Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T10:43:18.112Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 September 2012

Avner Greif
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy
Lessons from Medieval Trade
, pp. 453 - 488
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abercrombie, Nicholas, Hill, Stephen, and Turner, Bryan S.. 1994. The Dictionary of Sociology. 3rd ed. London: Penguin GroupGoogle Scholar
Abou El Fadl, Khaled. 2001. Rebellion and Violence in Islamic Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” Journal of Economic History 46 (2): 385–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip. 1988. “On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting.” Econometrica 56: 383–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Milgrom, Paul R., and Pearce, David G.. 1991. “Information and Timing in Repeated Partnerships.” Econometrica 59 (6): 1713–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Pearce, David G., and Stacchetti, Ennio. 1986. “Optimal Cartel Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring.” Journal of Economic Theory 39 (June): 251–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abulafia, David. 1977. The Two Italies. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abulafia, David. 1985. “Catalan Merchants and the Western Mediterranean, 1236–1300: Studies in the Notarial Acts of Barcelona and Sicily.” Viator 16: 209–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abu-Lughod, Janet. 1991. Before European Hegemony: The World System, A. D. 1250–1350. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (Dec.): 1369–1401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2002. “The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth.” Memo, MITCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2000. “Political Losers as a Barrier to Economic Development.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 90: 126–30Google Scholar
Airaldi, Gabriella. 1983. “Groping in the Dark: The Emergence of Genoa in the Early Middle Ages.” Miscellanea di Studi Storia 2: 7–17Google Scholar
Airaldi, Gabriella. 1986. Genova e la Liguria nel Medioevo. Turin: Utet LibreriaGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1986. An Economic Theorist's Book of Tales. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Kranton, R. E.. 2000. “Economics and Identity.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 715–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Yellen, Janet L.. 1986. Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
AlSayyad, Nezar. 1991. Cities and Caliphs: On the Genesis of Arab Muslim Urbanism. New York: GreenwoodGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James, and Miller, John. 2002. “Giving According to GARP: An Experimental Test of the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism.” Econometrica 70 (2): 737–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Annali Genovesi di Caffaro e dei suoi Continuatori. 1099–1240. Trans. Ceccardo Roccatagliata Ceccardi and Giovanni Monleone. 4 vols. Genoa: Municipio di Genova, 1923–29
Annen, Kurt. 2003. “Social Capital, Inclusive Networks, and Economic Performance.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (4): 449–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 1994. “The Contingent Governance of Teams: Analysis of Institutional Complementarity.” International Economic Review 35 (3): 657–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Arias, G. 1901. I trattati commerciali della Repubblica Fiorentina. Florence: Successori le MonnierGoogle Scholar
Aron, J. 2000. “Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence.” World Bank Research Observer 15 (1): 99–135CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1981. “Optimal and Voluntary Income Redistribution.” In Rosenfield, Steven (ed.), Economic Welfare and the Economics of Soviet Socialism: Essays in Honor of Abram Bergson, 267–88. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, Brian W. 1988. “Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics.” In Arrow, K. J. and Anderson, P. (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, 9–33. New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Arthur, Brian W. 1994. Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashburner, M., and Walter, A.. 1909. The Rodian Sea-Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. 1987. “Game Theory.” In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 2: 460–82. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J., and Brandenburger, Adam. 1995. “Epistemic Conditions for Nash Equilibrium.” Econometrica 65 (5): 1161–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J., and Hart, Sergiu (eds.). 1994, 2002. Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Implications. Vols. 2, 3. North Holland: Elsevier Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Bairoch, Paul, Batou, Jean, and Chèvre, Pierre (eds.). 1988. The Population of European Cities from 800 to 1850. Geneva: Center of International Economic HistoryGoogle Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep, and Polak, Ben. 2004. “The Emergence and Persistence of the Anglo-Saxon and German Financial Systems.” Review of Financial Studies 17 (1): 129–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R. 2001. “Individualism, Collectivism, and Economic Development.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 573 (Jan.): 57–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard, Adolphus, and Tait, James (eds.). 1913. British Borough Charters, 1042–1216. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Ballard, Adolphus, and Tait, James (eds.). 1923. British Borough Charters, 1216–1307. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bandura, A. 1971. Social Learning Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. V., and Newman, A. F.. 1993. “Occupational Choice and the Process of Development.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (2): 274–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S., and Randall L. Calvert. 1989. “Communication and Efficiency in Coordination Games.” Working Paper No. 196. Department of Political Science, University of Rochester
Barbadoro, Bernardino. 1921. Consigli della Reppublica Fiorentina. Bologna: R. Accademia dei Lincei, Forni EditoreGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab. 1991. “Alternative Approaches to the Theory of Institutions in Economic Development.” In Bardhan, Pranab (ed.), The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, 3–17. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 2002. A Theory of the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 2001. Prosperity and Violence: The Political Economy of Development. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Figueiredo, R. J. P., and Weingast, B. R.. 1998. “The Politics of Interpretation: Rationality, Culture, and Transition.” Politics & Society 26 (4): 603–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Greif, Avner, Levi, Margaret, Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, and Weingast, Barry. 1998. Analytic Narrative. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Greif, Avner, and Singh, Smita. 2002. “Organizing Violence.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (5): 599–628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1974. “A Theory of Social Interactions.” Journal of Political Economy 82: 1963–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belgrano, Luigi T. 1873. Tavole genealogiche a corredo della illustrazione del registro arcivescovile de Genova. Genoa: Atti della Società Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Bellah, Robert N., Madsen, Richard, Sullivan, William M., Swidler, Ann, and Tipton, Steven M.. 1985. Habits of the Heart: Individualism and Commitment in American Life. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Bellamy, John. 1973. Crime and the Courts in England, 1660–1800. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Benabou, R. 1994. “Education, Income Distribution, and Growth: The Local Connection.” Working paper, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Bendor, Jonathan, and Mookherjee, Dilip. 1990. “Norms, Third-Party Sanctions, and Cooperation.” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 6 (Spring): 33–63Google Scholar
Benjamin of Tudela. 1159–1173. Itinerary. Trans. Michael Singer, Marcus N. Adler, and A. Asher. Malibu, Calif.: Joseph Simon/Pangloss Press, 1987
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Putterman, Louis (eds.). 1998. Economics, Values and Organization. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, Jean-Pierre, and Krishna, Vijay. 1985. “Finitely Repeated Games.” Econometrica 53 (4): 905–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bensa, Enrico. 1925. The Early History of Bills of Lading. Genoa: Stabilimento D'arti GraficheGoogle Scholar
Ben-Sasson, Menahem. 1991. The Jews of Sicily, 825–1068 (in Hebrew and Judeo-Arabic). Jerusalem: Ben-Zevi InstituteGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce L. 1989. “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law.” Southern Economic Journal 55 (3): 644–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beresford, M., and Finberg, H. P. R.. 1973. English Medieval Boroughs: A Handlist. Newton Abbott: David and CharlesGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L. 1977. Invitation to Sociology. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L., and Luckmann, Thomas. 1967. The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Anchor BooksGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, Daniel, Pistor, Katherian, and Richard, Jean-François. 2003. “Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect.” European Economic Review 47 (1): 165–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Harold J. 1983. Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1984. “Rationalizable Strategic Behavior.” Econometrica 52 (4): 1007–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Ray, Debraj. 1989. “Collective Dynamic Consistency in Dynamic Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (4): 295–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Whinston, Michael D.. 1990. “Multi-market Contract and Collusive Behavior.” Rand Journal of Economics 21 (1): 1–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, L. 1992. “Opting Out the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies 21 (Jan.): 115–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertolotto, Gerolamo. 1896. “Nuova serie di documenti sulle relazioni di Genova coll' Impero Bizantino.” In Atti della Società Ligure de Storia Patria, XXVIII. Genoa: Società Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Besley, Tim, and Coate, Stephen. 1995. “Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and Social Collateral.” Journal of Development Economics 46 (1): 1–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bester, H., and Güth, W.. 1998. “Is Altruism Evolutionarily Stable?Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 34: 193–209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth. 1996. “A Note on Backward Induction.” Games and Economic Behavior 17 (1): 135–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth, Gale, John, and Samuelson, Larry. 1995. “Learning to be Imperfect: The Ultimatum Game.” Games and Economic Behavior 8: 56–90Google Scholar
Bittles, Alan H. 1994. “The Role and Significance of Consanguinity as a Demographic Variable.” Population and Development Review 20 (3): 561–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blau, Joshua, 1961. A Grammar of Medieval Judaeo-Arabic. Jerusalem: Magnes PressGoogle Scholar
Blau, Joshua. 1965. The Emergence and Linguistic Background of Judaeo-Arabic. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Marc. 1961. Feudal Society. Vol. 1. Trans. L. A. Manyon. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, Iris, and Frey, Bruno S.. 1999. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games: Comment.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 335–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Gary E., and Ockenfels, Axel. 2000. “A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity and Competition.” American Economic Review 90 (1): 166–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouman, F. J. A. 1995. “Rotating and Accumulating Savings and Credit Associations: A Development Perspective.” World Development 23 (3): 371–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 1976. Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and the Contradictions of Economic Life. New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 1998. “The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity.” Santa Fe Institute Working Paper, 98–08–073E
Brinton, Mary, and Nee, Victor (eds.). 1998. The New Institutionalism in Sociology. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Britnell, R. H. 1996. The Commercialisation of English Society, 1000–1500. 2nd ed. New York: Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1999. The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. Fairfax, VA: Liberty FundGoogle Scholar
Bull, Clive. 1987. “The Existence of Self-Enforcing Implicit Contracts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (1): 147–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulow, Jeremy, and Rogoff, Kenneth. 1989. “A Constant Reconstracting Model of Sovereign Debt.” Journal of Political Economy 97 (1): 155–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1916–17. “Commercial Contracts of the Genoese in the Syrian Trade of the Twelfth Century.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 31: 128–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1920. “Genoese Trade with Syria in the Twelfth Century.” American Historical Review 25: 191–219CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1928. “The Genoese Colonies in Syria.” In Paetow, L. J. (ed.), The Crusade and Other Historical Essays, 139–82. New York: F. S. Crofts
Cahen, Claude. 1990. “Economy, Society, Institutions.” In Holt, P. M., Lambton, Ann K. S., and Lewis, Bernard (eds.), The Cambridge History of Islam, 511–38. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Calendar of Letters from the Mayor and Corporation of the City of London. Circa A. D. 1350–60. Ed. Sharpe, Reginald R.. London: Corporation of the City of London, 1885Google Scholar
Calendar of Plea and Memoranda Rolls Preserved among the Archives of the Corporation of the City of London at the Guild Hall. 1926–61. Corporation of London. 6 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Calendar of the Patent Rolls Preserved in the Public Record Office. English Historical Documents. 1893–1910. 14 vols. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office
Calvert, Randall L. 1992. “Leadership and Its Basis in Problems of Social Coordination.” International Political Science Review 13 (1): 7–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995. “Rational Actors, Equilibrium, and Social Institutions.” In Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai (eds.), Explaining Social Institutions, 57–93. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin, and Ari Vespsalaninen. 1987. “The Efficiency of Corporate Culture.” Paper presented at the Colloquium on Strategy Content Research, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania
Campos, N. F., and Nugent, J. B.. 2002. “Who Is afraid of Political Instability?Journal of Development Economics 67 (1): 157–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardini, Franco. 1978. “Profilo di un Crociato Guglielmo Embriaco.” Acrchivo Storico Italiano 2–4: 405–36Google Scholar
Carus-Wilson, E. M. 1967. Medieval Merchant Venturers. London: Butler and TannerGoogle Scholar
Casella, A., and Rauch, J. E.. 2002. “Anonymous Market and Group Ties in International Trade.” Journal of International Economics 58 (1): 19–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Catoni, Giuliano. 1976. “La brutta avventura di un mercante senese nel 1309 e una questione di rappresaglia.” Archivo Storico Italiano 479: 65–77Google Scholar
Cavalli-Sforza, Luigi L., and Feldman, Marcus W.. 1981. Cultural Transmission and Evolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chamley, Christophe P. 2004. Rational Herds: Economic Models of Social Learning. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Charness, Gary, and Grosskopf, Brit. 2001. “Relative Payoffs and Happiness: An Experimental Study.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 45: 301–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, Gary, and Rabin, Matthew. 2002. “Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (3): 817–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiani, Emilio. 1962. Nobilta' e popolo nel Comune di Pisa. Instituto Italiano per gli Studi Storici, 13. Milan: Casa Editrice EinaudiGoogle Scholar
Chwe, Michael Suk Young. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Cipolla, Carlo M. 1993. Before the Industrial Revolution. 3rd ed. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Çizakça, Murat. 1996. A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships. Leiden: E. J. BrillGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andy. 1997a. “Economic Reason: The Interplay of Individual Learning and External Structure.” In Drobak, John and Nye, John (eds.), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 269–90. San Diego, CA: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andy. 1997b. Being There: Putting the Brain, Body, and World Togther Again. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Clark, Gregory. 1991. “Yields per Acre in English Agriculture, 1250–1860: Evidence from Labour Inputs.” Economic History Review 44 (3): 445–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, Karen. 1997. “Trade, Institutions, and Credit.” Explorations in Economic History 34 (4): 495–521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Close Rolls of the Reign of Henry III. 1227–72. 14 vols. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office, 1902–38
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica, n.s., 4: 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Codice diplomatico della Repubblica di Genova dal ⅯⅭⅬⅫII [sic] al ⅯⅭⅬXXXX [sic]. 1936, 1938, 1942, Ed. di Sant'Angelo, Cesare Imperiale. Vols. I–III. Rome: Tipografia del Senato
Cole, Harold L., Mailath, George J., and Postlewaite, Andrew. 1992. “Social Norms, Saving Behavior and Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (6): 1092–1125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Collier, David, and Collier, Ruth. 1991. Shaping the Political Arena. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Collins, Kathleen. 2004. “The Logic of Clan Politics – Evidence from Central Asian Trajectories.” World Politics 56 (2): 224–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colvin, Ian D. 1971. The Germans in England, 1066–1598. London: Kennikat PressGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Conlisk, J. 1996. “Why Bounded Rationality?Journal of Economic Literature 34 (2): 669–700Google Scholar
Constable, R. Olivia. 2003. Housing the Stranger in the Mediterranean World: Lodging, Trade, and Travel in Late Antiquity and the Middle Ages. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Cook, Mechael. 2003. Forbidding Wrong in Islam. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coulton, G. G. (ed.). 1918. Social Life in Britain from the Conquest to the Reformation. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crawford, S., and Ostrom, Elinor. 1995. “A Grammar of Institutions.” American Political Review 89 (3): 582–600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, Jacques. 1986. “Cooperation in Ongoing Organizations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (1): 33–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2002. Roman, Provincial and Islamic Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2003. Slaves on Horses. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2004. God's Rule: Government and Islam. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
D'Andrade, R. G. 1984. “Cultural Meaning Systems.” In Shweder, R. A. and LeVine, R. A. (eds.), Culture Theory: Essays on Mind, Self, and Emotion, 88–122. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha. 2000. “Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital.” In Dasgupta, Partha and Serageldin, Ismail (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, 325–424. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha, and Serageldin, Ismail (eds.). 2000. Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
David, Paul A. 1985. “Clio and the Economics of Qwerty.” American Economic Review 75 (2): 332–37Google Scholar
David, Paul A. 1994. “Why Are Institutions the ‘Carriers of History’?: Path-Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations and Institutions.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 5 (2): 205–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, Douglas D., and Holt, Charles A.. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Davis, Kingsley. 1949. Human Society. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M., and Thaler, Richard H.. 1988. “Anomalies: Cooperation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2 (3): 187–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, John. 1963. Les douanes de genes, 1376–1377. Paris: S. E. V. P. E. N.Google Scholar
Day, Gerald W. 1984. “The Impact of the Third Crusade upon Trade with the Levant.” International History Review 3 (Apr.): 159–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, Gerald W. 1988. Genoa's Response to Byzantium, 1154–1204. Urbana: University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
De Figueiredo, Rui, Jack Rakove, and Barry R. Weingast. 2001. “Rationality, Inaccurate Mental Models, and Self-Confirming Equilibrium: A New Understanding of the American Revolution.” Memo, Stanford University
Dekel, E., Fudenberg, D., and Levine, D. K.. 1999. “Payoff Information and Self-Confirming Equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Theory 89 (2): 165–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negri, Teoflio Ossian. 1986. Storia di Genova. Florence: G. MartelloGoogle Scholar
Denzau, A., and North, D. C.. 1994. “Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions.” Kyklos 47: 3–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roover, Raymond. 1948. Money, Banking and Credit in Mediaeval Bruges. Cambridge, MA: Mediaeval Academy of AmericaGoogle Scholar
Roover, Raymond. 1963. The Rise and Decline of the Medici Bank, 1397–1494. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
de Roover, Raymond. 1965. “The Organization of Trade.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3:42–118. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Jared. 1997. Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul. 1994. “Culture and Economy.” In Smelser, Neil and Swedberg, Richard (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 27–57. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul. 1997. “The New Institutionalism: Avenues of Collaboration.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154: 1–10Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul, and W. Powell. 1991a. Introduction. In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 1–40. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul, and W. Powell. 1991b. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 63–82. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Nalebuff, Barry. 1991. Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics and Everyday Life. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, Glaeser, Edward L., Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2003. “The New Comparative Economics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (4): 595–619CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, F. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railroad Age. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dollinger, Philippe. 1970. The German Hansa. Stanford, CA.: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Donaver, Federico. 1990 [1890]. Storia di Genova. Genoa: Nuova Editrice GenoveseGoogle Scholar
Duby, Georges. 1974. The Early Growth of the European Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Duffy, Bella. 1903. The Tuscan Republics (Florence, Siena, Pisa and Lucca) with Genoa. New York: G. P. Putnam's SonsGoogle Scholar
Dugger, William M. 1990. “The New Insitutionalism: New but Not Insitutionalist.” Journal of Economic Issues 24 (2): 423–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1950 [1895]. The Rules of Sociological Method. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1953. Sociology and Philosophy. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Easterly, William. 2001. The Illusive Quest for Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Easterly, William, and R. Levine. 2002. “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development.” Mimeo, Center for Global Development and Institute for International Economics
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., Hébert, Robert F., Tollison, Robert D., Anderson, Gary M., and Davidson, Audrey B.. 1996. Sacred Trust: The Medieval Church as an Economic Firm. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Tollison, Robert D.. 1981. Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Order without Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellison, Glenn. 1993. “Learning, Local Interaction, and Coordination.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1047–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellison, Glenn. 1994. “Cooperation in the Prisoner's Dilemma with Anonymous Random Matching.” Review of Economic Studies 61 (3): 567–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1983. Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1989a. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1989b. “Social Norms and Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (4): 99–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 2000. “Rational Choice History: A Case of Excessive Ambition.” American Political Science Review 94 (3): 685–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ely, J., and O. Yilankaya. 1997. “Evolution of Preferences and Nash Equilibrium.” Mimeo, Northwestern University
Emery, R. 1952. “The Use of the Surname in the Study of Medieval Economic History.” Medievalia et Humanistica 7: 43–50Google Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. 1997. “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies.” In Haber, Stephen (ed.), How Did Latin America Fall Behind?, 260–304. Stanford, CA: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
English, Edward D. 1988. Enterprise and Liability in Sienese Banking, 1230–1350. Cambridge, MA: Medieval Academy of AmericaGoogle Scholar
English Historical Documents, 1042–1189. 1968. Ed. Douglas, D. C. and Greenaway, G. W.. Vol. 2. London: Eyre and SpottiswoodeGoogle Scholar
English Historical Documents, 1189–1327. 1975. Ed. Rothwell, H.. Vol. 3. London: Eyre and SpottiswoodeGoogle Scholar
Ensminger, Jean. 1997. “Changing Property Rights: Reconciling Formal and Informal Rights to Land in Africa.” In Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V. C. (eds.), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 165–96. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1984. Wills and Wealth in Medieval Genoa, 1150–1250. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1991. Wage Labor and Guilds in Medieval Europe. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1996. Genoa and the Genoese, 958–1528. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven. R. 1998. “Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship and Technological Change in Preindustrial Europe.” Journal of Economic History 53 (4): 684–713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven. R. 2000. Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Markets in Europe, 1300–1750. New York: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eysenck, M. W., and Keane, M. T.. 1995. Cognitive Psychology: A Student's Handbook. Hillsdale, MI: Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Face, Richard D. 1952. “The Embriaci: Feudal Imperialists of the Twelfth-Century Genoa.” M. A. thesis, University of Cincinnati
