Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-20T23:14:35.352Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 December 2009

Benedetto Gui
Affiliation:
Università degli Studi di Padova, Italy
Robert Sugden
Affiliation:
University of East Anglia
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Economics and Social Interaction
Accounting for Interpersonal Relations
, pp. 271 - 294
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abrams, Burton A., and Schmitz, Mark D. 1984. ‘The crowding out effect of government transfers on private charitable contributions: cross-sectional evidence’, National Tax Journal 37: 563–8.Google Scholar
Adam, J. S. 1963. ‘Wage inequalities, productivity, and work quality’, Industrial Relations 3: 9–16.Google Scholar
Adam, J. S.1965. ‘Inequity in social exchange’, in Berkowitz, (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Adam, J. S., and Rosenbaum, W. E. 1964. ‘The relationship of worker productivity to cognitive dissonance about wage inequalities’, Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 69: 19–25.Google Scholar
Adelman, Mara B., Aaron C. Ahuvia and Cathy Goodwin 1994. ‘Beyond smiling: social support and service quality’, in Rust, and Oliver, (eds.), Service Quality: New Directions in Theory and Practice. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 139–71.Google Scholar
Adelman, Mara B., Malcolm R. Parks and Terrance L. Albrecht 1987. ‘Beyond close relationships: social support and weak ties’, in Albrecht, and Adelman, (eds.), Communicating Social Support. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 126–47.
Akerlof, George A. 1982. ‘Labor contracts as partial gift exchange’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 97(4): 543–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1984. An Economic Theorist's Book of Tales. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1997. ‘Social distance and social decisions’, Econometrica 65(5):1005–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A., and Kranton, Rachel 2000. ‘Economics and identity’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3): 715–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, W. David 2000. ‘Social networks and self-employment’, Journal of Socio-Economics 29: 487–501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almond, Stephen, and Kendall, Jeremy 2000. ‘Taking the employee's perspective seriously: an initial UK cross-sectoral comparison’, Nonprofit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly 29(2): 205–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James 1988a. ‘Privately provided public goods in a large economy – the limits of altruism’, Journal of Public Economics 35: 57–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James 1988b. ‘Why free-ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments’, Journal of Public Economics 37: 291–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James 1990. ‘Impure altruism and donations to public goods: a theory of warm glow giving’, Economic Journal 100: 464–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreoni, James 1998. ‘Towards a theory of charitable fund-raising’, Journal of Political Economy 106: 1186–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antoci, Angelo 1996. Negative Externalities and Growth of the Activity Level. Report no. 9308, Ministero dell'lstruzione, dell'Università e della Ricerea research project on non-linear dynamics and application to economic and social sciences, University of Florence.Google Scholar
Antoci, Angelo, and Bartolini, Stefano 1997. Externalities and Growth in an Evolutionary Game. Discussion Paper no. 10, Department of Economics, University of Trento.Google Scholar
Antoci, Angelo and Bartolini, Stefano 2004. ‘Negative externalities, defensive expenditures and labour supply in an evolutionary context’, Environment and Development Economics 9(5): 591–612CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antoci, Angelo, Pier Luigi Sacco and Paolo Vanin 2002. Participation, Growth and Social Poverty: Social Capital in a Homogeneous Society. Paper presented at the 54th International Atlantic Economic Society in Washington, DC, 12 October.
Antoci, Angelo, Pier Luigi Sacco and Paolo Vanin2005. ‘Social capital accumulation and the evolution of social participation’, Journal of socio-Economics, forthcoming.
