Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-4rdpn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T18:01:33.610Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

18 - Network economics: neutrality, competition, and service differentiation

from Part IV - Theory and models

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 October 2012

John Musacchio
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Cruz, USA
Galina Schwartz
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley, USA
Jean Walrand
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley, USA
Byrav Ramamurthy
Affiliation:
University of Nebraska, Lincoln
George N. Rouskas
Affiliation:
North Carolina State University
Krishna Moorthy Sivalingam
Affiliation:
Indian Institute of Technology, Madras
Get access

Summary

In 2007 Comcast, a cable TV and Internet service provider in the United States, began to selectively rate limit or “shape” the traffic from users of the peer-to-peer application Bit Torrent. The access technology that Comcast uses is asymmetric in its capacity – the “uplink” from users is much slower than the “downlink.” For client-server applications like Web, this asymmetry is fine, but for peer-to-peer, where home users are serving up huge files for others to download, the uplink quickly becomes congested. Comcast felt that it had to protect the rest of its users from a relatively small number of heavy peer-to-peer users that were using a disproportionate fraction of the system's capacity. In other words, peer-to-peer users were imposing a negative externality by creating congestion that harmed other users.

This negative externality reduces the welfare of the system because users act selfishly. The peer-to-peer user is going to continue to exchange movies even though this action is disrupting his neighbor's critical, work-related video conference. Comcast thought that by singling out users of peer-to-peer applications, it could limit the ill effects of this externality and keep the rest of its users (who mostly don't use peer-to-peer) happy. Instead Comcast's decision placed them in the center of the ongoing network neutrality debate. Supporters of the network neutrality concept feel that the Internet access provider ought not to be allowed to “discriminate” between traffic of different users or different applications.

Type
Chapter
Information
Next-Generation Internet
Architectures and Protocols
, pp. 378 - 402
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