Face, Richard D. 1958. “Techniques of Business in the Trade between the Fairs of Champagne and the South of Europe in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries.” Economic History Review 10 (3): 427–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Face, Richard D. 1980. “Secular History in Twelfth Century Italy: Caffaro of Genoa.” Journal of Medieval History 6 (2): 169–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel. 2004. Market Institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Falk, Armin, and Urs Fischbacher. 2000. “A Theory of Reciprocity.” Working Paper No. 6, University of Zurich
Farrell, Joseph, and Maskin, Eric. 1989. “Renegotiation in Repeated Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (3): 327–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1991. “Counterfactuals and Hypothesis-Testing in Political-Science.” World Politics 43 (2): 169–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1997. “Bargaining over Objects That Influence Future Bargaining Power.” Working paper, Department of Political Science, University of Chicago
Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D.. 1996. “Explaining Interethnic Cooperation.” American Political Science Review 90 (4): 715–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Urs Fischbacher. 2001. “Reputation and Retaliation.” Mimeo, University of Zürich
Fehr, Ernst, and Gächter, Simon. 2000. “Cooperation and Punishment in Public Good Experiments.” American Economic Review 90 (4): 980–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 1999. “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 817–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 2001. “Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications.” Working Paper 75, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zürich
Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 2003. “Theories of Fairness and Reciprosity: Evidence and Economic Applications.” In Dewatripont, Mathias, Hansen, Lars Peter, and Turnovsky, Stephen (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, 1:208–56. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Fernandez, Raquel, and Rodrik, Dani. 1991. “Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 81 (5): 1146–55Google Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim, and Weiss, Yoram. 1993. “Social Status, Culture and Economic Performance.” Economic Journal 103 (July): 946–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, Alexander. 1981. “The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference to the North-Thomas Model of Pre-1500 Europe.” Explorations in Economic History 18 (2): 174–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, Alexander. 2002. Altruistically Inclined?: The Behavioral Sciences, Evolutionary Theory, and the Origins of Reciprocity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs, Gächter, Simon, and Fehr, Ernst. 2001. “Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment.” Economic Letters 71: 397–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischel, Walter J. 1958. “The Spice Trade in Mamluk Egypt.” Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient 1 (2): 157–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Horowitz, Joel, Savin, N. S., and Sefton, Martin. 1994. “Fairness in Simple Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 6: 347–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1998. Reorient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 1987. “If Homo Economics Could Choose His Own Utility Function, Would He Want One with a Conscience?American Economic Review 77 (4): 593–604Google Scholar
French, H. R., and Hoyle, R. W.. 2003. “English Individualism Refuted – and Reasserted: The Land Market of Earls Clone (Essex), 1550–1750.” Economic History Review 4 (Nov.): 595–622CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. 1997. Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James W. 1971. “Noncooperative Equilibrium for Supergames.” Review of Economic Studies 38 (8): 1–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Jeffrey (ed.). 1996. The Rational Choice Controversy: Economic Models of Politics Reconsidered. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1984. The Methodology of Positive Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and D. Kreps. 1988. “A Theory of Learning and Nash Equilibrium.” Mimeo, Stanford University
Fudenberg, Drew, and Levine, David K.. 1993. “Self-Confirming Equilibrium.” Econometrica 61 (3): 523–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Levine, David K.. 1998. The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and David K. Levine. 2003. “Steady State Learning and the Code of Hammurabi.” Working paper, University of California, Los Angeles
Fudenberg, Drew, Levine, David K., and Maskin, Eric. 1994. “The Folk Theorem with Imperfect Public Information.” Econometrica 62 (5): 997–1039CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and Maskin, E.. 1986. “The Folk Theorem for Repeated Games with Discounting and Incomplete Information.” Econometrica 54 (3): 533–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Tirole, Jean. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Furnivall, John S. 1956. Colonial Policy and Practice: A Comparative Study of Burma and Netherlands India. New York: New York University PressGoogle Scholar
Furubotn, Erik G., and Richter, Rudolf. 1997. Institutions and Economic Theory. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Gächter, Simon, and Falk, Armin. 2002. “Reputation and Reciprocity: Consequences for the Labour Relation.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104 (1): 1–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., and Zeira, J.. 1993. “Income-Distribution and Macroeconomics.” Review of Economic Studies 60 (1): 35–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Harold. 1967. Studies in Ethnomethodology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, John, Pearce, David, and Stacchetti, Ennio. 1989. “Psychological Games and Sequential Rationality.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (1): 60–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghatak, M., and Guinnane, T. W.. 1999. “The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability: Theory and Practice.” Journal of Development Economics 60 (1): 195–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghosh, Parikshit, and Ray, Debraj. 1996. “Cooperation in Community Interaction without Information Flows.” Review of Economic Studies 63 (3): 491–519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 1992. Game Theory for Applied Economists. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 1998. “Game Theory and Garbage Cans: An Introduction to the Economics of Internal Organization.” In Stern, R. and Halpern, J. (eds.), Debating Rationality: Nonrational Elements of Organizational Decision Making, chap. 2. Ithaca, NY: ILR PressGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 2001. “Trust in Social Structures: Hobbes and Coase Meet Repeated Games.” In Cook, K. (ed.), Trust in Society, chap. 11. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert, and Andrew Rutten. 1997. “Hierarchical Dilemmas: Social Order with Self-Interested Rulers.” Working paper, Cornell University
Giddens, Anthony. 1997. Sociology. London: Polity PressGoogle Scholar
Gil, Moshe. 1971. The Tustars, the Family and the Sect. Tel Aviv: Tel Aviv University PressGoogle Scholar
Gil, Moshe. 1983a. “The Jews in Sicily under the Muslim Rule in the Light of the Geniza Documents.” Unpublished manuscript, Tel Aviv University
Gil, Moshe. 1983b. Palestine during the First Muslim Period (634–1099) (in Hebrew and Arabic). Vols. 1–3. Tel Aviv: Ministry of Defense Press and Tel Aviv University PressGoogle Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak, and Schmeidler, David. 2001. Theory of Case-Based Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. 2000. Game Theory Evolving. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Giovanni di Guiberto. 1200–11. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Hall-Cole, M. W. and Reinert, R. G.. Documenti, XVII–XVIII. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1939–40Google Scholar
Giovanni Scriba. 1154–64. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Chiaudano, Mario and Moresco, Mattia. Vols. 1, 2. Turin: S. Lattes & C. Editori, 1935Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shliefer, Andrei. 2004. Do Institutions Cause Growth? Memo, Harvard UniversityCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., and Shleifer, Andrei. 2002. “Legal Origin.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1193–1230CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1957. “The Beginning of the Karim Merchants and the Character of Their Organization.” Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient 1: 175–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1964. “Commercial and Family Partnerships in the Countries of Medieval Islam.” Islamic Studies 3: 315–37Google Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1967. A Mediterranean Society: Economic Foundations. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1971. A Mediterranean Society: The Community. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1973. Letters of Medieval Jewish Traders. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1978. A Mediterranean Society: The Family. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira. 2002. “Institutions for Contract Enforcement and Risk-Sharing: From Debt to Equity in Late Medieval Venice.” Memo, Ente Einaudi, Bank of Italy
Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira. 2004. “The State as an Enforcer in Early Venetian Trade: A Historical Institutional Analysis.” Memo, University of Alicante, Spain
Goodin, Robert, and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.). 1996. A New Handbook of Political Science. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Goody, J. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gould, S. J., and Eldredge, N.. 1977. “Punctuated Equilibria: The Tempo and Mode of Evolution Reconsidered.” Paleobiology 3: 115–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grantham, George. 1992. “The Manse, the Manor and the Market: New Perspectives on the Medieval Agricultural Revolution.” Memo, McGill University
Grantham, George. 1993. “Economic Growth without Causes: A Reexamination of Medieval Economic Growth and Decay.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Economic History Association, Tucson, AZ
Granovetter, Mark S. 1985. “Economic Action, Social Structure, and Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481–510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark S. 2002. “A Theoretical Agenda for Economic Sociology.” In Guillen, Mauro, Collins, Randall, England, Paula, and Meyer, Marshall (eds.), The New Economic Sociology: Developments in an Emerging Field, 35–59. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Gras, N. S. B. 1939. Business and Capitalism: An Introduction to Business History. New York: F. S. CroftsGoogle Scholar
Green, Donald P., and Shapiro, Ian. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Green, Edward, and Porter, Robert. 1984. “Noncooperative Collusion under Imperfect Price Information.” Econometrica 52 (Jan.): 87–100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1985. “Sicilian Jews during the Muslim Period (827–1061)” (in Hebrew and Arabic). M. A. thesis, Tel Aviv University
Greif, Avner. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 857–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1992. “Institutions and Commitment in International Trade: Lessons from the Commercial Revolution.” American Economic Review 82 (2): 128–33Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition.” American Economic Review 83 (3): 525–48Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994a. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (5): 912–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994b. “Trading Institutions and the Commercial Revolution in Medieval Europe.” In Aganbegyan, Abel, Bogomolov, Oleg, and Kaser, Michael (eds.), Economics in a Changing World, 1: 115–25. Proceedings of the Tenth World Congress of the International Economic Association. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994c. “On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries.” Journal of Economic History 54 (4): 271–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1995. “Political Organizations, Social Structures, and Institutional Success: Reflections from Genoa and Venice during the Commercial Revolution.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 151 (4): 734–40Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1996a. “A Comment on the ‘Evolution of Economic Systems: The Case of Japan’ by Tetsuji Okazaki and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara.” In Hayami, Y. and Aoki, Masahiko (eds.), The Institutional Foundation of Economic Development in East Asia, 522–6. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1996b. “Microtheory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions through Economic History.” Working Paper No. 96–001, Stanford University, Department of Economics
Greif, Avner. 1997a. “Microtheory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions through Economic History.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, 2: 79–113. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997b. “Institutional Structure and Economic Development: Economic History and the New Institutionalism.” In Drobak, John N. and Nye, John (eds.), Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 57–94. Volume in honor of Douglass C. North. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997c. “Cultural Beliefs as a Common Resource in an Integrating World: An Example from the Theory and History of Collectivist and Individualist Societies.” In Dasgupta, P., Mäler, K.-G., and Vercelli, A. (eds.), The Economics of Transnational Commons, 238–96. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997d. “Contracting, Enforcement, and Efficiency: Economics beyond the Law.” In Bruno, Michael and Pleskovic, Boris (eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 239–66. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998a. “Historical and Comparative Institutional Analysis.” American Economic Review 88 (2): 80–4Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998b. “Historical Institutional Analysis: Game Theory and Non-market Self-Enforcing Institutions during the Late Medieval Period” (in French). Annales, no. 3 (May–June): 597–633CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998c. “Self-Enforcing Political Systems and Economic Growth: Late Medieval Genoa.” In Robert H. Bates, Avner Greif, Margaret Levi, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, and Barry R. Weingast, Analytic Narratives, 23–63. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2000. “The Fundamental Problem of Exchange: A Research Agenda in Historical Institutional Analysis.” Review of European Economic History 4 (3): 251–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2001. “Impersonal Exchange and the Origin of Markets: From the Community Responsibility System to Individual Legal Responsibility in Pre-modern Europe.” In Aoki, M. and Hayami, Y. (eds.), Communities and Markets in Economic Development, 3–41. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2002. “The Islamic Equilibrium: Legitimacy and Political, Social, and Economic Outcomes.” Working paper, Stanford University
Greif, Avner. 2004a. “State Building and Commercial Expansion: Genoa's Experience.” Memo, Stanford University
Greif, Avner. 2004b. “Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange.” In Menard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M. (eds.), The Handbook for New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic PublishersGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2004c. “Impersonal Exchange without Impartial Law: The Community Responsibility System.” Chicago Journal of International Law 5 (1): 109–38Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Eugene Kandel. 1995. “Contract Enforcement Institutions: Historical Perspective and Current Status in Russia.” In Lazear, Edward P. (ed.), Economic Transition in Eastern Europe and Russia: Realities of Reform, 291–321. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Laitin, David. 2004. “A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change.” American Political Science Review 98 (4): 1–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, Milgrom, Paul R., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1994. “Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Gild.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 745–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, Charles. 1890. Gild Merchant. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2002a. Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2002b. “Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 85–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2003. “Outsourcing in a Global Economy.” Review of Economic Studies 1: 300–16Google Scholar
Grossman, Herschel, and Kim, Minseong. 1995. “Swords or Plowshares? A Theory of the Security of Claims to Property.” Journal of Political Economy 103 (6): 1275–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D.. 1986. “The Cost and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4): 691–719CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guglielmo Cassinese. 1190–2. Carlolare (in Latin and Italian). In Hall, Margaret W., Krueger, Hilmar C., and Reynolds, Robert L. (eds.), Notai Liguri Del Sec. Ⅻ. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1938Google Scholar
Guinnane, T. W. “Cooperatives as Information Machines: German Rural Credit Cooperatives, 1883–1914.” Discussion Papers 97–20. University of Copenhagen, Department of Economics
Gurevich, Aaron. 1995. The Origins of European Individualism. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Gustafsson, Bo. 1987. “The Rise and Economic Behaviour of Medieval Crafts Guilds. An Economic-Theoretical Interpretation.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 35 (1): 1–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W. 1992. “An Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Cooperative Behavior by Reciprocal Incentives.” International Journal of Game Theory 24: 323–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., and M. Yaari. 1992. “Explaining Reciprocal Behavior in Simple Strategic Games: An Evolutionary Approach.” In Witt, U. (ed.), Explaining Forces and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary Economics, 23–34. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haber, Stephen. 1997. “Institutional Change and TFP Growth: Brazil and Mexico, 1860–1940.” Working Paper, Stanford University
Haber, Stephen, Razo, Armando, and Maurer, Noel. 2003. The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagel, John H., and Roth, Alvin (eds.). 1995. Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Taylor, Rosemary C. R.. 1996. “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms.” Political Studies 44 (4): 936–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Taylor, Rosemary C. R.. 1998. “The Potential of Historical Institutionalism: A Response to Hay and Wincott.” Political Studies 46 (4): 958–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E., and Jones, Charles I.. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker Than Others?Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (Feb.): 83–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Gary G. 1991. “The Organizational Foundations of Western and Chinese Commerce: A Historical and Comparative Analysis.” In Hamilton, Gary G. (ed.), Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia, 48–65. Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong, Centre of Asian StudiesGoogle Scholar
Hanawalt, B. 1974. “The Peasant Family and Crime in Fourteenth-Century England.” Journal of British Studies 13 (2): 1–18Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1989. “Why a Constitution.” In Grofman, Bernard and Wittman, Donal (eds.), The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism, 100–20. New York: Agathon PressGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1997. “Economic Theories of the State.” In Mueller, Dennis C. (ed.), Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook, 21–34. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 2001. “Norms and the Theory of the Firm.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 149 (6): 1701–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Bengt Holmstrom. 1987. “The Theory of Contracts.” In Bewley, Truman F. (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory, Fifth World Congress, 71–157. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Moore, J.. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 115–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hatcher, John, and Bailey, Mark. 2001. Modeling the Middle Ages: The History and Theory of England's Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.. 1937. “Economics and Knowledge.” Economica 4: 33–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1973. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 1. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1976. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 2. Chicago: University of ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1979. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 3. Chicago: University of ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Hearder, H., and Waley, D. P. (eds.). 1963. A Short History of Italy from Classical Times to the Present Day. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hechter, M. 1992. “The Insufficiency of Game Theory for the Resolution of Real World Collective Action Problems.” Rationality and Society 4 (1): 33–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heers, Jacques. 1977. Parties and Political Life in the Medieval West. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan. 2004. The Mystery of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, and Gintis, Hebert. 2004. Foundations of Human Sociality: Experimental and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, Gintis, Hebert, and McElreath, Richard. 2001. “In Search for Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies.” American Economic Review 74 (May): 73–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herb, Michael. 2003. “Taxation and Representation.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38 (3): 3–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlihy, David. 1958. “The Agrarian Revolution in Southern France and Italy, 801–1150.” Speculum: A Journal of Mediaeval Studies 33 (1): 23–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlihy, David. 1969. “Family Solidarity in Medieval Italian History.” In Herlihy, David, Lopez, R. S., Slessarev, V. (eds.), Economy Society, and Government in Medieval Italy: Essays in Memory of Robert L. Reynolds, 173–84. Kent, OH: Kent State University PressGoogle Scholar
Heyd, W. 1868. Le colonie commerciali degli Italiani in Oriente nel Medio Evo. 2 vols. Venice: G. AntonelliGoogle Scholar
Heyd, W. 1885. Histoire du commerce du Levant au Moyen-âge. 2 vols. Leipzig: Otto HarrassowitzGoogle Scholar
Heywood, William. 1921. A History of Pisa, Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John. 1969. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hickson, Charles R., and Thompson, Earl A.. 1991. “A New Theory of Guilds and European Economic Development.” Explorations in Economic History 28 (2): 127–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1985. “The Expanding Domain of Economics.” American Economic Review 75 (6): 53–70Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1998. “The Approach of Institutional Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 166–92Google Scholar
Hodgson, Marshall G. S. 1974. The Venture of Islam. Vols. 1, 2. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Shachat, Keith, and Smith, Vernon. 1994. “Preferences, Property Rights, and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 7 (3): 346–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, and Smith, Vernon. 1996a. “On Expectations and the Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games.” International Journal of Game Theory 125 (3): 289–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Smith, Vernon. 1996b. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.” American Economic Review 86 (3): 653–60Google Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T. 1990. “Taxes, Fiscal Crises, and Representative Institutions: The Case of Early Modern France.” Unpublished manuscript, Washington University, Center for the History of Freedom
Hoffman, Phillip T. 1991. “Land Rents and Agricultural Productivity – the Paris Basin, 1450–1789.” Journal of Economic History 51 (4): 771–805CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Phillip T. 1996. Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T., Postel-Vinay, Gilles, and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 2000. Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660–1870. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Höllander, Heinz. 1990. “A Social Exchange Approach to Voluntary Cooperation.” American Economic Review 80 (5): 1157–67Google Scholar
Homans, George C. 1950. The Human Group. New York: HarcourtGoogle Scholar
Homans, George C. 1961. Social Behavior. New York: Harcourt, Brace & WorldGoogle Scholar
Hsu, F. L. K. 1983. Rugged Individualism Reconsidered. Knoxville: University of Tennessee PressGoogle Scholar
Huck, S., and Oechssler, J.. 1999. “The Indirect Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Fair Allocations.” Games and Economic Behavior 28: 13–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1974. “Toward Historical Ethnography: Notarial Records and Family History in the Middle Ages.” Historical Methods Newsletter 7 (2): 61–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1977. “Kinsmen and Neighbors in Medieval Genoa.” In Mistiming, Harry A., Herlihy, David, and Udovitch, A. L. (eds.), The Medieval City, 95–111. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1978. “Urban Growth and Family Structure in Medieval Genoa.” In Abrams, Philip and Wrigley, E. A. (eds.), Towns in Societies, 105–30. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Previously published in Past and Present 66 (1975): 3–28Google Scholar
Hughes, Everett C. 1937. “Institutional Office and the Person.” American Journal of Sociology 43 (3): 404–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, John K. 1973. Society and Politics in Medieval Italy: The Evolution of Civil Life, 1000–1350. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingram, Paul. 1996. “Organizational Form as a Solution to the Problem of Credible Commitment: The Evolution of Naming Strategies among US Hotel Chains, 1896–1980.” Strategic Management Journal 17 (Summer): 85–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacoby, David. 1997. Trade, Commodities, and Shipping in the Medieval Mediterranean. Aldershot: VariorumGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Simon, McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 2002. “Courts and Relational Contracts.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 18 (Spring): 221–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, W. J. 1976. The Foundations of English Bankruptcy: Statutes and Commissions in the Early Modern Period. Philadelphia: Transactions of the American Philosophical SocietyGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. 1984. “Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Mine-Mouth Coal Plants.” Paper presented at the Economic and Legal Organization Workshop, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Kalai, E., and Lehrer, E.. 1993a. “Rational Learning Leads to Nash Equilibrium.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1019–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Lehrer, E.. 1993b. “Subjective Equilibrium in Repeated Games.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1231–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Lehrer, E.. 1995. “Subjective Games and Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 8: 123–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kali, R. 1999. “Endogenous Business Networks.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15 (3): 615–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kambayashi, Ryo. 2002. “The Registration System and the Grade Wage System, Coordination and Relative Performance Evaluation.” Memo, Tokyo University