Aoki, Masahiko 1984. The Co-operative Game Theory of the Firm. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aristotle, 1980. Nichomachean Ethics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth 1974. The Limits of Organization. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth1999. ‘Observations on social capital’, in Dasgupta, and Serageldin, (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World Bank, 3–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian 1988. ‘Self-reinforcing mechanisms in economics’, in Anderson, Arrow and Pines, (eds.), The Economy as an Evolving Complex System. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley, 9–31.Google Scholar
Arthur, W. Brian 1989. ‘Competiting technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events’, Economic Journal 99: 116–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asch, Solomon E. 1951. ‘Effects of group pressure upon the modification and distortion of judgements’, in Guetzkow, (ed.), Groups, Leadership and Men. Pittsburgh, PA: Carnegie Press.Google Scholar
Ash, Colin 2000. ‘Social self-interest’, in Gui, (ed.) Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, special issue on ‘Economics and interpersonal relations’ 71(2): 261–83.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bacharach, Michael 1993. ‘Variable universe games’, in Binmore, Kirman and Tani, (eds.), Frontiers of Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 255–75.Google Scholar
Bacharach, Michael 1999. ‘Interactive team reasoning: a contribution to the theory of cooperation’, Research in Economics 53: 117–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacharach, Michael, Guerra, Gerardo and Zizzo, Daniel 2001. Is Trust Self-Fulfilling? An Experimental Study. Mimeo, Bounded Rationality in Economic Behaviour Unit, University of Oxford.Google Scholar
Baier, Annette 1986. ‘Trust and antitrust’, Ethics 96: 231–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baier, Annette 1994. Moral Prejudices. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Baker, James 1987. ‘Trust and rationality’, Pacific Philosophical Quarterly, 68: 1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardsley, Nicholas 2000. ‘Control without deception: individual behaviour in free-riding experiments revisited’, Experimental Economics 3: 215–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barkema, Harry G. 1995. ‘Do top managers work harder when they are monitored?’, Kyklos 48: 19–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, Hans 1955. The Crisis of the Early Italian Renaissance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baron, Hans 1988. In Search of Florentine Civic Humanism: Essays on the Transitions from Medieval to Modern Thought. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, Jonathan 1998. ‘Trust: beliefs and morality’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Value and Organisation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 408–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartolini, Stefano, and Bonatti, Luigi 1997. Negative Externalities as the Cause of Growth in a Neoclassical Model. Discussion Paper no. 9, Department of Economics, University of Trento.Google Scholar
Bartolini, Stefano, and Bonatti, Luigi 2004. Social Capital and its Role in Production: Does the Depletion of Social Capital Depress Economic Growth? Quaderni di Dipartimento no. 421, Department of Economics, University of Siena.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1965. ‘A theory of the allocation of time’, Economic Journal 75(299): 493–517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1975. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1981. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1991. ‘A note on restaurant pricing and other examples of social influence on prices’, Journal of Political Economy 99(5): 1109–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1996. Accounting for Tastes. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland 1996. ‘Equity and efficiency in human capital investment: the local connection’, Review of Economic Studies 63: 237–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, Seyla 1987. ‘The generalized and the concrete other: the Kohlberg–Gilligan controversy and moral theory’, in Meyers, and Kittay, (eds.), Women and Moral Theory. Totowa, NJ: Rowman and Littlefield, 154–77.Google Scholar
Benn, Stanley 1978a. ‘The problematic rationality of political participation’, in Benn, , Political Participation. Canberra: Australian National University Press, 1–22.Google Scholar
Benn, Stanley1978b. ‘The problematic rationality of political participation: rejoinder’, in Benn, , Political Participation. Canberra: Australian National University Press, 61–8.Google Scholar
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Putterman, Louis 1998a. ‘Preface’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Values and Organisation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, xv–xxvi.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Louis Putterman 1998b. ‘Values and institutions in economic analysis’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Values and Organisation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 3–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Ner, Avner, Putterman, Louis, Kong, Fanmin and Magan, Dan 2004. ‘Reciprocity in a two-part dictator game’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 53: 333–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Porath, Yoram 1980. ‘The F-connection: families, friends, and firms and the organization of exchange’, Population and Development Review 6(1): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, Peter L., and Luckmann, Thomas 1966. The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. New York: Anchor Books.Google Scholar
Bergstrom, Theodore, Blume, Lawrence and Varian, Hal 1986. ‘On the private provision of public goods’, Journal of Public Economics 29(1): 25–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, Douglas B., and Stark, Oded 1988. ‘Altruism within the family reconsidered: do nice guys finish last?’, American Economic Review 78: 1034–45.Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirschleifer, David and Welch, Ivo 1998. ‘Learning from the behavior of others: conformity, fads, and informational cascades’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12: 151–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth G. 1992. Fun and Games. Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath.Google Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth G. 1994. Game Theory and the Social Contract. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Vol. I: Playing Fair.Google Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth G. 1998. Game Theory and the Social Contract. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, Vol. II: Just Playing.Google Scholar
Bitner, Mary J., Bernard, H. Booms and Mary, S. Tetreault 1990. ‘The service encounter: diagnosing favorable and unfavorable incidents’, Journal of Marketing 54(1): 71–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, Lawrence E., and Steven N. Durlauf 2001. ‘The interactions-based approach to socioeconomic behavior’, in Durlauf, and Young, (eds.), Social Dynamics: Economic Learning and Social Evolution. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press; Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press, Vol. IV, 15–44.
