Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-27T01:37:38.871Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Democratic Theory and the Public Interest: Condorcet and Rousseau Revisited

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 1989

David M. Estlund
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Jeremy Waldron
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Bernard Grofman
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Scott L. Feld
Affiliation:
State University of New York, Stony Brook

Abstract

Bernard Grofman and Scott Feld argued in the June 1988 issue of this Review that Jean-Jacques Rousseau's contributions to democratic political theory could be illuminated by invoking the theorizing of one of his eighteenth-century contemporaries, the Marquis de Condorcet, about individual and collective preferences or judgments. Grofman and Feld's claims about collective consciousness and the efficacy of the public interest provoke debate. One focus of discourse lies in the application of Condorcet's jury theorem to Rousseau's theory of the general will. In this controversy David M. Estlund and Jeremy Waldron in turn raise a variety of issues of theory and interpretation; Grofman and Feld then extend their argument, and propose clarifications.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, Kenneth J. 1963. Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1986. “An Evolutionary Approach to Norms.” American Political Science Review 80:10951111.10.1017/S0003055400185016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Keith M., ed. 1976. Condorcet: Selected Writings. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Barry, Brian. 1964. “The Public Interest.” Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society 38:914.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bordley, Robert F. 1986. “Review Essay: Bayesian Group Decision Theory.” In Information Pooling and Croup Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James, and Tullock, Gordon. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Joshua. 1986. “An Epistemic Conception of Democracy.” Ethics 97:2638.10.1086/292815CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, Jules, and Ferejohn, John. 1986. “Democracy and Social Choice.” Ethics 97:625.10.1086/292814CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Condorcet, Marquis de. 1976. Condorcet: Selected Writings. Ed. Baker, Keith Michael. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Dalkey, Norman C. 1969a. The Delphi Method: An Experimental Study of Croup Opinion. Santa Monica: Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
Dalkey, Norman C. 1969b. “An Experimental Study of Group Opinion: the Delphi Method.” Futures 1 (5):408–26.10.1016/S0016-3287(69)80025-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalkey, Norman C. 1986. “Information Pooling As the Composition of Inquiry Systems,” in Information Pooling and Croup Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Dworkin, Ronald. 1986. Law's Empire. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Estlund, David. N.d. “Democracy without Preference.” The Philosophical Review. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Federal Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas. 1944. 320 U.S. 591, 127.Google Scholar
Feld, Scott L., and Grofman, Bernard N.. 1984. “The Accuracy of Group Majority Decisions in Groups with Added Members.” Public Choice 42:273–85.10.1007/BF00124946CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, Scott L., and Grofman, Bernard N.. 1986a. “On the Possibility of Faithfully Representative Committees.” American Political Science Review 80:863–79.10.2307/1960542CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, Scott L., and Grofman, Bernard N.. 1986b. “Partial Single-Peakedness: An Extension and Clarification.” Public Choice 51:7180.10.1007/BF00141686CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, Scott L., and Grofman, Bernard N.. 1988. “Ideological Consistency As a Collective Phenomenon.” American Political Science Review 82:6475.10.2307/1962490CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaertner, W. and Heinecke, A. 1978. “Cyclically Mixed Preferences—A Necessary and Sufficient Condition for Transitivity of the Social Preference Relation.” In Decision Theory and Social Ethics, ed. Goltinger, Hans W. and Leinfellner, Werner. Dordrecht: Reidel.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N. 1974. “Helping Behavior and Group Size, Some Exploratory Stochiastic Models.” Behavioral Science 19:219–24.10.1002/bs.3830190402CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N. 1975. “A Comment on Democratic Theory: A Preliminary Mathematical Model.” Public Choice 21:99104.10.1007/BF01705949CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N. 1978. “Judgmental Competence of Individuals and Groups in a Dichotomous Choice Situation: Is a Majority of Heads Better Than One?Journal of Mathematical Sociology 6:4760.10.1080/0022250X.1978.9989880CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N. 1979. “A Preliminary Model of Jury Decision Making As a Function of Jury Size, Effective Jury Decision Rule, and Mean Juror Judgmental Competence.” In Frontiers of Economics, vol. 3, ed. Arrow, Kenneth J. and Honkapohja, Seppo.