Kandori, Michihiro. 1992. “Social Norms and Community Enforcement.” Review of Economic Studies 59 (1): 63–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 1997. “Evolutionary Game Theory in Economics.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory 1: 243–77. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 2002. “Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring.” Journal of Economic Theory 102 (1): 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 2003. “The Erosions and Sustainability of Norms and Morals.” Japanese Economic Review 54 (1): 29–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro, George Mailath, andRob, R.. 1993. “Learning, Mutation, and Long Run Equilibria in Games,” Econometrica 61 (1): 29–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaneko, Mamoru, and Matsui, Akihiko. 1999. “Inductive Game Theory: Discrimination and Prejudices.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 1 (1): 1–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, Shawn E. 1998. Politics and Property Rights: The Closing of the Open Range in the Postbellum South. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kedar, Benjamin Z. 1976. Merchants in Crisis: Genoese and Venetian Men of Affairs and the Fourteenth-Century Depression. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Kelly, J. M. 1992. A Short History of Western Legal Theory. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, Hugh. 1986. The Prophet and the Age of the Caliphates. New York: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, and Leffler, Keith B.. 1981. “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (4): 615–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Daniel (ed.). 1996. Reputation: Studies in the Voluntary Enforcement of Good Behavior. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kockesen, L., Ok, E. A., and Sethi, R.. 2000a. “The Strategic Advantage of Negatively Interdependence Preferences.” Journal of Economic Theory 92: 274–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kockesen, L, Ok, E. A., and Sethi, R.. 2000b. “Evolution of Interdependent Preferences in Aggregative Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 31: 303–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korotayev, A. V. 2003. “Unilineal Descent Organization and Deep Christianization: A Cross-Cultural Comparison.” Cross-Cultural Research 37 (1): 133–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E. 1996. “Reciprocal Exchange: A Self-Sustaining System.” American Economic Review 86 (4): 830–51Google Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E., and Minehart, D. F.. 2001. “A Theory of Buyer-Seller Networks.” American Economic Review 91 (3): 485–508CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasner, S. D. 1984. “Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics.” Comparative Politics 16 (2): 223–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M. 1990a. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David, M. 1990b. “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory.” In Alt, James and Shepsle, Kenneth (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, 90–143. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M., Milgrom, Paul, Roberts, John, and Wilson, Robert. 1982. “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners' Dilemma.” Journal of Economic Theory 27: 245–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kritkos, Alexander, and Friedel Bolle. 1999. “Approaching Fair Behavior: Self-Centered Inequality Aversion versus Reciprocity and Altruism.” Discussion Paper 143. Frankfurt/Oder
Kroeber, A. L., and Kluckhohn, Clyde. 1952. Culture: A Critical Review of Concepts and Definitions. Cambridge, MA: Peabody MuseumGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1932. “The Commercial Relations between Genoa and Northwest Africa in the Twelfth Century.” Ph.D. diss., University of Wisconsin, Madison
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1933. “Genoese Trade with Northwest Africa in the Twelfth Century.” Speculum 6 (July): 377–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1949. “Post-War Collapse and Rehabilitation in Genoa (1149–1162).” In Studi in onore di Gino Luzzatto, 4: 117–28. Milan: Istituto di Storia Economica dell'Universita di NapoliGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1957. “Genoese Merchants, Their Partnerships and Investments, 1155 to 1164.” In Cisalpina, Editoriale (eds.), Studi in onore di Armando Sapori, 257–72. Milan: Institudo Editoriale CisalpinoGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1962. “Genoese Merchants, Their Associations and Investments, 1155 to 1230.” In Graffre, D. A. (ed.), Studi in onore di Amintore Fanfani, 1: 415–26. Milan: Multa PaucisGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1987. “The Genoese Exportation of Northern Cloths to Mediterranean Ports, Twelfth Century.” Revue Belge de Philologie et d'Histoire 65 (4): 722–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Arthur K. 1912. The Law of Corporations. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1993. “The Unthinkable and the Unthought.” Rationality and Society 5 (4): 473–505CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1995. Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1998. “Moral Overload and Its Alleviation.” In Ben-Ner, Avner and Putterman, Louis (eds.), Economics, Values, and Organization, 231–66. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2004. “Why the Middle East Is Economically Underdeveloped: Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation.” Journal of Economic Perspective 18 (2): 71–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2005. “Why the Islamic Middle East Did Not Generate an Indigenous Corporate Law.” Memo, University of Southern California
Kydland, Finn E., and Prescott, Edward C.. 1977. “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy 85 (3): 473–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lal, Deepak. 1998. Unintended Consequences: The Impact of Endowments, Culture, and Politics on Long-Run Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Landa, Janet T. 1978. “The Economics of the Ethnically Homogeneous Chinese Middleman Group: A Property Rights–Public Choice Approach.” Ph.D. diss., Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
Landa, Janet T. 1988. “A Theory of the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: Beyond Markets and Hierarchies.” Working paper, Hoover Institution, Stanford University
Lane, Frederic C. 1944. “Family Partnerships and Joint Ventures in the Venetian Republic.” Journal of Economic History 4: 178–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, Frederic C. 1973. Venice: A Maritime Republic. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Lanfranco Scriba. 1202–26. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). In Krueger, H. C. and Reynolds, R. L. (eds.), Notai Liguri Del Sec. Ⅻ e Del ⅫI. Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia Patria, 1952–4Google Scholar
Langum, David J. 1987. Law and Community on the Mexican California Frontier: Anglo-American Expatriates and the Clash of Legal Traditions, 1821–1846. Norman: University of Oklahoma PressGoogle Scholar
Lapidus, Ira M. 1984. Muslim Cities in the Later Middle Ages. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lapidus, Ira M. 1989. A History of Islamic Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lau, Lawrence J., Qian, Yingyi, and Roland, Gérard. 2000. “Reform without Losers: An Interpretation of China's Dual-Track Approach to Transition.” Journal of Political Economy 108 (1): 120–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. On Rules and Revenues. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1997. Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 2004. “An Analytic Narrative Approach to Puzzles and Problems.” In Shapiro, Ian, Smith, Rogers, and Masoud, Tarek (eds.), Problems and Methods in the Study of Politics, 201–26. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, Jonathan. 2003. “Relational Incentive Contracts.” American Economic Review 93 (3): 835–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Daryl J. 2003. “Collective Sanctions.” Stanford Law Review 56 (253): 345–428Google Scholar
Lewis, Archibald R. 1951. Naval Power and Trade in the Mediterranean, A. D. 500–1100. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1982. The Muslim Discovery of Europe. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1990. Race and Slavery in the Middle East. Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1991. The Political Language of Islam. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Li, Shuhe. 1999. “The Benefits and Costs of Relation-Based Governance: An Explanation of the East Asian Miracle and Crisis.” Memo, City University of Hong Kong
Lieber, A. E. 1968. “Eastern Business Practices and Medieval Europe Commerce.” Economic History Review 21: 230–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar. 1997. “Incentives and Social Norms in Household Behavior.” American Economic Review 87 (2): 370–7Google Scholar
Lisciandrelli, Pasquale. 1960. “Trattati e negoziazioni politiche della Repubblica di Genova (958–1797).” Atti della Societa Ligure de Storia Patria, n.s., 1 (old series, 75). Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Lloyd, T. H. 1991. England and the German Hansa, 1157–1611. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewsenstein, George, Bazerman, Max, and Thomson, Leigh. 1989. “Social Utility and Decision Making in Interpersonal Context.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 426–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1937. “Aux origines du capitalisme gènois.” Annales d'Histoire Economique et Sociale 47: 429–54Google Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1938. Storia delle colonie genovesi nel Mediterraneo. Bologna: Nicola ZanichelliGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1943. “European Merchants in the Medieval Indies: The Evidence of Commercial Documents.” Journal of Economic History 3 (1): 164–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1952. “The Trade of Medieval Europe in the South.” In Postan, M. M. and Miller, E. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 2: 257–354. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1954. “Concerning Surnames and Places of Origin.” Medievalia et Humanistica 8: 6–16Google Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1967. The Birth of Europe. Trans. J. M. Dent & Sons. London: M. EvansGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1976. The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino, and Raymond, I. W.. 1955. Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Luzzatto, Gino. 1961. An Economic History of Italy: From the Fall of the Roman Empire to the Beginning of the Sixteenth Century. Trans. Philip Jones. London: Routledge & K. PaulGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, Stewart, 1963. “Noncontractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study.” American Sociological Review 28: 55–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macfarlane, Alan. 1978. The Origins of English Individualism. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1990 [1532]. Florentine Histories (also known as History of Florence). Introd. Harvey C. Mansfield Jr. Trans. Laura F. Banfield and Harvey C. Mansfield Jr. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
MacLeod, W. Bentley, and Malcomson, James M.. 1989. “Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment.” Econometrica 57 (2): 447–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macy, Michael W. 1997. “Identity, Interest and Emergent Rationality – an Evolutionary Synthesis.” Rationality and Society 9 (4): 427–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maggi, Giovanni. 1999. “The Role of Multilateral Institutions in International Trade Cooperation.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 190–214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2000. “Path Dependence in Historical Sociology.” Theory and Society 29 (4): 507–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maimonides, Moshe. 1951. Mishne Torah. Vol. 12. Trans. I. Klein. New Haven: Yale Judaica SeriesGoogle Scholar
Maimonides, Moshe. 1957. Responda (in Judeo-Arabic and Hebrew). Ed. Blau, J.. JerusalemGoogle Scholar
Maitland, Frederick William (ed.). 1889. Select Pleas in Manorial and Other Seigniorial Courts, Reigns of Henry III and Edward I. Vol. 2. London: Seldon Society PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Maitland, Frederick William, and Bateson, Mary. 1901. The Charters of the Borough of Cambridge. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mann, Jacob. 1919. “Responsa of the Babylonian Geonim as a Source of Jewish History.” Jewish Quarterly Review 20: 139–72, 309–65Google Scholar
Mann, Jacob. 1970. The Jews in Egypt and in Palestine under the Fatimid Caliphs. Vol. 2. New York: Katav Publishing HouseGoogle Scholar
Mantzavinos, Chris. 2001. Individual, Institutions and Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, G. James, and Olsen, Johan P.. 1989. Rediscovering Institution: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Margolis, Howard. 1987. Pattern, Thinking, and Cognition: A Theory of Judgement. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Margolis, Howard. 1994. Paradigms and Barriers: How Habits of Mind Govern Scientific Beliefs. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Marimon, Ramon. 1997. “Learning from Learning in Economics.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, 1: 278–315. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Marin, Dalia, and Schnitzer, Monika. 1995. “Tying Trade Flows: A Theory of Countertrade with Evidence.” American Economic Review 85 (5): 1047–64Google Scholar
Martines, Lauro (ed.). 1972. Violence and Civil Disorder in Italian Cities, 1200–1500. UCLA Center for Medieval and Renaissance Studies. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Maurer, Noel, and Sharma, T.. 2002. “Enforcing Property Rights through Reputation: Mexico's Early Industrialization, 1878–1913.” Journal of Economic History 61 (4): 950–73Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Palfrey, Thomas. 1992. “An Experimental Study of the Centipede Game.” Econometrica 60 (July): 803–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John. 2002. Reinventing the Bazar: A Natural History of Markets. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 1999. “Interfirm Relationships and Informal Credit in Vietnam.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4): 1285–1320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 2000. “Private Order under Dysfunctional Public Order.” Michigan Law Review 98: 2421–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mead, George Herbert. 1967 [1934]. Mind, Self, and Society: From the Standpoint of a Social Behaviorist. Ed. Morris, Charles W.. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1871 [1976]. Principles of Economics. New York: New York University PressGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., and B. Rowen. 1991. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 41–62. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Michael, Murad. 1965. “The Archives of Naharay ben Nissim, Businessman and Public Figure in Eleventh Century Egypt” (in Hebrew and Arabic). Ph.D. diss., Hebrew University, Jerusalem
Milgrom, Paul, North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1990. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Medieval Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics 1 (March), 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, Qian, Yingyi, and Roberts, John. 1991. “Complementarities, Momentum, and the Evolution of Modern Manufacturing.” American Economic Review 81 (2): 84–8Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John. 1982. “Predation, Reputation, and Entry Deterrence.” Journal of Economic Theory 27 (2): 280–312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1990. “Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities.” Econometrica 58 (6): 1255–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1992. Economics, Organization and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1995. “Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, Structure, and Organizational Change in Manufacturing.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 19 (2–3): 179–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Shannon, Chris. 1994. “Monotone Comparative Statics.” Econometrica 62 (1): 157–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 1993. Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, C. Wesley. 1925. “Quantitative Analysis in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 15 (1): 1–12Google Scholar
Mitterauer, Michael, and Sieder, Reinhard. 1982. The European Family. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gift of Athena. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Moore, Ellen Wedemeyer. 1985. The Fairs of Medieval England. Toronto: Pontifical Institute of Medieval StudiesGoogle Scholar
Moriguchi, Chiaki. 1998. “Evolution of Employment Systems in the US and Japan: 1900–60. A Comparative Historical Analysis.” Unpublished manuscript, Stanford University
Morris, Colin. 1972. The Discovery of the Individual, 1050–1200. London: S. P. C. K. for the Church Historical SocietyGoogle Scholar
Moser, Peter. 2000. The Political Economy of Democratic Institutions. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Munck, Gerardo L. 2001. “Game Theory and Comparative Politics.” World Politics 53 (Jan.): 173–204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munz, Peter. 1969. Frederick Barbarossa. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Muthoo, Abhinay, and Kenneth A. Shepsle. 2003. “Agenda-Setting Power in Organizations with Overlapping Generations of Players.” Typescript, Harvard University
Nee, Victor, and Paul Ingram. 1998. “Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange and Social Structure.” In Brinton, M. and Nee, V. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, 19–45. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Philip. 1974. “Advertising as Information.” Journal of Political Economy 82 (4): 729–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. 1994. “The Co-evolution of Technology, Industrial Structure, and Supporting Institutions.” Industrial and Corporate Change 3: 47–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. 1995. “Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change.” Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1): 48–90Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R., and Winter, Sidney G.. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1991. “Institutions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1993. “Institutions and Credible Commitment.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 (1): 11–23Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Institutional Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert P.. 1973. The Rise of the Western World. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49: 803–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norwich, John Julius. 1989. History of Venice. New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
Obertus Scriba de Mercato. 1186, 1190. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Chiaudano, R. Mario and Rocca, Morozzo Della. Documenti, Ⅺ and XVI. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1940Google Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji. 2005. “The Role of the Merchant Coalition in Pre-modern Japanese Economic Development: An Historical Institutional Analysis.” Explorations in Economic History 42 (2): 184–201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara. 1998. “Evolution of Economic Systems: The Case of Japan.” In Hayami, Y. and Aoki, Masahiko (eds.), The Institutional Foundation of Economic Development in East Asia, 482–521. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, and Andrew Postlewaite. 1990. “Social Norms and Random Matching Games.” CARESS Working Paper #90–18, University of Pennsylvania
Olivieri, Agostino. 1861. Serie dei consoli del comune di Genova. Genoa: Forni Editore Bologna. Originally published in Atti della Ligure di Storia Patria 1 (1858): 155–479Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. “A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action.” American Political Science Review 92 (1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otto of Freising and His Continuator. 1152–8. The Deeds of Frederick Barbarossa. Translated and annotated by Charles Christopher Mierow with collaboration of Richard Emery. New York: Columbia University Press, 1953
Pagano, Ugo, and Maria Alessandra Rossi. 2002. “Incomplete Contracts, Intellectual Property and Institutional Complementarities.” Memo, University of Siena
Pamuk, Şevket. 2000. A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Parker, Geoffrey. 1990. The Military Revolution (1500–1800). Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. London: Routledge and Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1990. “Prologomena to a Theory of Social Institutions.” American Sociological Review 55 (3): 319–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patourel, J. H.. 1937. Medieval Administration of the Channel Islands, 1199–1399. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Pearce, David G. 1984. “Rationalizable Strategic Behavior and the Problem of Perfection.” Econometrica 52 (4): 1029–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearce, David G. 1987. “Renegotiation-Proof Equilibria: Collective Rationality and Intertemporal Cooperation.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Yale University
Pearce, David G. 1995. “Repeated Games: Cooperation and Rationality.” In Laffont, Jean-Jacques (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory, 1: 132–74. Sixth World Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Persson, Karl Gunnar. 1988. Pre-industrial Economic Growth, Social Organization, and Technological Progress in Europe. New York: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Pertile, Antonio. 1966. Storia del diritto italiano dalla caduta dell'Impero Romano alla codificazione. 2nd ed. 2 vols. Bologna: Arnaldo Forni EditoreGoogle Scholar
Peters, Guy. 1996. “Political Institutions, Old and New.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 205–20. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review 94 (2): 251–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul, and Theda Skocpol. 2002. “Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science.” In Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V. (eds.), Political Science: State of the Discipline, 693–721. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1939. Mohammed and Charlemagne. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1956. A History of Europe. New York: University BooksGoogle Scholar
Planitz, H. 1919. “Studien zur Geschichte des Deutschen Arrestprozesses, II. Kapital, der Fremdenarrest.” Zeitschrift de Savigny-Stifung fuer Rechtsgeschichte (Germanistische Abteilung) 40: 87–198Google Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 1994. “Behind the Market Stage Where Real Societies Exist. Part II: The Role of Moral Norms.” Journal of Development Studies 30 (3): 753–817CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2000. Institutions, Social Norms and Economic Development. Amsterdam: Harwood Academic PublishersGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J. P., and Gaspart, F.. 2003. “The Risk of Resource Misappropriation in Community-Driven Development.” World Development 31 (10): 1687–1703CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe, and Y. Hayami. 1998. “Resource Endowments and Agricultural Development: Africa versus Asia.” In Aoki, M., and Hayami, Y. (eds.), The Institutional Foundations of East Asian Economic Development, 357–410. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Plucknett, Theodore Frank Thomas. 1949. Legislation of Edward I. Oxford: ClarendonGoogle Scholar
Pollock, Frederick, and Maitland, Frederic William. 1968. The History of the English Law before the Time of Edward I. 2nd ed. 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence: China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. A. 1997. “Social Norms and the Law: An Economic Approach.” Papers and Proceedings from the 104th Meeting of the American Economic Association. American Economic Review 87 (2): 333–8Google Scholar
Postan, Michael M. 1973. Medieval Trade and Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pounds, Norman John Greville. 1994. An Economic History of Medieval Europe. 2nd ed. New York: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1993. “Guns, Butter, and Anarchy.” American Political Science Review 87 (1): 115–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Powell, W., and DiMaggio, P. (eds.). 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Poznanski, S. 1904. “Ephraim ben Schemria de Fustat” (in French and Hebrew). Revue des Etudes Juives 48: 146–75Google Scholar
Pryor, F. L. 1977. The Origins of the Economy: A Comparative Study of Distribution and Peasant Economies. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Pryor, John. 1988. Geography, Technology, and War. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1993. Making Democracy Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone. New York: Simon and SchusterCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1993. “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics.” American Economic Review 83 (5): 1281–1302Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1994. “Cognitive Dissonance and Social Change.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 23 (2): 177–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1998. “Psychology and Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 11–46Google Scholar
Rahman, Fazlur. 2002. Islam. 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, Amnon. 1997. “Order of Play in Strategically Equivalent Games in Extensive Form.” International Journal of Game Theory 26 (1): 113–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashdal, Hastings. 1936. The Universities of Europe in the Middle Ages. Vol. 1. Ed. Powicke, F. M. and Emden, A. B.. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rauch, J. E. 2001. “Business and Social Networks in International Trade.” Journal of Economic Literature 39 (Dec.): 1177–1203CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Razi, Zevi. 1993. “The Myth of the Immutable English Family.” Past & Present 140 (Aug.): 3–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey, E. 1895. “Les seigneurs de giblet.” Revue de l'Orient Latin 3:398–422. Paris: Presses Universitaires de FranceGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Charles H., and Norman, Ralph V., eds. 1988. Community in America. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1929. “The Market for Northern Textiles in Genoa 1179–1200.” Revue Belge Philologie et d'Historie 8: 831–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1930. “Merchants of Arras and the Overland Trade with Genoa in the Twelfth Century.” Revue Belge Philologie et d'Histoirie 9: 495–533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1931. “Genoese Trade in the Late Twelfth Century, Particularly in Cloth from the Fair of Champagne.” Journal of Economic and Business History 3: 362–81Google Scholar
Richardson, Gary. 2002. “Craft Guilds and Christianity in Late-Medieval England: A Rational-Choice Analysis.” Memo, University of California, Irvine
Riker, William. 1964. Federalism: Origins, Operations, and Significance. Boston: Little BrownGoogle Scholar
Rippin, Andrew. 1994. Muslims: Their Religious Beliefs and Practices. Vol. 1: The Formative Period. Reprint, London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 2003. “Growth Strategies.” Memo, Harvard University. [Forthcoming in The Handbook of Economic Growth.]
