Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-vsgnj Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-18T22:34:12.498Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Optimal Control of a Jump Mutual Insurance Process

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 August 2014

Charles S. Tapiero*
Affiliation:
Hebrew University, Jerusalem, Israel University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Extract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

We shall define a mutual insurance firm as a firm whose stockholders are the bearers of the insurance contracts issued by the firm. The firm's insurance is then viewed as a collective process of say N persons seeking to protect themselves against claims that may occur to any one of them. For example, large employers protecting their employees by pooling risks and deducting for protection given amounts from salaries may be a case in point. In this latter case, the employer may match withdrawals from employees salaries and provide in the process a fringe benefit and increase employees loyalty to the firm. Alternatively, agricultural collectives have in some cases established mutual insurance firms whose purposes are to protect them, at a cost, from the uncertainty implicit in their production processes and the fluctuations of agricultural markets. Since these firms do not work for profit, contingent payments, or fund reimbursement in case of excess cash holdings are typical control policies which help cover extraordinary claims and at the same time are assumed the best investment policies. To further protect themselves against extraordinary claims, mutual insurers can turn to reinsurance firms, “selling” for example the excess claims of, say, a given amount R (e.g., see Tapiero and Zuckerman (1982)). The purpose of this paper is to consider such a mutual insurance firm facing a jump stochastic claims process, as is often assumed in the insurance literature (e.g., Feller (1971), Borch (1974)). For example, Poisson and Compound Poisson processes are typical jump processes treated in this paper, although other processes could be considered as well (see Srinivasan (1973) and Srinivasan and Mehata (1976), Bensoussan and Tapiero (1982)). First we define the mutual insurer problem as a jump process stochastic control problem which we solve analytically under the assumption of a gamma density claim sizes distribution. A solution is obtained by applying arguments from stochastic dynamic programming and by solving the resultant functional equation by application of Laplace transforms (e.g., Colombo and Lavoine (1972), Miller (1956), Tapiero, Chapter V). Subsequently, the effects of reinsurance are introduced and preliminary results obtained. As in Tapiero and Zuckerman (1982), we assume that the mutual insurance firm is a direct underwriter and that the reinsurer is a leader in a Stackleberg game (Stackleberg (1952), Simman and Cruz (1973), Luce and Raiffa (1957)).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © International Actuarial Association 1982

References

Bensoussan, A. and Lions, J. L. (1980). Contrôle impulsionnel et applications. Dunod: Paris.Google Scholar
Bensoussan, A. and Tapiero, C. S. (1982). Impulsive control: prospects and applications. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borch, K. (1974). The Mathematical Theory of Insurance. Lexington Books: Lexington, Mass.Google Scholar
Colombo, S. and La Voire, J. (1972). Transformations de Laplace et de Mellin. Gautheir-Villars Editeur: Paris.Google Scholar
Dayananda, P. A. W. (1970). Optimal reinsurance. Journal of Applied Probability 7, 134156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feller, W. (1971). An Introduction to Probability and its Applications, Volume II. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.: New York.Google Scholar
Luce, R. D. and Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and Decisions. John Wiley & Sons, Inc.: New York.Google Scholar
Miller, S. K. (1956). Engineering Mathematics. Dover Publications: New York.Google Scholar
Simman, M., and Cruz, J. B. (1973). Additional aspects of the Stackelberg strategy in non zero sum-games. Journal of Optimization Theory and Applications 11, 613626.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Srinivasan, S. K. (1973). Stochastic Point Processes and their Applications. Griffin: London.Google Scholar
Srinivasan, S. K. and Mehata, K. M. (1976). Stochastic Processes. Tata McGraw Publishing Co. Ltd.: New Dehli.Google Scholar
Stackelberg, V. H. (1952). The Theory of Market Economy. Oxford University Press: Oxford.Google Scholar
Tapiero, C. S. (1977). Managerial Planning: An Optimum and Stochastic Control Approach. Gordon Breach Science Publ.: New York.Google Scholar
Tapiero, C. S. and Zuckerman, D. (1982). Optimum excess-of-loss reinsurance: A dynamic framework. Stochastic Processes and Applications, 12, 8596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vajda, S. (ed.) (1955). Non-Proportional Reinsurance. E. J. Brill: Leyden.CrossRefGoogle Scholar