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N. 1980. “The Slippery Slope: Jury Size and Jury Verdict Requirements—Legal and Social Science Approaches.” Law and Politics Quarterly 2 (3):285304.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N., and Feld, Scott L.. 1984. “Group Size and the Performance of a Composite Group Majority: Statistical Truths and Empirical Results.” Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 33:350–59.10.1016/0030-5073(84)90028-XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N., and Feld, Scott L.. 1986. “Determining Optimal Weights for Expert Judgment.” In Information Pooling and Group Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N., and Feld, Scott L.. 1988. “Rousseau's General Will: A Condorcetian Perspective.” American Political Science Review 82:567–76.10.2307/1957401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N., Feld, Scott, and Owen, Guillermo. 1982. “Evaluating the Competence of Experts, Pooling Individual Judgments into a Collective Choice, and Delegating Decision Responsibility to Subgroups.” In Dependence and Inequality, ed. Geyer, Felix and van der Zouwen, Hans. New York: Pergamon.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard N., and Norrander, Barbara. N.d. “Efficient Use of Reference Group Cues in a Single Dimension.” Public Choice. Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Grofman, Bernard, Owen, Guillermo, and Feld, Scott L.. 1983. “Thirteen Theorems in Search of the Truth.” Theory and Decision 15:261–78.10.1007/BF00125672CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gustafson, David H., Lebeq, R. K., and Walsten, G. W.. 1973. “A Comparative Study of Differences in Subjective Likelihood Estimates Made by Individuals, Interacting Groups, and Nominal Groups.” Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 9:280–91.10.1016/0030-5073(73)90052-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hastie, Reid. 1986. “Review Essay: Experimental Evidence on Group Accuracy.” In Information Pooling and Croup Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Kintzler, Catherine. 1984. Condorcet: L'instruction publique et la naissance du citoyen. Paris: Minerve.Google Scholar
Lowi, Theodore J. 1969. End of Liberalism: Ideology, Policy, and the Crisis of Public Authority. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Mansbridge, Jane J. 1980. Beyond Adversary Democracy. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Mansbridge, Jane J. 1981. “Living with Conflict: Representation in the Theory of Adversary Democracy.” Ethics 92:466–76.10.1086/292254CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1975. John Stuart Mill: Three Essays. Ed. Wollheim, Richard. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nitzan, Shmuel, and Paroush, Jacob. 1982. “Optimal Decision Rules in Uncertain Dichotomous Choice Situations.” International Economic Review 23 (2):288–97.10.2307/2526438CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitzan, Shmuel, and Paroush, Jacob. 1985. Collective Decision Making: An Economic Approach. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. New York: Shocken.Google Scholar
Owen, Guillermo. 1986. “‘Fair’ Indirect Majority Rules.” In Information Pooling and Group Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1976. “Axiomatic Social Choice Theory: An Overview and Interpretation.” American Journal of Political Science 20:511–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Redford, Emmette Shelburn. 1958. “The Never-ending Search for the Public Interest.” In Ideals and Practice in Public Administration, ed. Redford, E. S.. Alabama: University of Alabama Press.Google Scholar
Riker, William. 1982. Liberalism Against Populism. New York: Freeman.Google Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques. 1964. Oeuvres Completes. Ed. Gagnebin, Bernard and Raymond, Marcel. Paris: Bibliotheque de la Pleiade.Google Scholar
Runciman, W. G., and Sen, Amartya K.. 1965. “Games, Justice, and the General Will.” Mind 74:554–62.10.1093/mind/LXXIV.296.554CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul Anthony. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. 1966. “A Possibility Theorem on Majority Decisions.” Econometrica 34:491–99.10.2307/1909947CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapley, Lloyd S., and Grofman, Bernard. 1984. “Optimizing Group Judgmental Accuracy in the Presence of Interdependencies.” Public Choice 43:329–43.10.1007/BF00118940CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shklar, Judith. 1969. Men and Citizens: A Study of Rousseau's Social Theory. Oxford: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Urken, Arnold B., and Traflet, S.. 1984. “Optimal Jury Design.” Jurimetrics 24:218–35.Google Scholar
Walzer, Michael. 1983. Spheres of Justice: A Defense of Pluralism and Equality. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Young, H. Peyton. 1986. “Optimal Ranking and Choice from Pairwise Comparisons.” In Information Pooling and Croup Decision Making, ed. Grofman, Bernard and Owen, Guillermo. Westport, CT: JAI.Google Scholar
Young, H. Peyton. 1988. “Condorcet's Theory of Voting.” American Political Science Review 82: 1231–44.10.2307/1961757CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.