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2003. “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development.” Memo, Harvard University
Roland, Gérard. 2000. Transitions and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Romer, Paul. 1996. “Preferences, Promises, and the Politics of Entitlement.” In Fuchs, Victor R. (ed.), The Individual and Social Responsibility, 195–220. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1989. “Tying the King's Hands: Credible Commitments and Royal Fiscal Policy during the Old Regime.” Rationality and Society 1 (Oct.): 240–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1994. The Fountain of Privilege: Political Foundations of Markets in Old Regime France and Englands. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Rorig, Fritz. 1967. The Medieval Town. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1982. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan, and Birdzell, L. E. Jr. 1986. How the West Grew Rich. New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1992. The Fruits of Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, and Nisbett, Richard E.. 1991. The Person and the Situation. Boston: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Rossetti, G., Pratesi, M. C., Garzella, G., Guzzardi, M. B., Guglie, G., and Sturmann, C.. 1979. Pisa nei secoli Ⅺ e Ⅻ: Formazione e caratteri di una classe di governo. Pisa: Pacini EditoreGoogle Scholar
Roth, Alvin E., Prasnikar, Vesna, Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, and Zamir, Shmuel. 1991. “Bargaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An Experimental Study.” American Economic Review 81 (5): 1068–95Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E., and Erev, I.. 1995. “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in Intermediate Term.” Games and Economic Behavior, special issue: Nobel Symposium, 8: 164–212CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, Bo. 1996. “Political Institutions: An Overview.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 133–66. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1991. “Comments on the Interpretation of Game Theory.” Econometrica 59 (4): 909–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1998. Modeling Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Sachs, Jefrey D. 2001. “Tropical Underdevelopment.” NBER Working Paper No. 8119
Salzman, L. F. 1928. “A Riot at Boston Fair.” History Teachers' Miscellany 6: 2–3Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1993. “Altruism as a Problem Involving Group versus Individual Selection in Economics and Biology.” American Economic Review 83 (2): 143–8Google Scholar
Santini, Pietro. 1886. “Appunti sulla vendetta privata e sulle rappresaglie.” Archivo Strico Italiano 18: 162–76Google Scholar
Saunders, J. J. 1965. A History of Medieval Islam. New York: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley & SonsGoogle Scholar
Schacht, Joseph. 1982 [1964]. An Introduction to Islamic Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, F. W. 1997. Games Real Actors Play. Boulder, CO: WestviewGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G., Plumper, T., and Baumann, S., 2000. “Bringing Putnam to the European Regions – on the Relevance of Social Capital for Economic Growth.” European Urban and Regional Studies 7 (4): 307–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, Andrew. 1981. The Economic Theory of Social Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumann, Reinhold. 1992. Italy in the Last Fifteen Hundred Years. 2nd ed. Lanham, MD: University Press of AmericaGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 1998. Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard, Meyer, John W., et al. 1994. Institutional Environments and Organizations. London: Sage PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Searle, John R. 1995. The Construction of Social Reality. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ilya. 1999. “Complexity and Renegotiation: A Foundation for Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 57–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ronald. 2001. Islam's Black Slaves. New York: Farrar, Straus and GirouxGoogle Scholar
Segal, Uzi, and Joel Sobel. 2000. “Tit for Tat: Foundations of Preferences for Reciprocity in Strategic Settings.” Memo, University of California, San Diego
Select Cases Concerning the Law Merchant, A. D. 1270–1638. Vol. 1: Local Courts. 1908. Ed. Gross, Charles. Selden Society Publications, 23. London: B. QuaritchGoogle Scholar
Select Cases Concerning the Law Merchant, A. D. 1239–1633. Vol. 2: Central Courts. 1930. Ed. Hall, H.. Selden Society Publications, 46. London: B. QuaritchGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. 1995. “Moral Codes and Economic Success.” In Brittan, Samuel and Hamlin, Alan P. (eds.), Market Capitalism and Moral Values. Aldershot: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Sened, Itai. 1997. The Political Institution of Private Property. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Sewell, William H. 1992. “A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation.” American Journal of Sociology 98 (1): 1–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Carl. 1983. “Premiums for High Quality Products as Return to Reputation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (4): 659–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, C., and Stiglitz, J. E.. 1984. “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device.” American Economic Review 74 (3): 433–44Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23: 27–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1992. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Weisberg, H. F. (ed.), Political Science: The Science of Politics, 51–82. New York: Agathon PressGoogle Scholar
Shirley, Mary M. 2004. “Institutions and Development.” In Menard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M. (eds.), Handbook on New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer PressGoogle Scholar
Shiue, Carol H., and Wolfgang Keller. 2003. “Markets in China and Europe on the Eve of the Industrial Revolution.” Memo, University of Texas
Sieveking, Heinrich. 1898–9. Genueser Finanzwesen mit Besonderer Berücksichtigung de Casa di S. Giorgio. 2 vols. Leipzig: Freiburg
Simon, Herbert A. 1955. “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1976. Administrative Behavior. 3rd ed. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1987 [1957]. Model of Man, Social and Rational. New York: John WileyGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 1992. “Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property Rights.” American Economic Review 84 (4): 720–39Google Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 1996. “Contest Success Functions.” Economic Theory 7: 283–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smelser, Neil, and Richard Swedberg. 1994. “The Sociological Perspective on the Economy.” In Smelser, N. and Swedberg, R. (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 3–26. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Sobel, Joel. 2002. “Can We Trust Social Capital?Journal of Economic Literature 40 (March): 139–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sonn, Tamara. 1990. Between Qur'an and Crown. Boulder, CO: Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Staiger, Robert. 1995. “International Rules and Institutions for Trade Policy.” In Grossman, Gene M. and Rogoff, Kenneth (eds.), The Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3, chap. 29. North Holland: Elsevier Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Stark, R. 1996. The Rise of Christianity: A Sociologist Reconsiders History. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Stein, Peter. 1999. Roman Law in European History. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, Hamish. 1992. “Rationality and the Market for Human Blood.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1 (2): 125–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. 1994. Whither Socialism? Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Stillman, Norman Arthur. 1970. “East-West Relations in the Islamic Mediterranean in the Early Eleventh Century.” Ph.D. diss., University of Pennsylvania
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1968. Constructing Social Theories. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Stubbs, W. (ed.). 1913. Selected Charters and Other Illustrations of English Institutional History from the Earliest Times to the Reign of Edward the First. 9th ed. Oxford: ClarendonGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1986. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1989. “Spontaneous Order.” Journal of Economic Perspective 3 (4): 85–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutton, John. 1991. Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising, and the Evolution of Concentration. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action.” American Sociological Review 51 (Apr.): 273–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tabacco, Giovanni. 1989. The Struggle for Power in Medieval Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steve. 1999. “What's in a Name? Reputation as a Tradeable Asset.” Economic Review 89 (3): 548–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steve. 2002. “The Market for Reputations as an Incentive Mechanism.” Journal of Political Economy 110 (4): 854–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telser, L. G. 1980. “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements.” Journal of Business 53: 27–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 2 (June): 369–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, H. 1977. “Beitraege zur Geschichte der Champagne-Messen im 14. Jahrhundert.” Vierteljahrschrift fuer Sozial-und Wietschaftsgeschichte 64 (4): 433–67Google Scholar
Thrupp, Sylvia L. 1965. “The Gilds.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3: 230–79. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992. Cambridge, MA: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 1996. “A Theory of Collective Reputation (with Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Review of Economic Studies 63 (1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tooby, John, and Leda Cosmides. 1992. “The Psychological Foundations of Culture.” In Barkow, Jerome H., Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John (eds.), The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, 19–136. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Topiks, D. 1998. Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Townsend, Robert M. 1979. “Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification.” Journal of Economic Theory 21 (2): 265–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trackman, Leon E. 1983. The Law Merchant: The Evolution of Commercial Law. Littleton, CO: Fred B. RothmanGoogle Scholar
Triandis, Harry C. 1990. “Cross-Cultural Studies of Individualism and Collectivism.” In Berman, J. (ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation, 1989, 41–133. Lincoln: University of Nebraska PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. 1981. “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” Science 211: 453–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Udovitch, Abraham L. 1962. “At the Origins of Western Commenda: Islam, Israel, Byzantium.” Speculum 37: 198–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Udovitch, Abraham L. 1970. Partnership and Profit in Medieval Islam. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna. 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Damme, Eric. 1983. Refinements of the Nash Equilibrium Concept. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damme, Eric. 1987. Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibria. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van der Vee, Herman. 1977. “Monetary, Credit, and Banking Systems.” In Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 5: 290–391. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R. 1990. “Monitoring Agents with Other Agents.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146 (1): 153–74Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Vecchio, A. del, and Casanova, E.. 1894. Le rappresaglie nei comuni medievali e specialmente in Firenze. Bologna: R. ForniGoogle Scholar
Verlinden, C. 1979. “Markets and Fairs.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3: 119–53. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Vitale, V. 1951. Il comune del podestà a Genova. Milan: RicciardiGoogle Scholar
Vitale, V. 1955. Breviario della storia di Genova. 2 vols. Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Volckart, Oliver. 2001. “The Economics of Feuding in Late Medieval Germany.” Working paper, Institut fur Wirtschaftsgeschichte, Berlin
Wach, A. 1868. Der Arrestprozess in seiner geschichtlichen Entwicklung. 1. Teil: De Italienische Arrestprozess. Leipzig: HaesselGoogle Scholar
Waley, Daniel. 1988. The Italian City-Republics. 3rd ed. London: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Watson, Joel. 1999. “Starting Small and Renegotiation.” Journal of Economic Theory 85 (1): 52–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watson, Joel. 2001. Strategy: An Introduction to Game Theory. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Watt, Montgomery W. 1961. Muhammad: Prophet and Statesman. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Watt, Montgomery W. 1987. The Influence of Islam on Medieval Europe. Edinburgh: At the University PressGoogle Scholar
Watts, R. W., and Zimmermann, J. L.. 1983. “Agency Problems, Auditing and the Theory of the Firm: Some Evidence.” Journal of Law and Economics 26 (Oct.): 613–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. Reprint, New York: Free Press, 1964Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1949. The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Glencoe, IL: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. 1958 [1904–5]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Charles Scribner's SonsGoogle Scholar
Weibull, Jörgen. 1995. Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Weiner, A. 1932. “The Hansa.” In Tanner, J. R., Previté-Orton, C. W., and Brooke, Z. N. (eds.), The Cambridge Medieval History, 7: 216–69. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1993. “Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secured Markets.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 (1): 286–311Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. “Institutions and Political Commitment: A New Political Economy of the American Civil War Era.” Memo, Stanford University
Weingast, Barry R. 1996. “Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 167–90. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law.” American Political Science Review 91 (2): 245–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, B., and Marshall, W.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (1): 132–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Lynn. 1964. The Medieval Technology and Social Change. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Wiessner, Polly. 2002. “Hunting, Healing, and Hxaro Exchange. A Long-Term Perspective on!Kung (Ju/'hoansi) Large-Game Hunting.” Evolution and Human Behavior 23: 407–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Dean V. 2002. “Transparency and Contract Selection: Evidence from the Financing of Trade in Venetian Crete, 1303–1351.” Memo, U.S. Department of Justice
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analyses and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1993. “Transaction Cost Economics and Organization Theory.” Industrial and Corporate Change 2 (2): 107–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1998. “Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works; Where It Is Headed.” De Economist 146 (1): 23–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2000. “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead.” Journal of Economic Literature 38 (Sept.): 595–613CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Edward O. 1975. Sociobiology. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich. 1986. “Evolution and Stability of Cooperation without Enforceable Contracts.” Kyklos 39, fasc. 2: 245–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woolcock, Michael. 1998. “Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework.” Theory and Society 27 (2): 151–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Mark. 2002. “Reputations and Sovereign Debt.” Working paper, Stanford University
Wrong, Dennis H. 1961. “The Oversocialized Conception of Man in Modern Sociology.” American Sociological Review 26 (2): 183–93. Reprinted as chapter 2 in Dennis H. Wrong, The Oversocialized Conception of Man (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 1999)
Wrong, Dennis H. 1999. The Oversocialized Conception of Man. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Yang Li, Mu. 2002. “Essays on Public Finance and Economic Development in a Historical Institutional Perspective.” Ph.D. diss., Stanford University
Young, H. Peyton. 1993. “The Evolution of Conventions.” Econometrica 61 (1): 57–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Peyton. 1998. Individual Strategy and Social Structure. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Peyton, and Burke, Mary A.. 2001. “Competition and Custom in Economic Contracts: A Case Study of Illinois Agriculture.” American Economic Review 91 (3): 559–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, Paul J., and Knack, Stephen. 2001. “Trust and Growth.” Economic Journal 111 (470): 295–321CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Jiajie. 1997. “Nature of External Representations in Problem Solving.” Cognitive Science 21 (2): 179–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zucker, L. G. 1983. “Organizations as Institutions.” In Bacharach, S. B. (ed.), Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 1–42. Greenwich, CT: JAIGoogle Scholar
Zucker, L. G. 1991. “The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 83–107. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Abercrombie, Nicholas, Hill, Stephen, and Turner, Bryan S.. 1994. The Dictionary of Sociology. 3rd ed. London: Penguin GroupGoogle Scholar
Abou El Fadl, Khaled. 2001. Rebellion and Violence in Islamic Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abramovitz, M. 1986. “Catching Up, Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind.” Journal of Economic History 46 (2): 385–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip. 1988. “On the Theory of Infinitely Repeated Games with Discounting.” Econometrica 56: 383–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Milgrom, Paul R., and Pearce, David G.. 1991. “Information and Timing in Repeated Partnerships.” Econometrica 59 (6): 1713–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Pearce, David G., and Stacchetti, Ennio. 1986. “Optimal Cartel Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring.” Journal of Economic Theory 39 (June): 251–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abulafia, David. 1977. The Two Italies. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abulafia, David. 1985. “Catalan Merchants and the Western Mediterranean, 1236–1300: Studies in the Notarial Acts of Barcelona and Sicily.” Viator 16: 209–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abu-Lughod, Janet. 1991. Before European Hegemony: The World System, A. D. 1250–1350. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (Dec.): 1369–1401CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James A.. 2002. “The Rise of Europe: Atlantic Trade, Institutional Change and Economic Growth.” Memo, MITCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2000. “Political Losers as a Barrier to Economic Development.” AEA Papers and Proceedings 90: 126–30Google Scholar
Airaldi, Gabriella. 1983. “Groping in the Dark: The Emergence of Genoa in the Early Middle Ages.” Miscellanea di Studi Storia 2: 7–17Google Scholar
Airaldi, Gabriella. 1986. Genova e la Liguria nel Medioevo. Turin: Utet LibreriaGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1986. An Economic Theorist's Book of Tales. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Kranton, R. E.. 2000. “Economics and Identity.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3): 715–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Yellen, Janet L.. 1986. Efficiency Wage Models of the Labor Market. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
AlSayyad, Nezar. 1991. Cities and Caliphs: On the Genesis of Arab Muslim Urbanism. New York: GreenwoodGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James, and Miller, John. 2002. “Giving According to GARP: An Experimental Test of the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism.” Econometrica 70 (2): 737–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Annali Genovesi di Caffaro e dei suoi Continuatori. 1099–1240. Trans. Ceccardo Roccatagliata Ceccardi and Giovanni Monleone. 4 vols. Genoa: Municipio di Genova, 1923–29
Annen, Kurt. 2003. “Social Capital, Inclusive Networks, and Economic Performance.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (4): 449–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 1994. “The Contingent Governance of Teams: Analysis of Institutional Complementarity.” International Economic Review 35 (3): 657–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Masahiko. 2001. Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Arias, G. 1901. I trattati commerciali della Repubblica Fiorentina. Florence: Successori le MonnierGoogle Scholar
Aron, J. 2000. “Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence.” World Bank Research Observer 15 (1): 99–135CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1981. “Optimal and Voluntary Income Redistribution.” In Rosenfield, Steven (ed.), Economic Welfare and the Economics of Soviet Socialism: Essays in Honor of Abram Bergson, 267–88. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, Brian W. 1988. “Self-Reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics.” In Arrow, K. J. and Anderson, P. (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System, 9–33. New York: WileyGoogle Scholar
Arthur, Brian W. 1994. Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashburner, M., and Walter, A.. 1909. The Rodian Sea-Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J. 1987. “Game Theory.” In Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P. (eds.), The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 2: 460–82. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J., and Brandenburger, Adam. 1995. “Epistemic Conditions for Nash Equilibrium.” Econometrica 65 (5): 1161–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aumann, Robert J., and Hart, Sergiu (eds.). 1994, 2002. Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Implications. Vols. 2, 3. North Holland: Elsevier Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Bairoch, Paul, Batou, Jean, and Chèvre, Pierre (eds.). 1988. The Population of European Cities from 800 to 1850. Geneva: Center of International Economic HistoryGoogle Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep, and Polak, Ben. 2004. “The Emergence and Persistence of the Anglo-Saxon and German Financial Systems.” Review of Financial Studies 17 (1): 129–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R. 2001. “Individualism, Collectivism, and Economic Development.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 573 (Jan.): 57–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ballard, Adolphus, and Tait, James (eds.). 1913. British Borough Charters, 1042–1216. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Ballard, Adolphus, and Tait, James (eds.). 1923. British Borough Charters, 1216–1307. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bandura, A. 1971. Social Learning Theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. V., and Newman, A. F.. 1993. “Occupational Choice and the Process of Development.” Journal of Political Economy 101 (2): 274–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S., and Randall L. Calvert. 1989. “Communication and Efficiency in Coordination Games.” Working Paper No. 196. Department of Political Science, University of Rochester
Barbadoro, Bernardino. 1921. Consigli della Reppublica Fiorentina. Bologna: R. Accademia dei Lincei, Forni EditoreGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab. 1991. “Alternative Approaches to the Theory of Institutions in Economic Development.” In Bardhan, Pranab (ed.), The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, 3–17. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Yoram. 2002. A Theory of the State. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 2001. Prosperity and Violence: The Political Economy of Development. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Figueiredo, R. J. P., and Weingast, B. R.. 1998. “The Politics of Interpretation: Rationality, Culture, and Transition.” Politics & Society 26 (4): 603–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Greif, Avner, Levi, Margaret, Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent, and Weingast, Barry. 1998. Analytic Narrative. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Bates, Robert H., Greif, Avner, and Singh, Smita. 2002. “Organizing Violence.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (5): 599–628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1974. “A Theory of Social Interactions.” Journal of Political Economy 82: 1963–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belgrano, Luigi T. 1873. Tavole genealogiche a corredo della illustrazione del registro arcivescovile de Genova. Genoa: Atti della Società Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Bellah, Robert N., Madsen, Richard, Sullivan, William M., Swidler, Ann, and Tipton, Steven M.. 1985. Habits of the Heart: Individualism and Commitment in American Life. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Bellamy, John. 1973. Crime and the Courts in England, 1660–1800. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Benabou, R. 1994. “Education, Income Distribution, and Growth: The Local Connection.” Working paper, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Bendor, Jonathan, and Mookherjee, Dilip. 1990. “Norms, Third-Party Sanctions, and Cooperation.” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 6 (Spring): 33–63Google Scholar