Bochet, Olivier, Talbot Page and Louis Putterman (forthcoming). ‘Communication and punishment in voluntary contribution experiments’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.
Bogart, William T., and Cromwell, Brian A. 2000. ‘How much is a neighborhood school worth?’, Journal of Urban Economics 47: 280–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, Iris, and Frey, Bruno S. 1999. ‘The sound of silence in prisoner's dilemma and dictator games’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 38(1): 43–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Gary E., and Ockenfels, Axel 1998. ‘Strategy and equity: an ERC-analysis of the Güth–van Damme game’, Journal of Mathematical Psychology 42: 215–26.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bolton, Gary E., and Ockenfels, Axel 2000. ‘ERC: a theory of equity, reciprocity and competition’, American Economic Review, 90: 166–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borjas, George J. 1995. ‘Ethnicity, neighborhoods, and human-capital externalities’, American Economic Review 85(3): 365–90.Google Scholar
Bornstein, Gary, and Ben-Yossef, Meyrav 1994. ‘Cooperation in intergroup and single group social dilemmas’, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 30: 52–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borzaga, Carlo (ed.) 2000. Capitale umano e qualità del lavoro nei servizi sociali: un'analisi comparata tra modelli di gestione. Rome: Fondazione Italiana per il Volontariato.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre 1958. Sociologie de l'Algérie. Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre 1963. ‘La société traditionnelle: attitude à l'égard du temps et conduite économique’, Sociologie du travail 1(January–March): 24–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre 1980a. ‘Le capital social’, Actes de la recherche en sciences sociales 31: 2–3.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre 1980b. Questions de sociologie. Paris: Editions de Minuit.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre 2000. Les structures sociales de l'économie. Paris: Seuil.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre, Darbel, Alain, Rivet, Jean-Pierre and Seibel, Claude 1963. Travail et travailleurs en Algérie. Paris: Editions Mouton.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre, and Sayad, Abdelmalek 1964. Le déracinement, la crise de l'agriculture traditionnelle en Algérie. Paris: Editions de Minuit.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel 1985. ‘The production process in a competitive economy: walrasian, neo-hobbesian and marxian models’, American Economic Review 75(1): 16–36.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel 1999. ‘“Social capital” and community governance’, Focus 20(3): 6–10.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, Carpenter, Jeffrey and Gintis, Herbert 2001. Mutual Monitoring in Teams: The Effects of Residual Claimancy and Reciprocity. Working paper, Middlebury College, Middlebury, Vermont.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert 1988. ‘Contested exchange: political economy and modern economic theory’, American Economic Review 78(2): 145–50.Google Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert 1990. ‘Contested exchange: new microfoundations for the political economy of capitalism’, Politics and Society 18(2): 165–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert 1993. ‘The revenge of Homo economicus: contested exchange and the revival of political economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(1): 83–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert 2000. ‘Walrasian economics in retrospect’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(4): 1411–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braithwaite, Valerie, and Levi, Margaret (eds.) 2002. Trust and Governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.Google Scholar
Brandts, Jordi, and Schram, Arthur 2001. ‘Cooperation and noise in public goods experiments: applying the contribution function approach’, Journal of Public Economics 79: 399–427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey 1996. ‘Selection and the currency of reward’, in Goodin, (ed.), The Theory of Institutional Design. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 256–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Lomasky, Loren 1985. ‘The impartial spectator goes to Washington’, Economics and Philosophy 1: 189–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey, and Pettit, Philip 2000. ‘The hidden economy of esteem’, Economics and Philosophy 16: 77–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Marilyn B. 1989. ‘Ambivalent sociality: the human condition’, Behavioural and Brain Sciences 12: 699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, Marilyn B., and Kramer, Roderick M. 1984. ‘Effects of group identity on resource use in a simulated Commons dilemma’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 46: 1044–57.Google Scholar