E., Whitacre, At SBC, it's all about ‘scale and scope.’Business Week, Interview by R. O. Crockett, (November 7, 2005).Google Scholar
J., Musacchio, G., Schwartz, and J., Walrand, A two-sided market analysis of provider investment incentives with an application to the net neutrality issue. Review of Network Economics, 8:1 (2009), 22–39.Google Scholar
A., Odlyzko, Network neutrality, search neutrality, and the never-ending conflict between efficiency and fairness in markets. Review of Network Economics, 8 (2009), 40–60.Google Scholar
R. B., Chong, The 31 flavors of the net neutrality debate: Beware the trojan horse. Advanced Communications Law and Policy Institute, Scholarship Series, New York Law School, (December 2007).Google Scholar
Federal Trade Commission, Broadband connectivity competition policy. Report (June 2007).
Department of Justice, Comments on network neutrality in federal communications commission proceeding. Press Release, (September 7, 2007).
J.-C., Rochet and J., Tirole, Two-sided markets: A progress report. RAND Journal of Economics, 37:3 (2006), 655–667.Google Scholar
M., Armstrong, Competition in two sided markets. RAND Journal of Economics, 37:3 (2006), 668–691.Google Scholar
B., Hermalin and M., Katz, The economics of product-line restrictions with an application to the network neutrality controversy. Information Economics and Policy, 19 (2007), 215–248.Google Scholar
C., Hogendorn, Broadband internet: Net neutrality versus open access. International Economics and Economic Policy, 4 (2007), 185–208.Google Scholar
P., Weiser, Report from the Center for the New West putting network neutrality in perspective. Center for the New West discussion paper (January 2007).
A., Dixit and J., Stiglitz, Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. The American Economic Review, 67:3 (1977), 297–308.Google Scholar
J., Thijssen, Investment Under Uncertainty, Coalition Spillovers and Market Evolution in a Game Theoretic Perspective, (Springer, 2004).Google Scholar
J., Musacchio, G., Schwartz, and J., Walrand, A Two-Sided Market Analysis of Provider Investment Incentives With an Application to the Net-Neutrality Issue, School of Engineering, Universitiy of California, Santa Cruz, UCSCSOE-09-08 (2009).Google Scholar
J. A., Kay, Tax policy: A survey. The Economic Journal, 100:399 (1990), 18–75.Google Scholar
T., Roughgarden, Stackelberg scheduling strategies. In Proceedings of the 33rd Annual Symposium ACM Symposium on Theory of Computing, (2001), 104–13.Google Scholar
T., Roughgarden, How bad is selfish routing? Journal of ACM, 49:2 (2002), 236–259.Google Scholar
T., Roughgarden, The price of anarchy is independent of the network topology. Journal of Computer and System Sciences, 67:2 (2003), 341–364.Google Scholar
J., Feigenbaum, R., Sami, and S., Shenker, Mechanism design for policy routing. Distributed Computing, 18 (2006), 293–305.Google Scholar
D., Acemoglu and A., Ozdaglar, Competition and efficiency in congested markets. Mathematics of Operations Research, 32:1 (2007), 1–31.Google Scholar
A., Ozdaglar, Price competition with elastic traffic. Networks, 52:3 (2008), 141–155.Google Scholar
A., Hayrapetyan, E., Tardos, and T., Wexler, A network pricing game for selfish traffic. Distributed Computing, 19:4 (2007), 255–266.Google Scholar
J., Musacchio and S., Wu, The price of anarchy in a network pricing game. In Proceedings of the 45th Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing, Monticello, IL, (2007), 882–891.Google Scholar
E., Koutsoupias and C. H., Papadimitriou, Worst-case equilibria. In Proceedings of the 16th Annual Symposium on Theoretical Aspects of Computer Science, Trier, Germany, (1999), 404–413.Google Scholar
D., Acemoglu and A., Ozdaglar, Competition in parallel-serial networks. IEEE Journal on Selected Areas in Communications, 25:6 (2007), 1180–1192.Google Scholar
J., Musacchio, The Price of Anarchy in Parallel-Serial Competition with Elastic Demand, School of Engineering, University of California, Santa Cruz, UCSC-SOE-09-20 (2009).Google Scholar
J., Wardrop, Some theoretical aspects of road traffic research. Proceedings of the Institute of Civil Engineers, Part II, 1:36 (1952), 352–362.Google Scholar
A. C., Pigou, The Economics of Welfare, (Macmillan, 1920).Google Scholar
L., Chua, C., Desoer, and E., Kuh, Linear and Nonlinear Circuits, (McGraw-Hill, 1987).Google Scholar
J., Walrand, Economic models of communication networks. In Performance Modeling and Engineering, ed. Xia and Liu. (Springer, 2008), pp. 57–90.Google Scholar
J., Musacchio and S., Wu, The price of anarchy in differentiated services networks. In Proceedings of the 46th Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing, Monticello, IL, (2008), 615–622.Google Scholar
J., Musacchio, J., Walrand, and S., Wu, A game theoretic model for network upgrade decisions. In Proceedings of the 44th Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing, Monticello, IL, (2006), 191–200.
Y., Jin, S., Sen, R., Guerin, K., Hosanagar, and Z.-L., Zhang, Dynamics of competition between incumbent and emerging network technologies. In Proceedings of the ACM NetEcon08: The Workshop on the Economics of Networks, Systems, and Computation, Seattle, WA, (2008), 49–54.Google Scholar
G., Schwartz, N., Shetty, and J., Walrand, Network neutrality: Avoiding the extremes. In Proceedings of the 46th Annual Allerton Conference on Communication, Control, and Computing, Monticello, IL, (2008), 1086–1093.Google Scholar
A., Odlyzko, Paris metro pricing for the internet. In Proceedings of the 1st ACM conference on Electronic Commerce, Denver, CO, (1999), 140–147.Google Scholar
R., Gibbens, R., Mason, and R., Steinberg, Internet service classes under competition. IEEE Journal on Selected Areas in Communications, 18:12 (2000), 2490–2498.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×