Benjamin of Tudela. 1159–1173. Itinerary. Trans. Michael Singer, Marcus N. Adler, and A. Asher. Malibu, Calif.: Joseph Simon/Pangloss Press, 1987
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Putterman, Louis (eds.). 1998. Economics, Values and Organization. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, Jean-Pierre, and Krishna, Vijay. 1985. “Finitely Repeated Games.” Econometrica 53 (4): 905–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bensa, Enrico. 1925. The Early History of Bills of Lading. Genoa: Stabilimento D'arti GraficheGoogle Scholar
Ben-Sasson, Menahem. 1991. The Jews of Sicily, 825–1068 (in Hebrew and Judeo-Arabic). Jerusalem: Ben-Zevi InstituteGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce L. 1989. “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law.” Southern Economic Journal 55 (3): 644–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beresford, M., and Finberg, H. P. R.. 1973. English Medieval Boroughs: A Handlist. Newton Abbott: David and CharlesGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L. 1977. Invitation to Sociology. Harmondsworth: Penguin BooksGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L., and Luckmann, Thomas. 1967. The Social Construction of Reality. New York: Anchor BooksGoogle Scholar
Berkowitz, Daniel, Pistor, Katherian, and Richard, Jean-François. 2003. “Economic Development, Legality, and the Transplant Effect.” European Economic Review 47 (1): 165–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Harold J. 1983. Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western Legal Tradition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas. 1984. “Rationalizable Strategic Behavior.” Econometrica 52 (4): 1007–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Ray, Debraj. 1989. “Collective Dynamic Consistency in Dynamic Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (4): 295–326CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, and Whinston, Michael D.. 1990. “Multi-market Contract and Collusive Behavior.” Rand Journal of Economics 21 (1): 1–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, L. 1992. “Opting Out the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry.” Journal of Legal Studies 21 (Jan.): 115–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertolotto, Gerolamo. 1896. “Nuova serie di documenti sulle relazioni di Genova coll' Impero Bizantino.” In Atti della Società Ligure de Storia Patria, XXVIII. Genoa: Società Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Besley, Tim, and Coate, Stephen. 1995. “Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and Social Collateral.” Journal of Development Economics 46 (1): 1–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bester, H., and Güth, W.. 1998. “Is Altruism Evolutionarily Stable?Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 34: 193–209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth. 1996. “A Note on Backward Induction.” Games and Economic Behavior 17 (1): 135–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth, Gale, John, and Samuelson, Larry. 1995. “Learning to be Imperfect: The Ultimatum Game.” Games and Economic Behavior 8: 56–90Google Scholar
Bittles, Alan H. 1994. “The Role and Significance of Consanguinity as a Demographic Variable.” Population and Development Review 20 (3): 561–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blau, Joshua, 1961. A Grammar of Medieval Judaeo-Arabic. Jerusalem: Magnes PressGoogle Scholar
Blau, Joshua. 1965. The Emergence and Linguistic Background of Judaeo-Arabic. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Marc. 1961. Feudal Society. Vol. 1. Trans. L. A. Manyon. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, Iris, and Frey, Bruno S.. 1999. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games: Comment.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 335–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Gary E., and Ockenfels, Axel. 2000. “A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity and Competition.” American Economic Review 90 (1): 166–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouman, F. J. A. 1995. “Rotating and Accumulating Savings and Credit Associations: A Development Perspective.” World Development 23 (3): 371–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert. 1976. Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and the Contradictions of Economic Life. New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 1998. “The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity.” Santa Fe Institute Working Paper, 98–08–073E
Brinton, Mary, and Nee, Victor (eds.). 1998. The New Institutionalism in Sociology. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Britnell, R. H. 1996. The Commercialisation of English Society, 1000–1500. 2nd ed. New York: Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. 1999. The Collected Works of James M. Buchanan. Fairfax, VA: Liberty FundGoogle Scholar
Bull, Clive. 1987. “The Existence of Self-Enforcing Implicit Contracts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (1): 147–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bulow, Jeremy, and Rogoff, Kenneth. 1989. “A Constant Reconstracting Model of Sovereign Debt.” Journal of Political Economy 97 (1): 155–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1916–17. “Commercial Contracts of the Genoese in the Syrian Trade of the Twelfth Century.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 31: 128–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1920. “Genoese Trade with Syria in the Twelfth Century.” American Historical Review 25: 191–219CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byrne, Eugene H. 1928. “The Genoese Colonies in Syria.” In Paetow, L. J. (ed.), The Crusade and Other Historical Essays, 139–82. New York: F. S. Crofts
Cahen, Claude. 1990. “Economy, Society, Institutions.” In Holt, P. M., Lambton, Ann K. S., and Lewis, Bernard (eds.), The Cambridge History of Islam, 511–38. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Calendar of Letters from the Mayor and Corporation of the City of London. Circa A. D. 1350–60. Ed. Sharpe, Reginald R.. London: Corporation of the City of London, 1885Google Scholar
Calendar of Plea and Memoranda Rolls Preserved among the Archives of the Corporation of the City of London at the Guild Hall. 1926–61. Corporation of London. 6 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press
Calendar of the Patent Rolls Preserved in the Public Record Office. English Historical Documents. 1893–1910. 14 vols. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office
Calvert, Randall L. 1992. “Leadership and Its Basis in Problems of Social Coordination.” International Political Science Review 13 (1): 7–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995. “Rational Actors, Equilibrium, and Social Institutions.” In Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai (eds.), Explaining Social Institutions, 57–93. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin, and Ari Vespsalaninen. 1987. “The Efficiency of Corporate Culture.” Paper presented at the Colloquium on Strategy Content Research, The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania
Campos, N. F., and Nugent, J. B.. 2002. “Who Is afraid of Political Instability?Journal of Development Economics 67 (1): 157–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cardini, Franco. 1978. “Profilo di un Crociato Guglielmo Embriaco.” Acrchivo Storico Italiano 2–4: 405–36Google Scholar
Carus-Wilson, E. M. 1967. Medieval Merchant Venturers. London: Butler and TannerGoogle Scholar
Casella, A., and Rauch, J. E.. 2002. “Anonymous Market and Group Ties in International Trade.” Journal of International Economics 58 (1): 19–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Catoni, Giuliano. 1976. “La brutta avventura di un mercante senese nel 1309 e una questione di rappresaglia.” Archivo Storico Italiano 479: 65–77Google Scholar
Cavalli-Sforza, Luigi L., and Feldman, Marcus W.. 1981. Cultural Transmission and Evolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chamley, Christophe P. 2004. Rational Herds: Economic Models of Social Learning. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Charness, Gary, and Grosskopf, Brit. 2001. “Relative Payoffs and Happiness: An Experimental Study.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 45: 301–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, Gary, and Rabin, Matthew. 2002. “Understanding Social Preferences with Simple Tests.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (3): 817–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiani, Emilio. 1962. Nobilta' e popolo nel Comune di Pisa. Instituto Italiano per gli Studi Storici, 13. Milan: Casa Editrice EinaudiGoogle Scholar
Chwe, Michael Suk Young. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Cipolla, Carlo M. 1993. Before the Industrial Revolution. 3rd ed. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Çizakça, Murat. 1996. A Comparative Evolution of Business Partnerships. Leiden: E. J. BrillGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andy. 1997a. “Economic Reason: The Interplay of Individual Learning and External Structure.” In Drobak, John and Nye, John (eds.), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 269–90. San Diego, CA: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Clark, Andy. 1997b. Being There: Putting the Brain, Body, and World Togther Again. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Clark, Gregory. 1991. “Yields per Acre in English Agriculture, 1250–1860: Evidence from Labour Inputs.” Economic History Review 44 (3): 445–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clay, Karen. 1997. “Trade, Institutions, and Credit.” Explorations in Economic History 34 (4): 495–521CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Close Rolls of the Reign of Henry III. 1227–72. 14 vols. London: His Majesty's Stationery Office, 1902–38
Coase, Ronald H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica, n.s., 4: 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Codice diplomatico della Repubblica di Genova dal ⅯⅭⅬⅫII [sic] al ⅯⅭⅬXXXX [sic]. 1936, 1938, 1942, Ed. di Sant'Angelo, Cesare Imperiale. Vols. I–III. Rome: Tipografia del Senato
Cole, Harold L., Mailath, George J., and Postlewaite, Andrew. 1992. “Social Norms, Saving Behavior and Growth.” Journal of Political Economy 100 (6): 1092–1125CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Collier, David, and Collier, Ruth. 1991. Shaping the Political Arena. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Collins, Kathleen. 2004. “The Logic of Clan Politics – Evidence from Central Asian Trajectories.” World Politics 56 (2): 224–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colvin, Ian D. 1971. The Germans in England, 1066–1598. London: Kennikat PressGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Conlisk, J. 1996. “Why Bounded Rationality?Journal of Economic Literature 34 (2): 669–700Google Scholar
Constable, R. Olivia. 2003. Housing the Stranger in the Mediterranean World: Lodging, Trade, and Travel in Late Antiquity and the Middle Ages. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Cook, Mechael. 2003. Forbidding Wrong in Islam. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coulton, G. G. (ed.). 1918. Social Life in Britain from the Conquest to the Reformation. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crawford, S., and Ostrom, Elinor. 1995. “A Grammar of Institutions.” American Political Review 89 (3): 582–600CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, Jacques. 1986. “Cooperation in Ongoing Organizations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101 (1): 33–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2002. Roman, Provincial and Islamic Law. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2003. Slaves on Horses. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Crone, Patricia. 2004. God's Rule: Government and Islam. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
D'Andrade, R. G. 1984. “Cultural Meaning Systems.” In Shweder, R. A. and LeVine, R. A. (eds.), Culture Theory: Essays on Mind, Self, and Emotion, 88–122. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha. 2000. “Economic Progress and the Idea of Social Capital.” In Dasgupta, Partha and Serageldin, Ismail (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective, 325–424. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha, and Serageldin, Ismail (eds.). 2000. Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
David, Paul A. 1985. “Clio and the Economics of Qwerty.” American Economic Review 75 (2): 332–37Google Scholar
David, Paul A. 1994. “Why Are Institutions the ‘Carriers of History’?: Path-Dependence and the Evolution of Conventions, Organizations and Institutions.” Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 5 (2): 205–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, Douglas D., and Holt, Charles A.. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Davis, Kingsley. 1949. Human Society. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M., and Thaler, Richard H.. 1988. “Anomalies: Cooperation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2 (3): 187–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, John. 1963. Les douanes de genes, 1376–1377. Paris: S. E. V. P. E. N.Google Scholar
Day, Gerald W. 1984. “The Impact of the Third Crusade upon Trade with the Levant.” International History Review 3 (Apr.): 159–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Day, Gerald W. 1988. Genoa's Response to Byzantium, 1154–1204. Urbana: University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
De Figueiredo, Rui, Jack Rakove, and Barry R. Weingast. 2001. “Rationality, Inaccurate Mental Models, and Self-Confirming Equilibrium: A New Understanding of the American Revolution.” Memo, Stanford University
Dekel, E., Fudenberg, D., and Levine, D. K.. 1999. “Payoff Information and Self-Confirming Equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Theory 89 (2): 165–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Negri, Teoflio Ossian. 1986. Storia di Genova. Florence: G. MartelloGoogle Scholar
Denzau, A., and North, D. C.. 1994. “Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions.” Kyklos 47: 3–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roover, Raymond. 1948. Money, Banking and Credit in Mediaeval Bruges. Cambridge, MA: Mediaeval Academy of AmericaGoogle Scholar
Roover, Raymond. 1963. The Rise and Decline of the Medici Bank, 1397–1494. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
de Roover, Raymond. 1965. “The Organization of Trade.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3:42–118. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Jared. 1997. Guns, Germs, and Steel: The Fates of Human Societies. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul. 1994. “Culture and Economy.” In Smelser, Neil and Swedberg, Richard (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 27–57. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul. 1997. “The New Institutionalism: Avenues of Collaboration.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154: 1–10Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul, and W. Powell. 1991a. Introduction. In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 1–40. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul, and W. Powell. 1991b. “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 63–82. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Nalebuff, Barry. 1991. Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics and Everyday Life. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Djankov, Simeon, Glaeser, Edward L., Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shleifer, Andrei. 2003. “The New Comparative Economics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31 (4): 595–619CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, F. 1994. Forging Industrial Policy: The United States, Britain and France in the Railroad Age. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dollinger, Philippe. 1970. The German Hansa. Stanford, CA.: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
Donaver, Federico. 1990 [1890]. Storia di Genova. Genoa: Nuova Editrice GenoveseGoogle Scholar
Duby, Georges. 1974. The Early Growth of the European Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Duffy, Bella. 1903. The Tuscan Republics (Florence, Siena, Pisa and Lucca) with Genoa. New York: G. P. Putnam's SonsGoogle Scholar
Dugger, William M. 1990. “The New Insitutionalism: New but Not Insitutionalist.” Journal of Economic Issues 24 (2): 423–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1950 [1895]. The Rules of Sociological Method. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Durkheim, Emile. 1953. Sociology and Philosophy. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Easterly, William. 2001. The Illusive Quest for Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Easterly, William, and R. Levine. 2002. “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development.” Mimeo, Center for Global Development and Institute for International Economics
Eggertsson, Thráinn. 1990. Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., Hébert, Robert F., Tollison, Robert D., Anderson, Gary M., and Davidson, Audrey B.. 1996. Sacred Trust: The Medieval Church as an Economic Firm. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Tollison, Robert D.. 1981. Mercantilism as a Rent-Seeking Society. College Station: Texas A&M University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. 1991. Order without Law. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellison, Glenn. 1993. “Learning, Local Interaction, and Coordination.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1047–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellison, Glenn. 1994. “Cooperation in the Prisoner's Dilemma with Anonymous Random Matching.” Review of Economic Studies 61 (3): 567–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1983. Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1989a. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 1989b. “Social Norms and Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3 (4): 99–117CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon. 2000. “Rational Choice History: A Case of Excessive Ambition.” American Political Science Review 94 (3): 685–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ely, J., and O. Yilankaya. 1997. “Evolution of Preferences and Nash Equilibrium.” Mimeo, Northwestern University
Emery, R. 1952. “The Use of the Surname in the Study of Medieval Economic History.” Medievalia et Humanistica 7: 43–50Google Scholar
Engerman, Stanley L., and Kenneth L. Sokoloff. 1997. “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies.” In Haber, Stephen (ed.), How Did Latin America Fall Behind?, 260–304. Stanford, CA: Stanford University PressGoogle Scholar
English, Edward D. 1988. Enterprise and Liability in Sienese Banking, 1230–1350. Cambridge, MA: Medieval Academy of AmericaGoogle Scholar
English Historical Documents, 1042–1189. 1968. Ed. Douglas, D. C. and Greenaway, G. W.. Vol. 2. London: Eyre and SpottiswoodeGoogle Scholar
English Historical Documents, 1189–1327. 1975. Ed. Rothwell, H.. Vol. 3. London: Eyre and SpottiswoodeGoogle Scholar
Ensminger, Jean. 1997. “Changing Property Rights: Reconciling Formal and Informal Rights to Land in Africa.” In Drobak, John N. and Nye, John V. C. (eds.), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 165–96. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1984. Wills and Wealth in Medieval Genoa, 1150–1250. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1991. Wage Labor and Guilds in Medieval Europe. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven A. 1996. Genoa and the Genoese, 958–1528. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina PressGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven. R. 1998. “Craft Guilds, Apprenticeship and Technological Change in Preindustrial Europe.” Journal of Economic History 53 (4): 684–713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Steven. R. 2000. Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Markets in Europe, 1300–1750. New York: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ertman, Thomas. 1997. Birth of the Leviathan: Building States and Regimes in Medieval and Early Modern Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eysenck, M. W., and Keane, M. T.. 1995. Cognitive Psychology: A Student's Handbook. Hillsdale, MI: Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Face, Richard D. 1952. “The Embriaci: Feudal Imperialists of the Twelfth-Century Genoa.” M. A. thesis, University of Cincinnati
Face, Richard D. 1958. “Techniques of Business in the Trade between the Fairs of Champagne and the South of Europe in the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries.” Economic History Review 10 (3): 427–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Face, Richard D. 1980. “Secular History in Twelfth Century Italy: Caffaro of Genoa.” Journal of Medieval History 6 (2): 169–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel. 2004. Market Institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Falk, Armin, and Urs Fischbacher. 2000. “A Theory of Reciprocity.” Working Paper No. 6, University of Zurich
Farrell, Joseph, and Maskin, Eric. 1989. “Renegotiation in Repeated Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (3): 327–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1991. “Counterfactuals and Hypothesis-Testing in Political-Science.” World Politics 43 (2): 169–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1997. “Bargaining over Objects That Influence Future Bargaining Power.” Working paper, Department of Political Science, University of Chicago
Fearon, James D., and Laitin, David D.. 1996. “Explaining Interethnic Cooperation.” American Political Science Review 90 (4): 715–35CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Urs Fischbacher. 2001. “Reputation and Retaliation.” Mimeo, University of Zürich
Fehr, Ernst, and Gächter, Simon. 2000. “Cooperation and Punishment in Public Good Experiments.” American Economic Review 90 (4): 980–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M.. 1999. “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3): 817–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 2001. “Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications.” Working Paper 75, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zürich
Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 2003. “Theories of Fairness and Reciprosity: Evidence and Economic Applications.” In Dewatripont, Mathias, Hansen, Lars Peter, and Turnovsky, Stephen (eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, 1:208–56. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Fernandez, Raquel, and Rodrik, Dani. 1991. “Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 81 (5): 1146–55Google Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim, and Weiss, Yoram. 1993. “Social Status, Culture and Economic Performance.” Economic Journal 103 (July): 946–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, Alexander. 1981. “The Problem with Neoclassical Institutional Economics: A Critique with Special Reference to the North-Thomas Model of Pre-1500 Europe.” Explorations in Economic History 18 (2): 174–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Field, Alexander. 2002. Altruistically Inclined?: The Behavioral Sciences, Evolutionary Theory, and the Origins of Reciprocity. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs, Gächter, Simon, and Fehr, Ernst. 2001. “Are People Conditionally Cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment.” Economic Letters 71: 397–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischel, Walter J. 1958. “The Spice Trade in Mamluk Egypt.” Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient 1 (2): 157–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fligstein, Neil. 1990. The Transformation of Corporate Control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Horowitz, Joel, Savin, N. S., and Sefton, Martin. 1994. “Fairness in Simple Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 6: 347–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Andre Gunder. 1998. Reorient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 1987. “If Homo Economics Could Choose His Own Utility Function, Would He Want One with a Conscience?American Economic Review 77 (4): 593–604Google Scholar
French, H. R., and Hoyle, R. W.. 2003. “English Individualism Refuted – and Reasserted: The Land Market of Earls Clone (Essex), 1550–1750.” Economic History Review 4 (Nov.): 595–622CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. 1997. Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar PublishingGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James W. 1971. “Noncooperative Equilibrium for Supergames.” Review of Economic Studies 38 (8): 1–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Jeffrey (ed.). 1996. The Rational Choice Controversy: Economic Models of Politics Reconsidered. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1984. The Methodology of Positive Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and D. Kreps. 1988. “A Theory of Learning and Nash Equilibrium.” Mimeo, Stanford University
Fudenberg, Drew, and Levine, David K.. 1993. “Self-Confirming Equilibrium.” Econometrica 61 (3): 523–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Levine, David K.. 1998. The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and David K. Levine. 2003. “Steady State Learning and the Code of Hammurabi.” Working paper, University of California, Los Angeles
Fudenberg, Drew, Levine, David K., and Maskin, Eric. 1994. “The Folk Theorem with Imperfect Public Information.” Econometrica 62 (5): 997–1039CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, D., and Maskin, E.. 1986. “The Folk Theorem for Repeated Games with Discounting and Incomplete Information.” Econometrica 54 (3): 533–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, and Tirole, Jean. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Furnivall, John S. 1956. Colonial Policy and Practice: A Comparative Study of Burma and Netherlands India. New York: New York University PressGoogle Scholar