Brewer, Marilyn B., and Kramer, Roderick M. 1986. ‘Choice behaviour in social dilemmas: effects of social identity, group size and decision framing’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 50: 543–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brosig, Jeannette, Weimann, Joachim and Ockenfels, Axel 2003. ‘The effect of communication media on cooperation’, German Economic Review 4(2): 217–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, Luigino 2002. Vilfredo Pareto and the Birth of the Modern Microeconomics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruni, Luigino, and Guala, Francesco 2001. ‘Pareto and the epistemological foundations of rational choice’, History of Political Economy 33: 21–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryan, James H., and Test, Mary A. 1967. ‘Models and helping: naturalistic studies in aiding behaviour’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 6: 400–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burlando, Roberto, and Hey, John D. 1997. ‘Do Anglo-Saxons free-ride more?’, Journal of Public Economics 64: 41–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin 2003. Behavioral Game Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cancian, Francesca M. 1975. What are Norms?Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cartwright, Nancy 1999. The Dappled World: A Study of the Boundaries of Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casson, Mark 1991. The Economics of Business Culture. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Catterall, Miriam, Maclaran, Pauline and Stevens, Lorna 2000. Marketing and Feminism: Current Issues and Research. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cauley, Jon, and Sandler, Todd 1980. ‘A general theory of interpersonal exchange’, Public Choice 35: 587–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Center for Career Development in Early Care and Education 2000. Briefing Booklet: Advance Reading for Sept. 14, 2000. Wheelock College, Boston.
Cetina, Karin Knorr, and Bruegger, Urs 2002. ‘Global microstructures: the virtual societies of financial markets’, American Journal of Sociology 107(4): 905–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chadwick-Jones, John K. 1986. ‘Social exchange, social psychology and economics’, in MacFadyen, and MacFadyen, (eds.), Economic Psychology: Intersections in Theory and Applications. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 249–67.Google Scholar
Chaminade, Thierry, and Decety, Jean 2003. ‘Neural correlates of feeling sympathy’, Neuropsychologia, special issue on ‘Social cognition’ 41(2): 127–38.Google Scholar
Chillemi, Ottorino, and Gui, Benedetto 1997. ‘Team human capital and worker mobility’, Journal of Labor Economics 15(4): 567–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cialdini, Robert B. 1993. Influence: Science and Practice. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Cialdini, Robert B., Kallgren, Carl A. and Reno, Raymond R. 1991. ‘A focus theory of normative conduct’, Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 24: 201–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clotfelter, Charles T. 1985. Federal Tax Policy and Charitable Giving. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, Stephen, and Ravallion, Martin 1993. ‘Reciprocity without commitment: characterization and performance of informal insurance arrangements’, Journal of Development Economics 40(1): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, Don, and Prusak, Laurence 2001. In Good Company: How Social Capital Makes Organizations Work. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Colander, David, and Klamer, Arjo 1987. ‘The making of an economist’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 1(2): 95–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1988. ‘Social capital in the creation of human capital’, American Journal of Sociology 94(supplement): 95–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James S. 1990. Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, MA and London: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Collard, David 1978. Altruism and Economy. Oxford: Martin Robertson and Co. Ltd.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Connolly, Laura S. 1997. ‘Does external funding of academic research crowd out institutional support?’, Journal of Public Economics 64: 389–406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Connolly, Sara, and Munro, Alistair 1999. Economics of the Public Sector. London: Prentice Hall Europe.Google Scholar
Conrad, Joseph 1998 [1909]. Under Western Eyes. On-line edition: www.bibliomania.com.
