progress of Underdeveloped Countries,” 184-5, 196.Google Scholar

26 See Britnell, G. E.. “The Implications of United States Policy for the Canadian Wheat Economy,” this Journal, XXII, no. 1, 02, 1956, 116.Google Scholar

27 See The Current Economic Position and Prospects of Guatemala, 10-11, and Tables 13, 15-17.

28 Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland: Economic Report, 1956, chaps, IX-X.

29 The price of Rhodesian copper on the London Metal Exchange dropped from an all-time high of £437 per long ton on March 19, 1956, to £.240 on February 19, 1957, and to £220 by June, 1957, but production could hardly be described as unprofitable even at the lower quotations. The Federal Minister of Finance has wisely treated all tax revenues from copper over £240 a ton as windfall profits to be used for capital development rather than as general revenues available for recurrent expenditures. On year-to-year fluctuations, cyclical movements, and long-term trends for copper, coffee, and many other primary products over half a century, see United Nations, Instability in Export Markets of Under-Developed Countries in Relation to Their Ability to Obtain Foreign Exchange from Exports of Primary Commodities, 1901-1950 (New York, 1952).Google Scholar

30 Measures for the Economic Development of Under-Developed Countries, 57. See also United Nations, Relative Prices of Exports and Imports of Under-Developed Countries: A Study of Post-War Terms of Trade between Under-Developed and Industrialized Countries (New York, 1949)Google Scholar, and United Nations, Commodity Trade and Economic Development (New York, 1953), especially Parts I and III.Google Scholar

31 Hirschman, Albert O., “Economics and Investment Planning: Reflections Based on the Experience of Colombia,” in Investment Criteria and Economic Growth: Papers Presented at a Conference Sponsored Jointly by the Center for International Studies and the Social Science Research Council (Cambridge, Mass., 1955), 51.Google Scholar

32 The United Kingdom, of course, still accounts for one-half of the exports from and nearly one-half of the imports into the Federation of Rhodesia and Nyasaland. See Economic Report, 1956, 58-63.

33 See also Britnell, G. E., “Problems of Economic and Social Change in Guatemala,” this Journal, XVII, no. 4, 11, 1951, 468–81Google Scholar, and Underdeveloped Countries: The Theory and Practice of Technical Assistance-Factors in the Economic Development of Guatemala,” American Economic Review, XLIII, no. 2, 05, 1953, 104–14.Google Scholar

34 Frankel, S. Herbert, The Economic Impact on Under-Developed Societies: Essays on International Investment and Social Change (Cambridge, Mass., 1953).Google Scholar Professor Frankel objects to “that commonplace view of technical change which regards it as resulting from the application of new knowledge—of technical ‘know-how’ … the implicit assumption that the ‘know-how’ exists, as it were, as a stock of techniques—like a stock of raw materials—which can be drawn upon at will, and applied to any situation, in order to produce the desired, and therefore forseeable, end. It is because we tend to think in such abstract terms that we are led to imagine that somehow economic development, or the lack of it, can be explained in terms of the presence or absence of adequate quantities of the factors of production. …” (p. 23)

35 Boeke, J. H., Economics and Economic Policy of Dual Societies as Exemplified by Indonesia (New York, 1953), 143.Google Scholar For a critical examination of Dr. Boeke's thesis see Higgins, The “Dwdistie Theory” of Underdeveloped Areas.

36 See Mason, Philip, A New Deal in East Africa (London, 1955), 78 Google Scholar, and Report of the East Africa Royal Commission, 14-22, and chaps, VI, XXI, and XXIII.

37 See Report of the Southern Rhodesia Franchise Commission, 1957 (Salisbury, 1957).Google Scholar

38 Professor K. C. Wheare, who was constitutional adviser at the conferences preceding federation, declared in a B.B.C. broadcast from London on January 1, 1954, that the new constitution's great claim to distinction was its “attempt to use federalism to provide a system of government for Europeans and Africans.” On the choice of a federal rather than a unitary basis for the new state, Professor Wheare argued that “it will have been justified, if it gives to Africans a sense of political justice, and if it makes them feel that, with the reservation of matters which primarily concern them to the territorial governments, they will not suffer by being associated with other territories in a federal government. Time alone will show whether a feeling of justice and security and prosperity does develop in the federation. What is clear, however, is that those who framed the constitution took great care that safeguards for the interests of Africans were provided in the constitution, and not only in its federal provisions. If, as the constitution is worked, Africans and Europeans can come to feel that they share in common a loyalty to Rhodesia and Nyasaland, while retaining, as do the French and British in Canada, all those national or racial characteristics and common loyalties and sentiments and ways of life which they value tremendously, then the federation will have achieved not merely success, but a unique success.” On the political background of federation and some of die problems encountered in working out arrangements for a federal state between a colony enjoying responsible government (Southern Rhodesia) and two Protectorates directly under the control of the Crown (Northern Rhodesia and Nyasaland), see Kirkwood, Kenneth, “British Central Africa: Politics under Federation” in the Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Sciences, CCXCVIII, 03, 1955, 130–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

39 “Mr. Kwenje: Sir, I beg to Move that the Nyasaland Protectorate be extricated from the Federation of Central Africa since Nyasaland is a foreign country under British protection because the protected people of Nyasaland did not sanction it, thus the Legislative Council sitting that passed Federation was incompetent. …

“Mr. Chinyama: I am seconding the Motion in full. It is now six years, even over, since we, the Africans of Nyasaland have opposed, and are still opposing the scheme of Federation. … Africans in Nyasaland, from Chiefs to the commoner, to the women; they all oppose Federation. …

“Mr. Chipembere: We prefer, Mr. President, a poverty-stricken Nyasaland outside the Federation to a fabulously rich Nyasaland inside the Federation; even if Federation were so economically advantageous as to turn every African in this country into a millionaire we would not accept it, we should still oppose it even if it meant walking naked in the streets of Blantyre or Zomba. Thank you, Mr. President (Applause.)” (Nyasaland Protectorate: Proceedings of the Third Meeting of the Seventy-First Session of Legislative Council, Sth, 7th, 8th, and 9th February, 1957, 54, 56-7, 61. See also headlines and news reports on 1957 session in Rhodesia Herald: “Nyasaland Africans Walk out of Legislative Council Debates” (Feb. 9, 1957); “Nyasaland Debates: Africans Shatter All Hope of Co-operation” (Feb. 11, 1957).

40 Huxley, Aldous, Beyond the Mexique Bay (London, 1934).Google Scholar

41 Economics and Economic Policy of Dual Societies as Exemplified by Indonesia, 4.

42 Broek, Jan O. M., Economic Development of the Netherlands Indies (New York, 1942), 5.Google Scholar

43 Report of the East Africa Royal Commission, 390-4.

44 Quoted by Copland, , “The Under-Developed Countries and the Structure of the Western Economy,” 429.Google Scholar