Furubotn, Erik G., and Richter, Rudolf. 1997. Institutions and Economic Theory. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Gächter, Simon, and Falk, Armin. 2002. “Reputation and Reciprocity: Consequences for the Labour Relation.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 104 (1): 1–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galor, O., and Zeira, J.. 1993. “Income-Distribution and Macroeconomics.” Review of Economic Studies 60 (1): 35–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Harold. 1967. Studies in Ethnomethodology. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Geanakoplos, John, Pearce, David, and Stacchetti, Ennio. 1989. “Psychological Games and Sequential Rationality.” Games and Economic Behavior 1 (1): 60–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghatak, M., and Guinnane, T. W.. 1999. “The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability: Theory and Practice.” Journal of Development Economics 60 (1): 195–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghosh, Parikshit, and Ray, Debraj. 1996. “Cooperation in Community Interaction without Information Flows.” Review of Economic Studies 63 (3): 491–519CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 1992. Game Theory for Applied Economists. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 1998. “Game Theory and Garbage Cans: An Introduction to the Economics of Internal Organization.” In Stern, R. and Halpern, J. (eds.), Debating Rationality: Nonrational Elements of Organizational Decision Making, chap. 2. Ithaca, NY: ILR PressGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert. 2001. “Trust in Social Structures: Hobbes and Coase Meet Repeated Games.” In Cook, K. (ed.), Trust in Society, chap. 11. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert, and Andrew Rutten. 1997. “Hierarchical Dilemmas: Social Order with Self-Interested Rulers.” Working paper, Cornell University
Giddens, Anthony. 1997. Sociology. London: Polity PressGoogle Scholar
Gil, Moshe. 1971. The Tustars, the Family and the Sect. Tel Aviv: Tel Aviv University PressGoogle Scholar
Gil, Moshe. 1983a. “The Jews in Sicily under the Muslim Rule in the Light of the Geniza Documents.” Unpublished manuscript, Tel Aviv University
Gil, Moshe. 1983b. Palestine during the First Muslim Period (634–1099) (in Hebrew and Arabic). Vols. 1–3. Tel Aviv: Ministry of Defense Press and Tel Aviv University PressGoogle Scholar
Gilboa, Itzhak, and Schmeidler, David. 2001. Theory of Case-Based Decisions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert. 2000. Game Theory Evolving. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Giovanni di Guiberto. 1200–11. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Hall-Cole, M. W. and Reinert, R. G.. Documenti, XVII–XVIII. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1939–40Google Scholar
Giovanni Scriba. 1154–64. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Chiaudano, Mario and Moresco, Mattia. Vols. 1, 2. Turin: S. Lattes & C. Editori, 1935Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Porta, Rafael, Lopez-de-Silanes, Florencio, and Shliefer, Andrei. 2004. Do Institutions Cause Growth? Memo, Harvard UniversityCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., and Shleifer, Andrei. 2002. “Legal Origin.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1193–1230CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1957. “The Beginning of the Karim Merchants and the Character of Their Organization.” Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient 1: 175–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1964. “Commercial and Family Partnerships in the Countries of Medieval Islam.” Islamic Studies 3: 315–37Google Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1967. A Mediterranean Society: Economic Foundations. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1971. A Mediterranean Society: The Community. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1973. Letters of Medieval Jewish Traders. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Goitein, Shelomo Dov. 1978. A Mediterranean Society: The Family. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira. 2002. “Institutions for Contract Enforcement and Risk-Sharing: From Debt to Equity in Late Medieval Venice.” Memo, Ente Einaudi, Bank of Italy
Gonzalez de Lara, Yadira. 2004. “The State as an Enforcer in Early Venetian Trade: A Historical Institutional Analysis.” Memo, University of Alicante, Spain
Goodin, Robert, and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.). 1996. A New Handbook of Political Science. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Goody, J. 1983. The Development of the Family and Marriage in Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gould, S. J., and Eldredge, N.. 1977. “Punctuated Equilibria: The Tempo and Mode of Evolution Reconsidered.” Paleobiology 3: 115–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grantham, George. 1992. “The Manse, the Manor and the Market: New Perspectives on the Medieval Agricultural Revolution.” Memo, McGill University
Grantham, George. 1993. “Economic Growth without Causes: A Reexamination of Medieval Economic Growth and Decay.” Presented at the annual meeting of the American Economic History Association, Tucson, AZ
Granovetter, Mark S. 1985. “Economic Action, Social Structure, and Embeddedness.” American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481–510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark S. 2002. “A Theoretical Agenda for Economic Sociology.” In Guillen, Mauro, Collins, Randall, England, Paula, and Meyer, Marshall (eds.), The New Economic Sociology: Developments in an Emerging Field, 35–59. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Gras, N. S. B. 1939. Business and Capitalism: An Introduction to Business History. New York: F. S. CroftsGoogle Scholar
Green, Donald P., and Shapiro, Ian. 1994. Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Green, Edward, and Porter, Robert. 1984. “Noncooperative Collusion under Imperfect Price Information.” Econometrica 52 (Jan.): 87–100CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1985. “Sicilian Jews during the Muslim Period (827–1061)” (in Hebrew and Arabic). M. A. thesis, Tel Aviv University
Greif, Avner. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.” Journal of Economic History 49 (4): 857–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1992. “Institutions and Commitment in International Trade: Lessons from the Commercial Revolution.” American Economic Review 82 (2): 128–33Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Maghribi Traders' Coalition.” American Economic Review 83 (3): 525–48Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994a. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (5): 912–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994b. “Trading Institutions and the Commercial Revolution in Medieval Europe.” In Aganbegyan, Abel, Bogomolov, Oleg, and Kaser, Michael (eds.), Economics in a Changing World, 1: 115–25. Proceedings of the Tenth World Congress of the International Economic Association. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1994c. “On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa during the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries.” Journal of Economic History 54 (4): 271–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1995. “Political Organizations, Social Structures, and Institutional Success: Reflections from Genoa and Venice during the Commercial Revolution.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 151 (4): 734–40Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1996a. “A Comment on the ‘Evolution of Economic Systems: The Case of Japan’ by Tetsuji Okazaki and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara.” In Hayami, Y. and Aoki, Masahiko (eds.), The Institutional Foundation of Economic Development in East Asia, 522–6. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1996b. “Microtheory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions through Economic History.” Working Paper No. 96–001, Stanford University, Department of Economics
Greif, Avner. 1997a. “Microtheory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions through Economic History.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, 2: 79–113. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997b. “Institutional Structure and Economic Development: Economic History and the New Institutionalism.” In Drobak, John N. and Nye, John (eds.), Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, 57–94. Volume in honor of Douglass C. North. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997c. “Cultural Beliefs as a Common Resource in an Integrating World: An Example from the Theory and History of Collectivist and Individualist Societies.” In Dasgupta, P., Mäler, K.-G., and Vercelli, A. (eds.), The Economics of Transnational Commons, 238–96. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1997d. “Contracting, Enforcement, and Efficiency: Economics beyond the Law.” In Bruno, Michael and Pleskovic, Boris (eds.), Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 239–66. Washington, DC: World BankGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998a. “Historical and Comparative Institutional Analysis.” American Economic Review 88 (2): 80–4Google Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998b. “Historical Institutional Analysis: Game Theory and Non-market Self-Enforcing Institutions during the Late Medieval Period” (in French). Annales, no. 3 (May–June): 597–633CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 1998c. “Self-Enforcing Political Systems and Economic Growth: Late Medieval Genoa.” In Robert H. Bates, Avner Greif, Margaret Levi, Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, and Barry R. Weingast, Analytic Narratives, 23–63. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2000. “The Fundamental Problem of Exchange: A Research Agenda in Historical Institutional Analysis.” Review of European Economic History 4 (3): 251–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2001. “Impersonal Exchange and the Origin of Markets: From the Community Responsibility System to Individual Legal Responsibility in Pre-modern Europe.” In Aoki, M. and Hayami, Y. (eds.), Communities and Markets in Economic Development, 3–41. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2002. “The Islamic Equilibrium: Legitimacy and Political, Social, and Economic Outcomes.” Working paper, Stanford University
Greif, Avner. 2004a. “State Building and Commercial Expansion: Genoa's Experience.” Memo, Stanford University
Greif, Avner. 2004b. “Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange.” In Menard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M. (eds.), The Handbook for New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic PublishersGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner. 2004c. “Impersonal Exchange without Impartial Law: The Community Responsibility System.” Chicago Journal of International Law 5 (1): 109–38Google Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Eugene Kandel. 1995. “Contract Enforcement Institutions: Historical Perspective and Current Status in Russia.” In Lazear, Edward P. (ed.), Economic Transition in Eastern Europe and Russia: Realities of Reform, 291–321. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution PressGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, and Laitin, David. 2004. “A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change.” American Political Science Review 98 (4): 1–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, Milgrom, Paul R., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1994. “Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Gild.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (4): 745–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gross, Charles. 1890. Gild Merchant. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2002a. Special Interest Politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2002b. “Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 85–120CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 2003. “Outsourcing in a Global Economy.” Review of Economic Studies 1: 300–16Google Scholar
Grossman, Herschel, and Kim, Minseong. 1995. “Swords or Plowshares? A Theory of the Security of Claims to Property.” Journal of Political Economy 103 (6): 1275–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Sanford J., and Hart, Oliver D.. 1986. “The Cost and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94 (4): 691–719CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guglielmo Cassinese. 1190–2. Carlolare (in Latin and Italian). In Hall, Margaret W., Krueger, Hilmar C., and Reynolds, Robert L. (eds.), Notai Liguri Del Sec. Ⅻ. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1938Google Scholar
Guinnane, T. W. “Cooperatives as Information Machines: German Rural Credit Cooperatives, 1883–1914.” Discussion Papers 97–20. University of Copenhagen, Department of Economics
Gurevich, Aaron. 1995. The Origins of European Individualism. Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Gustafsson, Bo. 1987. “The Rise and Economic Behaviour of Medieval Crafts Guilds. An Economic-Theoretical Interpretation.” Scandinavian Economic History Review 35 (1): 1–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W. 1992. “An Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Cooperative Behavior by Reciprocal Incentives.” International Journal of Game Theory 24: 323–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., and M. Yaari. 1992. “Explaining Reciprocal Behavior in Simple Strategic Games: An Evolutionary Approach.” In Witt, U. (ed.), Explaining Forces and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary Economics, 23–34. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haber, Stephen. 1997. “Institutional Change and TFP Growth: Brazil and Mexico, 1860–1940.” Working Paper, Stanford University
Haber, Stephen, Razo, Armando, and Maurer, Noel. 2003. The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876–1929. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagel, John H., and Roth, Alvin (eds.). 1995. Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Taylor, Rosemary C. R.. 1996. “Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms.” Political Studies 44 (4): 936–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A., and Taylor, Rosemary C. R.. 1998. “The Potential of Historical Institutionalism: A Response to Hay and Wincott.” Political Studies 46 (4): 958–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E., and Jones, Charles I.. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker Than Others?Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (Feb.): 83–116CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Gary G. 1991. “The Organizational Foundations of Western and Chinese Commerce: A Historical and Comparative Analysis.” In Hamilton, Gary G. (ed.), Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia, 48–65. Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong, Centre of Asian StudiesGoogle Scholar
Hanawalt, B. 1974. “The Peasant Family and Crime in Fourteenth-Century England.” Journal of British Studies 13 (2): 1–18Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1989. “Why a Constitution.” In Grofman, Bernard and Wittman, Donal (eds.), The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism, 100–20. New York: Agathon PressGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1997. “Economic Theories of the State.” In Mueller, Dennis C. (ed.), Perspectives on Public Choice: A Handbook, 21–34. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver. 2001. “Norms and the Theory of the Firm.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 149 (6): 1701–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Bengt Holmstrom. 1987. “The Theory of Contracts.” In Bewley, Truman F. (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory, Fifth World Congress, 71–157. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver, and Moore, J.. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 115–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hatcher, John, and Bailey, Mark. 2001. Modeling the Middle Ages: The History and Theory of England's Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A.. 1937. “Economics and Knowledge.” Economica 4: 33–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1973. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 1. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1976. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 2. Chicago: University of ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. von. 1979. Law Legislation and Liberty. Vol. 3. Chicago: University of ChicagoGoogle Scholar
Hearder, H., and Waley, D. P. (eds.). 1963. A Short History of Italy from Classical Times to the Present Day. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hechter, M. 1992. “The Insufficiency of Game Theory for the Resolution of Real World Collective Action Problems.” Rationality and Society 4 (1): 33–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heers, Jacques. 1977. Parties and Political Life in the Medieval West. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan. 2004. The Mystery of Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, and Gintis, Hebert. 2004. Foundations of Human Sociality: Experimental and Ethnographic Evidence from Fifteen Small-Scale Societies. Oxford: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph, Boyd, Robert, Bowles, Samuel, Camerer, Colin, Fehr, Ernst, Gintis, Hebert, and McElreath, Richard. 2001. “In Search for Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies.” American Economic Review 74 (May): 73–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herb, Michael. 2003. “Taxation and Representation.” Studies in Comparative International Development 38 (3): 3–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlihy, David. 1958. “The Agrarian Revolution in Southern France and Italy, 801–1150.” Speculum: A Journal of Mediaeval Studies 33 (1): 23–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herlihy, David. 1969. “Family Solidarity in Medieval Italian History.” In Herlihy, David, Lopez, R. S., Slessarev, V. (eds.), Economy Society, and Government in Medieval Italy: Essays in Memory of Robert L. Reynolds, 173–84. Kent, OH: Kent State University PressGoogle Scholar
Heyd, W. 1868. Le colonie commerciali degli Italiani in Oriente nel Medio Evo. 2 vols. Venice: G. AntonelliGoogle Scholar
Heyd, W. 1885. Histoire du commerce du Levant au Moyen-âge. 2 vols. Leipzig: Otto HarrassowitzGoogle Scholar
Heywood, William. 1921. A History of Pisa, Eleventh and Twelfth Centuries. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John. 1969. A Theory of Economic History. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Hickson, Charles R., and Thompson, Earl A.. 1991. “A New Theory of Guilds and European Economic Development.” Explorations in Economic History 28 (2): 127–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1985. “The Expanding Domain of Economics.” American Economic Review 75 (6): 53–70Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey M. 1998. “The Approach of Institutional Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 166–92Google Scholar
Hodgson, Marshall G. S. 1974. The Venture of Islam. Vols. 1, 2. Chicago: University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Shachat, Keith, and Smith, Vernon. 1994. “Preferences, Property Rights, and Anonymity in Bargaining Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 7 (3): 346–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, and Smith, Vernon. 1996a. “On Expectations and the Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games.” International Journal of Game Theory 125 (3): 289–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Smith, Vernon. 1996b. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.” American Economic Review 86 (3): 653–60Google Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T. 1990. “Taxes, Fiscal Crises, and Representative Institutions: The Case of Early Modern France.” Unpublished manuscript, Washington University, Center for the History of Freedom
Hoffman, Phillip T. 1991. “Land Rents and Agricultural Productivity – the Paris Basin, 1450–1789.” Journal of Economic History 51 (4): 771–805CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Phillip T. 1996. Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Philip T., Postel-Vinay, Gilles, and Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 2000. Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660–1870. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Höllander, Heinz. 1990. “A Social Exchange Approach to Voluntary Cooperation.” American Economic Review 80 (5): 1157–67Google Scholar
Homans, George C. 1950. The Human Group. New York: HarcourtGoogle Scholar
Homans, George C. 1961. Social Behavior. New York: Harcourt, Brace & WorldGoogle Scholar
Hsu, F. L. K. 1983. Rugged Individualism Reconsidered. Knoxville: University of Tennessee PressGoogle Scholar
Huck, S., and Oechssler, J.. 1999. “The Indirect Evolutionary Approach to Explaining Fair Allocations.” Games and Economic Behavior 28: 13–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1974. “Toward Historical Ethnography: Notarial Records and Family History in the Middle Ages.” Historical Methods Newsletter 7 (2): 61–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1977. “Kinsmen and Neighbors in Medieval Genoa.” In Mistiming, Harry A., Herlihy, David, and Udovitch, A. L. (eds.), The Medieval City, 95–111. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen. 1978. “Urban Growth and Family Structure in Medieval Genoa.” In Abrams, Philip and Wrigley, E. A. (eds.), Towns in Societies, 105–30. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Previously published in Past and Present 66 (1975): 3–28Google Scholar
Hughes, Everett C. 1937. “Institutional Office and the Person.” American Journal of Sociology 43 (3): 404–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, John K. 1973. Society and Politics in Medieval Italy: The Evolution of Civil Life, 1000–1350. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingram, Paul. 1996. “Organizational Form as a Solution to the Problem of Credible Commitment: The Evolution of Naming Strategies among US Hotel Chains, 1896–1980.” Strategic Management Journal 17 (Summer): 85–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacoby, David. 1997. Trade, Commodities, and Shipping in the Medieval Mediterranean. Aldershot: VariorumGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Simon, McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 2002. “Courts and Relational Contracts.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 18 (Spring): 221–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, W. J. 1976. The Foundations of English Bankruptcy: Statutes and Commissions in the Early Modern Period. Philadelphia: Transactions of the American Philosophical SocietyGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. 1984. “Vertical Integration and Long-Term Contracts: The Case of Mine-Mouth Coal Plants.” Paper presented at the Economic and Legal Organization Workshop, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Kalai, E., and Lehrer, E.. 1993a. “Rational Learning Leads to Nash Equilibrium.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1019–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Lehrer, E.. 1993b. “Subjective Equilibrium in Repeated Games.” Econometrica 61 (5): 1231–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalai, E. and Lehrer, E.. 1995. “Subjective Games and Equilibria.” Games and Economic Behavior 8: 123–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kali, R. 1999. “Endogenous Business Networks.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15 (3): 615–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kambayashi, Ryo. 2002. “The Registration System and the Grade Wage System, Coordination and Relative Performance Evaluation.” Memo, Tokyo University
Kandori, Michihiro. 1992. “Social Norms and Community Enforcement.” Review of Economic Studies 59 (1): 63–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 1997. “Evolutionary Game Theory in Economics.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory 1: 243–77. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 2002. “Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring.” Journal of Economic Theory 102 (1): 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro. 2003. “The Erosions and Sustainability of Norms and Morals.” Japanese Economic Review 54 (1): 29–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro, George Mailath, andRob, R.. 1993. “Learning, Mutation, and Long Run Equilibria in Games,” Econometrica 61 (1): 29–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaneko, Mamoru, and Matsui, Akihiko. 1999. “Inductive Game Theory: Discrimination and Prejudices.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 1 (1): 1–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kantor, Shawn E. 1998. Politics and Property Rights: The Closing of the Open Range in the Postbellum South. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kedar, Benjamin Z. 1976. Merchants in Crisis: Genoese and Venetian Men of Affairs and the Fourteenth-Century Depression. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Kelly, J. M. 1992. A Short History of Western Legal Theory. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, Hugh. 1986. The Prophet and the Age of the Caliphates. New York: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, and Leffler, Keith B.. 1981. “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (4): 615–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Daniel (ed.). 1996. Reputation: Studies in the Voluntary Enforcement of Good Behavior. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kockesen, L., Ok, E. A., and Sethi, R.. 2000a. “The Strategic Advantage of Negatively Interdependence Preferences.” Journal of Economic Theory 92: 274–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kockesen, L, Ok, E. A., and Sethi, R.. 2000b. “Evolution of Interdependent Preferences in Aggregative Games.” Games and Economic Behavior 31: 303–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Korotayev, A. V. 2003. “Unilineal Descent Organization and Deep Christianization: A Cross-Cultural Comparison.” Cross-Cultural Research 37 (1): 133–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E. 1996. “Reciprocal Exchange: A Self-Sustaining System.” American Economic Review 86 (4): 830–51Google Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E., and Minehart, D. F.. 2001. “A Theory of Buyer-Seller Networks.” American Economic Review 91 (3): 485–508CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krasner, S. D. 1984. “Approaches to the State: Alternative Conceptions and Historical Dynamics.” Comparative Politics 16 (2): 223–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M. 1990a. A Course in Microeconomic Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David, M. 1990b. “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory.” In Alt, James and Shepsle, Kenneth (eds.), Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, 90–143. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M., Milgrom, Paul, Roberts, John, and Wilson, Robert. 1982. “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners' Dilemma.” Journal of Economic Theory 27: 245–52CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kritkos, Alexander, and Friedel Bolle. 1999. “Approaching Fair Behavior: Self-Centered Inequality Aversion versus Reciprocity and Altruism.” Discussion Paper 143. Frankfurt/Oder
Kroeber, A. L., and Kluckhohn, Clyde. 1952. Culture: A Critical Review of Concepts and Definitions. Cambridge, MA: Peabody MuseumGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1932. “The Commercial Relations between Genoa and Northwest Africa in the Twelfth Century.” Ph.D. diss., University of Wisconsin, Madison
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1933. “Genoese Trade with Northwest Africa in the Twelfth Century.” Speculum 6 (July): 377–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1949. “Post-War Collapse and Rehabilitation in Genoa (1149–1162).” In Studi in onore di Gino Luzzatto, 4: 117–28. Milan: Istituto di Storia Economica dell'Universita di NapoliGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1957. “Genoese Merchants, Their Partnerships and Investments, 1155 to 1164.” In Cisalpina, Editoriale (eds.), Studi in onore di Armando Sapori, 257–72. Milan: Institudo Editoriale CisalpinoGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1962. “Genoese Merchants, Their Associations and Investments, 1155 to 1230.” In Graffre, D. A. (ed.), Studi in onore di Amintore Fanfani, 1: 415–26. Milan: Multa PaucisGoogle Scholar
Krueger, Hilmar C. 1987. “The Genoese Exportation of Northern Cloths to Mediterranean Ports, Twelfth Century.” Revue Belge de Philologie et d'Histoire 65 (4): 722–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Arthur K. 1912. The Law of Corporations. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1993. “The Unthinkable and the Unthought.” Rationality and Society 5 (4): 473–505CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1995. Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 1998. “Moral Overload and Its Alleviation.” In Ben-Ner, Avner and Putterman, Louis (eds.), Economics, Values, and Organization, 231–66. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2004. “Why the Middle East Is Economically Underdeveloped: Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation.” Journal of Economic Perspective 18 (2): 71–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timur. 2005. “Why the Islamic Middle East Did Not Generate an Indigenous Corporate Law.” Memo, University of Southern California
Kydland, Finn E., and Prescott, Edward C.. 1977. “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans.” Journal of Political Economy 85 (3): 473–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lal, Deepak. 1998. Unintended Consequences: The Impact of Endowments, Culture, and Politics on Long-Run Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Landa, Janet T. 1978. “The Economics of the Ethnically Homogeneous Chinese Middleman Group: A Property Rights–Public Choice Approach.” Ph.D. diss., Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University
Landa, Janet T. 1988. “A Theory of the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: Beyond Markets and Hierarchies.” Working paper, Hoover Institution, Stanford University
Lane, Frederic C. 1944. “Family Partnerships and Joint Ventures in the Venetian Republic.” Journal of Economic History 4: 178–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, Frederic C. 1973. Venice: A Maritime Republic. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University PressGoogle Scholar
Lanfranco Scriba. 1202–26. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). In Krueger, H. C. and Reynolds, R. L. (eds.), Notai Liguri Del Sec. Ⅻ e Del ⅫI. Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia Patria, 1952–4Google Scholar
Langum, David J. 1987. Law and Community on the Mexican California Frontier: Anglo-American Expatriates and the Clash of Legal Traditions, 1821–1846. Norman: University of Oklahoma PressGoogle Scholar
Lapidus, Ira M. 1984. Muslim Cities in the Later Middle Ages. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lapidus, Ira M. 1989. A History of Islamic Societies. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lau, Lawrence J., Qian, Yingyi, and Roland, Gérard. 2000. “Reform without Losers: An Interpretation of China's Dual-Track Approach to Transition.” Journal of Political Economy 108 (1): 120–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1988. On Rules and Revenues. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 1997. Consent, Dissent, and Patriotism. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levi, Margaret. 2004. “An Analytic Narrative Approach to Puzzles and Problems.” In Shapiro, Ian, Smith, Rogers, and Masoud, Tarek (eds.), Problems and Methods in the Study of Politics, 201–26. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levin, Jonathan. 2003. “Relational Incentive Contracts.” American Economic Review 93 (3): 835–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Daryl J. 2003. “Collective Sanctions.” Stanford Law Review 56 (253): 345–428Google Scholar
Lewis, Archibald R. 1951. Naval Power and Trade in the Mediterranean, A. D. 500–1100. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1982. The Muslim Discovery of Europe. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1990. Race and Slavery in the Middle East. Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, Bernard. 1991. The Political Language of Islam. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. 1969. Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Li, Shuhe. 1999. “The Benefits and Costs of Relation-Based Governance: An Explanation of the East Asian Miracle and Crisis.” Memo, City University of Hong Kong
Lieber, A. E. 1968. “Eastern Business Practices and Medieval Europe Commerce.” Economic History Review 21: 230–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar. 1997. “Incentives and Social Norms in Household Behavior.” American Economic Review 87 (2): 370–7Google Scholar
Lisciandrelli, Pasquale. 1960. “Trattati e negoziazioni politiche della Repubblica di Genova (958–1797).” Atti della Societa Ligure de Storia Patria, n.s., 1 (old series, 75). Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Lloyd, T. H. 1991. England and the German Hansa, 1157–1611. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewsenstein, George, Bazerman, Max, and Thomson, Leigh. 1989. “Social Utility and Decision Making in Interpersonal Context.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 426–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1937. “Aux origines du capitalisme gènois.” Annales d'Histoire Economique et Sociale 47: 429–54Google Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1938. Storia delle colonie genovesi nel Mediterraneo. Bologna: Nicola ZanichelliGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1943. “European Merchants in the Medieval Indies: The Evidence of Commercial Documents.” Journal of Economic History 3 (1): 164–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1952. “The Trade of Medieval Europe in the South.” In Postan, M. M. and Miller, E. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 2: 257–354. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1954. “Concerning Surnames and Places of Origin.” Medievalia et Humanistica 8: 6–16Google Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1967. The Birth of Europe. Trans. J. M. Dent & Sons. London: M. EvansGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino. 1976. The Commercial Revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lopez, Robert Sabatino, and Raymond, I. W.. 1955. Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World. New York: Columbia University PressGoogle Scholar
Luzzatto, Gino. 1961. An Economic History of Italy: From the Fall of the Roman Empire to the Beginning of the Sixteenth Century. Trans. Philip Jones. London: Routledge & K. PaulGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, Stewart, 1963. “Noncontractual Relations in Business: A Preliminary Study.” American Sociological Review 28: 55–70CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macfarlane, Alan. 1978. The Origins of English Individualism. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Machiavelli, Niccolò. 1990 [1532]. Florentine Histories (also known as History of Florence). Introd. Harvey C. Mansfield Jr. Trans. Laura F. Banfield and Harvey C. Mansfield Jr. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
MacLeod, W. Bentley, and Malcomson, James M.. 1989. “Implicit Contracts, Incentive Compatibility, and Involuntary Unemployment.” Econometrica 57 (2): 447–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macy, Michael W. 1997. “Identity, Interest and Emergent Rationality – an Evolutionary Synthesis.” Rationality and Society 9 (4): 427–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maggi, Giovanni. 1999. “The Role of Multilateral Institutions in International Trade Cooperation.” American Economic Review 89 (1): 190–214CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2000. “Path Dependence in Historical Sociology.” Theory and Society 29 (4): 507–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maimonides, Moshe. 1951. Mishne Torah. Vol. 12. Trans. I. Klein. New Haven: Yale Judaica SeriesGoogle Scholar
Maimonides, Moshe. 1957. Responda (in Judeo-Arabic and Hebrew). Ed. Blau, J.. JerusalemGoogle Scholar
Maitland, Frederick William (ed.). 1889. Select Pleas in Manorial and Other Seigniorial Courts, Reigns of Henry III and Edward I. Vol. 2. London: Seldon Society PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Maitland, Frederick William, and Bateson, Mary. 1901. The Charters of the Borough of Cambridge. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mann, Jacob. 1919. “Responsa of the Babylonian Geonim as a Source of Jewish History.” Jewish Quarterly Review 20: 139–72, 309–65Google Scholar
Mann, Jacob. 1970. The Jews in Egypt and in Palestine under the Fatimid Caliphs. Vol. 2. New York: Katav Publishing HouseGoogle Scholar
Mantzavinos, Chris. 2001. Individual, Institutions and Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, G. James, and Olsen, Johan P.. 1989. Rediscovering Institution: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Margolis, Howard. 1987. Pattern, Thinking, and Cognition: A Theory of Judgement. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Margolis, Howard. 1994. Paradigms and Barriers: How Habits of Mind Govern Scientific Beliefs. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Marimon, Ramon. 1997. “Learning from Learning in Economics.” In Kreps, David M. and Wallis, Kenneth F. (eds.), Advances in Economic Theory, 1: 278–315. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Marin, Dalia, and Schnitzer, Monika. 1995. “Tying Trade Flows: A Theory of Countertrade with Evidence.” American Economic Review 85 (5): 1047–64Google Scholar
Martines, Lauro (ed.). 1972. Violence and Civil Disorder in Italian Cities, 1200–1500. UCLA Center for Medieval and Renaissance Studies. Los Angeles: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Maurer, Noel, and Sharma, T.. 2002. “Enforcing Property Rights through Reputation: Mexico's Early Industrialization, 1878–1913.” Journal of Economic History 61 (4): 950–73Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Palfrey, Thomas. 1992. “An Experimental Study of the Centipede Game.” Econometrica 60 (July): 803–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John. 2002. Reinventing the Bazar: A Natural History of Markets. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 1999. “Interfirm Relationships and Informal Credit in Vietnam.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4): 1285–1320CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, John, and Woodruff, Christopher. 2000. “Private Order under Dysfunctional Public Order.” Michigan Law Review 98: 2421–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mead, George Herbert. 1967 [1934]. Mind, Self, and Society: From the Standpoint of a Social Behaviorist. Ed. Morris, Charles W.. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1871 [1976]. Principles of Economics. New York: New York University PressGoogle Scholar
Meyer, J. W., and B. Rowen. 1991. “Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and Ceremony.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 41–62. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Michael, Murad. 1965. “The Archives of Naharay ben Nissim, Businessman and Public Figure in Eleventh Century Egypt” (in Hebrew and Arabic). Ph.D. diss., Hebrew University, Jerusalem
Milgrom, Paul, North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1990. “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Medieval Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics 1 (March), 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, Qian, Yingyi, and Roberts, John. 1991. “Complementarities, Momentum, and the Evolution of Modern Manufacturing.” American Economic Review 81 (2): 84–8Google Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Roberts, John. 1982. “Predation, Reputation, and Entry Deterrence.” Journal of Economic Theory 27 (2): 280–312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1990. “Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities.” Econometrica 58 (6): 1255–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1992. Economics, Organization and Management. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul and Roberts, John. 1995. “Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, Structure, and Organizational Change in Manufacturing.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 19 (2–3): 179–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, Paul, and Shannon, Chris. 1994. “Monotone Comparative Statics.” Econometrica 62 (1): 157–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, Gary J. 1993. Managerial Dilemmas: The Political Economy of Hierarchy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, C. Wesley. 1925. “Quantitative Analysis in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 15 (1): 1–12Google Scholar
Mitterauer, Michael, and Sieder, Reinhard. 1982. The European Family. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mokyr, Joel. 1990. The Lever of Riches. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gift of Athena. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Moore, Ellen Wedemeyer. 1985. The Fairs of Medieval England. Toronto: Pontifical Institute of Medieval StudiesGoogle Scholar
Moriguchi, Chiaki. 1998. “Evolution of Employment Systems in the US and Japan: 1900–60. A Comparative Historical Analysis.” Unpublished manuscript, Stanford University
Morris, Colin. 1972. The Discovery of the Individual, 1050–1200. London: S. P. C. K. for the Church Historical SocietyGoogle Scholar
Moser, Peter. 2000. The Political Economy of Democratic Institutions. Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Munck, Gerardo L. 2001. “Game Theory and Comparative Politics.” World Politics 53 (Jan.): 173–204CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munz, Peter. 1969. Frederick Barbarossa. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University PressGoogle Scholar
Muthoo, Abhinay, and Kenneth A. Shepsle. 2003. “Agenda-Setting Power in Organizations with Overlapping Generations of Players.” Typescript, Harvard University
Nee, Victor, and Paul Ingram. 1998. “Embeddedness and Beyond: Institutions, Exchange and Social Structure.” In Brinton, M. and Nee, V. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Sociology, 19–45. New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Philip. 1974. “Advertising as Information.” Journal of Political Economy 82 (4): 729–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. 1994. “The Co-evolution of Technology, Industrial Structure, and Supporting Institutions.” Industrial and Corporate Change 3: 47–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. 1995. “Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change.” Journal of Economic Literature 33 (1): 48–90Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R., and Winter, Sidney G.. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1991. “Institutions.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1993. “Institutions and Credible Commitment.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 (1): 11–23Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 2005. Understanding the Process of Institutional Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Thomas, Robert P.. 1973. The Rise of the Western World. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of Economic History 49: 803–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norwich, John Julius. 1989. History of Venice. New York: Random HouseGoogle Scholar
Obertus Scriba de Mercato. 1186, 1190. Cartolare (in Latin and Italian). Ed. Chiaudano, R. Mario and Rocca, Morozzo Della. Documenti, Ⅺ and XVI. Turin: Editrice Libraria Italiana, 1940Google Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji. 2005. “The Role of the Merchant Coalition in Pre-modern Japanese Economic Development: An Historical Institutional Analysis.” Explorations in Economic History 42 (2): 184–201CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okazaki, Tetsuji, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara. 1998. “Evolution of Economic Systems: The Case of Japan.” In Hayami, Y. and Aoki, Masahiko (eds.), The Institutional Foundation of Economic Development in East Asia, 482–521. London: MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, and Andrew Postlewaite. 1990. “Social Norms and Random Matching Games.” CARESS Working Paper #90–18, University of Pennsylvania
Olivieri, Agostino. 1861. Serie dei consoli del comune di Genova. Genoa: Forni Editore Bologna. Originally published in Atti della Ligure di Storia Patria 1 (1858): 155–479Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political Science Review 87 (3): 567–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. “A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action.” American Political Science Review 92 (1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otto of Freising and His Continuator. 1152–8. The Deeds of Frederick Barbarossa. Translated and annotated by Charles Christopher Mierow with collaboration of Richard Emery. New York: Columbia University Press, 1953
Pagano, Ugo, and Maria Alessandra Rossi. 2002. “Incomplete Contracts, Intellectual Property and Institutional Complementarities.” Memo, University of Siena
Pamuk, Şevket. 2000. A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Parker, Geoffrey. 1990. The Military Revolution (1500–1800). Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. London: Routledge and Kegan PaulGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott. 1990. “Prologomena to a Theory of Social Institutions.” American Sociological Review 55 (3): 319–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patourel, J. H.. 1937. Medieval Administration of the Channel Islands, 1199–1399. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Pearce, David G. 1984. “Rationalizable Strategic Behavior and the Problem of Perfection.” Econometrica 52 (4): 1029–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearce, David G. 1987. “Renegotiation-Proof Equilibria: Collective Rationality and Intertemporal Cooperation.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Yale University
Pearce, David G. 1995. “Repeated Games: Cooperation and Rationality.” In Laffont, Jean-Jacques (ed.), Advances in Economic Theory, 1: 132–74. Sixth World Congress. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Persson, Karl Gunnar. 1988. Pre-industrial Economic Growth, Social Organization, and Technological Progress in Europe. New York: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Pertile, Antonio. 1966. Storia del diritto italiano dalla caduta dell'Impero Romano alla codificazione. 2nd ed. 2 vols. Bologna: Arnaldo Forni EditoreGoogle Scholar
Peters, Guy. 1996. “Political Institutions, Old and New.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 205–20. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review 94 (2): 251–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul, and Theda Skocpol. 2002. “Historical Institutionalism in Contemporary Political Science.” In Katznelson, Ira and Milner, Helen V. (eds.), Political Science: State of the Discipline, 693–721. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1939. Mohammed and Charlemagne. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Pirenne, Henri. 1956. A History of Europe. New York: University BooksGoogle Scholar
Planitz, H. 1919. “Studien zur Geschichte des Deutschen Arrestprozesses, II. Kapital, der Fremdenarrest.” Zeitschrift de Savigny-Stifung fuer Rechtsgeschichte (Germanistische Abteilung) 40: 87–198Google Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 1994. “Behind the Market Stage Where Real Societies Exist. Part II: The Role of Moral Norms.” Journal of Development Studies 30 (3): 753–817CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe. 2000. Institutions, Social Norms and Economic Development. Amsterdam: Harwood Academic PublishersGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J. P., and Gaspart, F.. 2003. “The Risk of Resource Misappropriation in Community-Driven Development.” World Development 31 (10): 1687–1703CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, Jean-Philippe, and Y. Hayami. 1998. “Resource Endowments and Agricultural Development: Africa versus Asia.” In Aoki, M., and Hayami, Y. (eds.), The Institutional Foundations of East Asian Economic Development, 357–410. London: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Plucknett, Theodore Frank Thomas. 1949. Legislation of Edward I. Oxford: ClarendonGoogle Scholar
Pollock, Frederick, and Maitland, Frederic William. 1968. The History of the English Law before the Time of Edward I. 2nd ed. 2 vols. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Pomeranz, Kenneth. 2000. The Great Divergence: China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. A. 1997. “Social Norms and the Law: An Economic Approach.” Papers and Proceedings from the 104th Meeting of the American Economic Association. American Economic Review 87 (2): 333–8Google Scholar
Postan, Michael M. 1973. Medieval Trade and Finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pounds, Norman John Greville. 1994. An Economic History of Medieval Europe. 2nd ed. New York: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1993. “Guns, Butter, and Anarchy.” American Political Science Review 87 (1): 115–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Powell, Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power: States and Strategies in International Politics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Powell, W., and DiMaggio, P. (eds.). 1991. The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Poznanski, S. 1904. “Ephraim ben Schemria de Fustat” (in French and Hebrew). Revue des Etudes Juives 48: 146–75Google Scholar
Pryor, F. L. 1977. The Origins of the Economy: A Comparative Study of Distribution and Peasant Economies. New York: Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Pryor, John. 1988. Geography, Technology, and War. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 1991. Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1993. Making Democracy Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone. New York: Simon and SchusterCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1993. “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics.” American Economic Review 83 (5): 1281–1302Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1994. “Cognitive Dissonance and Social Change.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 23 (2): 177–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, Matthew. 1998. “Psychology and Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 36 (1): 11–46Google Scholar
Rahman, Fazlur. 2002. Islam. 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Rapoport, Amnon. 1997. “Order of Play in Strategically Equivalent Games in Extensive Form.” International Journal of Game Theory 26 (1): 113–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashdal, Hastings. 1936. The Universities of Europe in the Middle Ages. Vol. 1. Ed. Powicke, F. M. and Emden, A. B.. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rauch, J. E. 2001. “Business and Social Networks in International Trade.” Journal of Economic Literature 39 (Dec.): 1177–1203CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Razi, Zevi. 1993. “The Myth of the Immutable English Family.” Past & Present 140 (Aug.): 3–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey, E. 1895. “Les seigneurs de giblet.” Revue de l'Orient Latin 3:398–422. Paris: Presses Universitaires de FranceGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Charles H., and Norman, Ralph V., eds. 1988. Community in America. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1929. “The Market for Northern Textiles in Genoa 1179–1200.” Revue Belge Philologie et d'Historie 8: 831–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1930. “Merchants of Arras and the Overland Trade with Genoa in the Twelfth Century.” Revue Belge Philologie et d'Histoirie 9: 495–533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert L. 1931. “Genoese Trade in the Late Twelfth Century, Particularly in Cloth from the Fair of Champagne.” Journal of Economic and Business History 3: 362–81Google Scholar
Richardson, Gary. 2002. “Craft Guilds and Christianity in Late-Medieval England: A Rational-Choice Analysis.” Memo, University of California, Irvine
Riker, William. 1964. Federalism: Origins, Operations, and Significance. Boston: Little BrownGoogle Scholar
Rippin, Andrew. 1994. Muslims: Their Religious Beliefs and Practices. Vol. 1: The Formative Period. Reprint, London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani. 2003. “Growth Strategies.” Memo, Harvard University. [Forthcoming in The Handbook of Economic Growth.]
Rodrik, Dani, Arvind Subramanian, and Francesco Trebbi. 2003. “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development.” Memo, Harvard University
Roland, Gérard. 2000. Transitions and Economics: Politics, Markets, and Firms. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Romer, Paul. 1996. “Preferences, Promises, and the Politics of Entitlement.” In Fuchs, Victor R. (ed.), The Individual and Social Responsibility, 195–220. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1989. “Tying the King's Hands: Credible Commitments and Royal Fiscal Policy during the Old Regime.” Rationality and Society 1 (Oct.): 240–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Root, Hilton L. 1994. The Fountain of Privilege: Political Foundations of Markets in Old Regime France and Englands. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Rorig, Fritz. 1967. The Medieval Town. Berkeley: University of California PressGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan. 1982. Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Rosenberg, Nathan, and Birdzell, L. E. Jr. 1986. How the West Grew Rich. New York: Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Rosenthal, Jean-Laurent. 1992. The Fruits of Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, and Nisbett, Richard E.. 1991. The Person and the Situation. Boston: McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Rossetti, G., Pratesi, M. C., Garzella, G., Guzzardi, M. B., Guglie, G., and Sturmann, C.. 1979. Pisa nei secoli Ⅺ e Ⅻ: Formazione e caratteri di una classe di governo. Pisa: Pacini EditoreGoogle Scholar
Roth, Alvin E., Prasnikar, Vesna, Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, and Zamir, Shmuel. 1991. “Bargaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An Experimental Study.” American Economic Review 81 (5): 1068–95Google Scholar
Roth, Alvin E., and Erev, I.. 1995. “Learning in Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and Simple Dynamic Models in Intermediate Term.” Games and Economic Behavior, special issue: Nobel Symposium, 8: 164–212CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothstein, Bo. 1996. “Political Institutions: An Overview.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 133–66. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1991. “Comments on the Interpretation of Game Theory.” Econometrica 59 (4): 909–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1998. Modeling Bounded Rationality. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Sachs, Jefrey D. 2001. “Tropical Underdevelopment.” NBER Working Paper No. 8119
Salzman, L. F. 1928. “A Riot at Boston Fair.” History Teachers' Miscellany 6: 2–3Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1993. “Altruism as a Problem Involving Group versus Individual Selection in Economics and Biology.” American Economic Review 83 (2): 143–8Google Scholar
Santini, Pietro. 1886. “Appunti sulla vendetta privata e sulle rappresaglie.” Archivo Strico Italiano 18: 162–76Google Scholar
Saunders, J. J. 1965. A History of Medieval Islam. New York: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley & SonsGoogle Scholar
Schacht, Joseph. 1982 [1964]. An Introduction to Islamic Law. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, F. W. 1997. Games Real Actors Play. Boulder, CO: WestviewGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schneider, G., Plumper, T., and Baumann, S., 2000. “Bringing Putnam to the European Regions – on the Relevance of Social Capital for Economic Growth.” European Urban and Regional Studies 7 (4): 307–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, Andrew. 1981. The Economic Theory of Social Institutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumann, Reinhold. 1992. Italy in the Last Fifteen Hundred Years. 2nd ed. Lanham, MD: University Press of AmericaGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 1998. Organizations: Rational, Natural, and Open Systems. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard. 1995. Institutions and Organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Scott, W. Richard, Meyer, John W., et al. 1994. Institutional Environments and Organizations. London: Sage PublicationsGoogle Scholar
Searle, John R. 1995. The Construction of Social Reality. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ilya. 1999. “Complexity and Renegotiation: A Foundation for Incomplete Contracts.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 57–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ronald. 2001. Islam's Black Slaves. New York: Farrar, Straus and GirouxGoogle Scholar
Segal, Uzi, and Joel Sobel. 2000. “Tit for Tat: Foundations of Preferences for Reciprocity in Strategic Settings.” Memo, University of California, San Diego
Select Cases Concerning the Law Merchant, A. D. 1270–1638. Vol. 1: Local Courts. 1908. Ed. Gross, Charles. Selden Society Publications, 23. London: B. QuaritchGoogle Scholar
Select Cases Concerning the Law Merchant, A. D. 1239–1633. Vol. 2: Central Courts. 1930. Ed. Hall, H.. Selden Society Publications, 46. London: B. QuaritchGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. 1995. “Moral Codes and Economic Success.” In Brittan, Samuel and Hamlin, Alan P. (eds.), Market Capitalism and Moral Values. Aldershot: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Sened, Itai. 1997. The Political Institution of Private Property. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Sewell, William H. 1992. “A Theory of Structure: Duality, Agency, and Transformation.” American Journal of Sociology 98 (1): 1–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Carl. 1983. “Premiums for High Quality Products as Return to Reputation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (4): 659–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, C., and Stiglitz, J. E.. 1984. “Equilibrium Unemployment as a Worker Discipline Device.” American Economic Review 74 (3): 433–44Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23: 27–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1992. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Weisberg, H. F. (ed.), Political Science: The Science of Politics, 51–82. New York: Agathon PressGoogle Scholar
Shirley, Mary M. 2004. “Institutions and Development.” In Menard, Claude and Shirley, Mary M. (eds.), Handbook on New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer PressGoogle Scholar
Shiue, Carol H., and Wolfgang Keller. 2003. “Markets in China and Europe on the Eve of the Industrial Revolution.” Memo, University of Texas
Sieveking, Heinrich. 1898–9. Genueser Finanzwesen mit Besonderer Berücksichtigung de Casa di S. Giorgio. 2 vols. Leipzig: Freiburg
Simon, Herbert A. 1955. “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99–118CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1976. Administrative Behavior. 3rd ed. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1987 [1957]. Model of Man, Social and Rational. New York: John WileyGoogle Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 1992. “Cooperation, Conflict, and Power in the Absence of Property Rights.” American Economic Review 84 (4): 720–39Google Scholar
Skaperdas, Stergios. 1996. “Contest Success Functions.” Economic Theory 7: 283–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smelser, Neil, and Richard Swedberg. 1994. “The Sociological Perspective on the Economy.” In Smelser, N. and Swedberg, R. (eds.), The Handbook of Economic Sociology, 3–26. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press; New York: Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Sobel, Joel. 2002. “Can We Trust Social Capital?Journal of Economic Literature 40 (March): 139–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sonn, Tamara. 1990. Between Qur'an and Crown. Boulder, CO: Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Spruyt, Hendrik. 1994. The Sovereign State and Its Competitors. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Staiger, Robert. 1995. “International Rules and Institutions for Trade Policy.” In Grossman, Gene M. and Rogoff, Kenneth (eds.), The Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3, chap. 29. North Holland: Elsevier Science PublishersGoogle Scholar
Stark, R. 1996. The Rise of Christianity: A Sociologist Reconsiders History. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Stein, Peter. 1999. Roman Law in European History. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, Hamish. 1992. “Rationality and the Market for Human Blood.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1 (2): 125–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. 1994. Whither Socialism? Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Stillman, Norman Arthur. 1970. “East-West Relations in the Islamic Mediterranean in the Early Eleventh Century.” Ph.D. diss., University of Pennsylvania
Stinchcombe, Arthur L. 1968. Constructing Social Theories. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Stubbs, W. (ed.). 1913. Selected Charters and Other Illustrations of English Institutional History from the Earliest Times to the Reign of Edward the First. 9th ed. Oxford: ClarendonGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1986. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare. Oxford: Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1989. “Spontaneous Order.” Journal of Economic Perspective 3 (4): 85–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sutton, John. 1991. Sunk Costs and Market Structure: Price Competition, Advertising, and the Evolution of Concentration. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Swidler, Ann. 1986. “Culture in Action.” American Sociological Review 51 (Apr.): 273–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tabacco, Giovanni. 1989. The Struggle for Power in Medieval Italy. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steve. 1999. “What's in a Name? Reputation as a Tradeable Asset.” Economic Review 89 (3): 548–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tadelis, Steve. 2002. “The Market for Reputations as an Incentive Mechanism.” Journal of Political Economy 110 (4): 854–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Telser, L. G. 1980. “A Theory of Self-Enforcing Agreements.” Journal of Business 53: 27–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 2 (June): 369–404CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, H. 1977. “Beitraege zur Geschichte der Champagne-Messen im 14. Jahrhundert.” Vierteljahrschrift fuer Sozial-und Wietschaftsgeschichte 64 (4): 433–67Google Scholar
Thrupp, Sylvia L. 1965. “The Gilds.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3: 230–79. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1992. Cambridge, MA: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean. 1996. “A Theory of Collective Reputation (with Applications to the Persistence of Corruption and to Firm Quality).” Review of Economic Studies 63 (1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tooby, John, and Leda Cosmides. 1992. “The Psychological Foundations of Culture.” In Barkow, Jerome H., Cosmides, Leda, and Tooby, John (eds.), The Adapted Mind: Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, 19–136. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Topiks, D. 1998. Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Townsend, Robert M. 1979. “Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification.” Journal of Economic Theory 21 (2): 265–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trackman, Leon E. 1983. The Law Merchant: The Evolution of Commercial Law. Littleton, CO: Fred B. RothmanGoogle Scholar
Triandis, Harry C. 1990. “Cross-Cultural Studies of Individualism and Collectivism.” In Berman, J. (ed.), Nebraska Symposium on Motivation, 1989, 41–133. Lincoln: University of Nebraska PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. 1981. “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” Science 211: 453–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Udovitch, Abraham L. 1962. “At the Origins of Western Commenda: Islam, Israel, Byzantium.” Speculum 37: 198–207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Udovitch, Abraham L. 1970. Partnership and Profit in Medieval Islam. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ullmann-Margalit, Edna. 1977. The Emergence of Norms. Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Damme, Eric. 1983. Refinements of the Nash Equilibrium Concept. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damme, Eric. 1987. Stability and Perfection of Nash Equilibria. Berlin: Springer-VerlagCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van der Vee, Herman. 1977. “Monetary, Credit, and Banking Systems.” In Rich, E. E. and Wilson, C. H. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 5: 290–391. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H. R. 1990. “Monitoring Agents with Other Agents.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 146 (1): 153–74Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Vecchio, A. del, and Casanova, E.. 1894. Le rappresaglie nei comuni medievali e specialmente in Firenze. Bologna: R. ForniGoogle Scholar
Verlinden, C. 1979. “Markets and Fairs.” In Postan, M. M., Rick, E. E., and Miltey, M. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, 3: 119–53. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Vitale, V. 1951. Il comune del podestà a Genova. Milan: RicciardiGoogle Scholar
Vitale, V. 1955. Breviario della storia di Genova. 2 vols. Genoa: Societa Ligure di Storia PatriaGoogle Scholar
Volckart, Oliver. 2001. “The Economics of Feuding in Late Medieval Germany.” Working paper, Institut fur Wirtschaftsgeschichte, Berlin
Wach, A. 1868. Der Arrestprozess in seiner geschichtlichen Entwicklung. 1. Teil: De Italienische Arrestprozess. Leipzig: HaesselGoogle Scholar
Waley, Daniel. 1988. The Italian City-Republics. 3rd ed. London: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Watson, Joel. 1999. “Starting Small and Renegotiation.” Journal of Economic Theory 85 (1): 52–90CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watson, Joel. 2001. Strategy: An Introduction to Game Theory. New York: NortonGoogle Scholar
Watt, Montgomery W. 1961. Muhammad: Prophet and Statesman. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Watt, Montgomery W. 1987. The Influence of Islam on Medieval Europe. Edinburgh: At the University PressGoogle Scholar
Watts, R. W., and Zimmermann, J. L.. 1983. “Agency Problems, Auditing and the Theory of the Firm: Some Evidence.” Journal of Law and Economics 26 (Oct.): 613–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. 1947. The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. Reprint, New York: Free Press, 1964Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1949. The Methodology of the Social Sciences. Glencoe, IL: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. 1958 [1904–5]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York: Charles Scribner's SonsGoogle Scholar
Weibull, Jörgen. 1995. Evolutionary Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Weiner, A. 1932. “The Hansa.” In Tanner, J. R., Previté-Orton, C. W., and Brooke, Z. N. (eds.), The Cambridge Medieval History, 7: 216–69. Cambridge: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1993. “Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secured Markets.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 149 (1): 286–311Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1995. “Institutions and Political Commitment: A New Political Economy of the American Civil War Era.” Memo, Stanford University
Weingast, Barry R. 1996. “Political Institutions: Rational Choice Perspectives.” In Goodin, Robert and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (eds.), A New Handbook of Political Science, 167–90. New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1997. “The Political Foundations of Democracy and the Rule of Law.” American Political Science Review 91 (2): 245–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, B., and Marshall, W.. 1988. “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 96 (1): 132–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Lynn. 1964. The Medieval Technology and Social Change. London: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Wiessner, Polly. 2002. “Hunting, Healing, and Hxaro Exchange. A Long-Term Perspective on!Kung (Ju/'hoansi) Large-Game Hunting.” Evolution and Human Behavior 23: 407–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Dean V. 2002. “Transparency and Contract Selection: Evidence from the Financing of Trade in Venetian Crete, 1303–1351.” Memo, U.S. Department of Justice
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analyses and Antitrust Implications. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1993. “Transaction Cost Economics and Organization Theory.” Industrial and Corporate Change 2 (2): 107–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1998. “Transaction Cost Economics: How It Works; Where It Is Headed.” De Economist 146 (1): 23–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2000. “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead.” Journal of Economic Literature 38 (Sept.): 595–613CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Edward O. 1975. Sociobiology. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press, Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich. 1986. “Evolution and Stability of Cooperation without Enforceable Contracts.” Kyklos 39, fasc. 2: 245–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woolcock, Michael. 1998. “Social Capital and Economic Development: Toward a Theoretical Synthesis and Policy Framework.” Theory and Society 27 (2): 151–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Mark. 2002. “Reputations and Sovereign Debt.” Working paper, Stanford University
Wrong, Dennis H. 1961. “The Oversocialized Conception of Man in Modern Sociology.” American Sociological Review 26 (2): 183–93. Reprinted as chapter 2 in Dennis H. Wrong, The Oversocialized Conception of Man (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 1999)
Wrong, Dennis H. 1999. The Oversocialized Conception of Man. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction PublishersGoogle Scholar
Yang Li, Mu. 2002. “Essays on Public Finance and Economic Development in a Historical Institutional Perspective.” Ph.D. diss., Stanford University
Young, H. Peyton. 1993. “The Evolution of Conventions.” Econometrica 61 (1): 57–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Peyton. 1998. Individual Strategy and Social Structure. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Peyton, and Burke, Mary A.. 2001. “Competition and Custom in Economic Contracts: A Case Study of Illinois Agriculture.” American Economic Review 91 (3): 559–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, Paul J., and Knack, Stephen. 2001. “Trust and Growth.” Economic Journal 111 (470): 295–321CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zhang, Jiajie. 1997. “Nature of External Representations in Problem Solving.” Cognitive Science 21 (2): 179–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zucker, L. G. 1983. “Organizations as Institutions.” In Bacharach, S. B. (ed.), Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 1–42. Greenwich, CT: JAIGoogle Scholar
Zucker, L. G. 1991. “The Role of Institutionalization in Cultural Persistence.” In Powell, W. and DiMaggio, P. (eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, 83–107. Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Avner Greif, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy
  • Online publication: 05 September 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511791307.020
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Avner Greif, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy
  • Online publication: 05 September 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511791307.020
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Avner Greif, Stanford University, California
  • Book: Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy
  • Online publication: 05 September 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511791307.020
Available formats
×