Cooper, Russel, and John, Andrew 1988. ‘Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 103(3): 441–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, Giacomo 2001. Work and Television. Discussion Paper no. 376, Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.Google Scholar
Corneo, Giacomo, and Jeanne, Olivier 1999a. ‘Segmented communication and fashionable behavior’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 39: 371–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, Giacomo, and Jeanne, Olivier 1999b. ‘Social organization in an endogenous growth model’, International Economic Review 40(3): 711–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard, and Sandler, Todd 1984. ‘Easy riders, joint production and public goods’, Economic Journal 94: 580–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard, and Sandler, Todd 1986. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cowan, Robin, Cowan, William and Swan, Peter 1997. ‘A model of demand with interactions among consumers’, International Journal of Industrial Organization 15: 711–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald, and Rank, Mark R. 1992. ‘Inter-vivos transfers and intergenerational exchange’, Review of Economics and Statistics 74(2): 305–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Croson, Rachel T. A. 1996. Contributions to Public Goods: Altruism or Reciprocity? Working Paper no. 96–08–01, Wharton Risk Management and Decision Processes Center, University of Pennsylvania.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha 1988. ‘Trust as a commodity’, in Gambetta, (ed.), Trust: Making Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 49–72.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha, and Serageldin, Ismail (eds.) 1999. Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
David, Paul A. 1985. ‘Clio and the economics of QWERTY’, American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 75(2): 332–7.Google Scholar
Davis, Douglas D., and Holt, Charles A. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, John 2003. The Theory of the Individual in Economics: Identity and Value. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M., and Thaler, Richard H. 1988. ‘Anomalies: cooperation’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 2: 187–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M., Jeanne, McTavish and Harriet, Shaklee 1977. ‘Behaviour, communication and assumptions about other people's behaviour in a Commons dilemma situation’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35: 1–11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Mello, Luiz 2000. ‘Can fiscal decentralization strengthen social capital?’, in Working Paper wp/00/129, International Monetary Fund, 1–31.
Demsetz, Harold 1988. ‘The structure of ownership and the theory of the firm’, in Demsetz, (ed.), Ownership, Control and the Firm. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 187–201.Google Scholar
Descartes, René 1965. ‘Works’, in Adam, and Tannery, (eds.), Oeuvres de Descartes. Paris: Vrin, 13 volumes.Google Scholar
Waal, Frans 1996. Good Natured: The Origins of Right and Wrong in Humans and Other Animals. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
DiPasquale, Denise, and Glaeser, Edward L. 1999. ‘Incentives and social capital: are homeowners better citizens?’, Journal of Urban Economics 45: 354–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Disney, Richard, Goodman, Alissa, Gosling, Amanda and Trinder, Chris 1998. Public Pay in Britain in the 1990s. Commentary no. 72, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diwan, Romesh 2000. ‘Relational wealth and the quality of life’, Journal of Socio-Economics 29: 305–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djajic, Slobodan, and Milbourne, Ross 1988. ‘A general equilibrium model of guest-worker migration’, Journal of International Economics 25: 335–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, Martin, and Gneezy, Uri 2000. ‘Measuring beliefs in an experimental lost wallet game’, Games and Economic Behavior 30: 163–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dufwenberg, Martin, and Kirchsteiger, Georg 1998. A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity. Discussion Paper no. 37, University of Tilburg, Netherlands.Google Scholar
Durlauf, Steven N. 2002. ‘Bowling alone: a review essay’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 47(3): 259–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dustmann, Christian 1997. ‘Return migration, uncertainty and precautionary savings’, Journal of Development Economics 52(2): 295–315.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Easterlin, Richard 2002. Happiness in Economics. Cheltenham: The International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Eckel, Catherine, and Grossman, Philip 1996. ‘Altruism in anonymous dictator games’, Games and Economic Behavior 16: 181–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Economist, The 2002. 24–30 August: 50.
Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro 1967 [1881]. Mathematical Psychics. London: Kegan.Google Scholar
Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro 1970 [1891]. Papers Related to Political Economy. New York: Burt Franklin, 3 volumes.Google Scholar
Edwards, Richard, Gordon, David M. and Reich, Michael 1982. Segmented Work, Divided Workers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Edwards, Richard, and MacEwan, Arthur 1970. ‘A radical approach to economics: basis for a new curriculum’, American Economic Review 60(2): 352–63.Google Scholar
Einarsen, Stal 1999. ‘The nature and causes of bullying at work’, International Journal of Manpower 20(1–2): 16–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, John 1983. Sour Grapes: Studies in the Subversion of Rationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, John 1989. The Cement of Society. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
England, Paula 1992. Comparable Worth: Theories and Evidence. New York: Aldine de Gruyter.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, Marcel, and Minten, Bart 2002. ‘Returns to social network capital among traders’, Oxford Economic Papers 54(2): 173–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falk, Armin, and Fischbacher, Urs 1998. A Theory of Reciprocity. Discussion paper, University of Zurich.Google Scholar
Falk, Armin, and Fischbacher, Urs 2001. ‘Distributional consequences and intentions in a model of reciprocity’, Annales d'économie et de statistique 6364: 111–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Fischbacher, Urs 2002. ‘The impact of non-selfish motives on competition, cooperation and incentives’, Economic Journal 112: C1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Gächter 1998a. ‘How effective are trust- and reciprocity-based incentives?’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Values and Organisation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 337–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Gächter, Simon 1998b. ‘Reciprocity and economics: the economic implications of Homo reciprocans’, European Economic Review 42: 845–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Gächter, Simon 2000. ‘Cooperation and punishment in public good experiments’, American Economic Review 90(4): 980–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Gächter, Simon and Kirchsteiger, Georg 1997. ‘Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device’, Econometrica 65(4): 833–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, and Schmidt, Klaus M. 1999. ‘A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 817–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferber, Marianne A., and Nelson, Julie A. (eds.) 1993. Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory and Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferber, Marianne A., and Nelson, Julie A.(eds.) 2003. Feminist Economics Today: Beyond Economic Man. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ferrara, Francesco 1934 [1849–51]. Lezioni di economia politica. Bologna: Zanichelli, 2 volumes.Google Scholar
Festinger, Leon 1957. A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Fine, Ben 2001. Social Capital versus Social Theory: Political Economy and Social Science at the Turn of the Millennium. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, Urs, Gächter, Simon and Fehr, Ernst 2001. ‘Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment’, Economics Letters 71: 397–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flap, Henk, and Volker, Beate 2001. ‘Goal-specific social capital and job satisfaction: effects of different types of networks on instrumental and social aspects of work’, Social Networks 23: 297–320.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foa, Uriel G. 1993. ‘Interpersonal and economic resources’, in Foa, U. G., Converse, Törnblom and Foa, E. B. (eds.), Resource Theory: Explorations and Applications. San Diego: Academic Press, 13–30.Google Scholar
Folbre, Nancy, and Nelson, Julie A. 2000. ‘For love or money – or both?’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(4): 123–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe 1997. ‘Identification and economic behavior: sympathy and empathy in historical perspective’, Economic and Philosophy 13: 264–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Horowitz, Joel L., Savin, N. E. and Sefton, Martin 1994. ‘Fairness in simple bargaining experiments’, Games and Economic Behavior 6: 347–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Jonathan, and Gershman, John 2000. ‘The World Bank and social capital: lessons from ten rural development projects in the Philippines and Mexico’, Policy Science 33: 399–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 1985. Choosing the Right Pond: Human Behaviour and the Quest for Status. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 1988. Passions within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H.1991. ‘Positional externalities’, in Zeckhauser, (ed.), Strategy and Choice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 25–47.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. 1997. ‘The frame of reference as a public good’, Economic Journal 107(6): 1832–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankfurt, Harry Gordon 1971. ‘Freedom of the will and the concept of a person’, Journal of Philosophy 68: 5–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. 1997. ‘Working for nothing: the supply of volunteer labor’, Journal of Labor Economics 15(1): S140–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno S. 1997. Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham, UK, and Lyme, NH: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno S.1998. ‘Institutions and morale: the crowding-out effect’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Values and Organisation. Cambridge, New York: Cambridge University Press, 437–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedberg, Erhard 1993. Le pouvoir et la règle. Paris: Seuil.Google Scholar
Frijters, Paul 2000. ‘The sale of relational capital through tenure profiles and tournaments’, Labour Economics 7: 373–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frohlich, Norman, and Oppenheimer, Joe 1998. ‘Some consequences of e-mail vs. face to face communication in experiment’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 35: 389–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gächter, Simon and Ernst, Fehr 1999. ‘Collective action as social exchange’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organizaion 39: 341–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GambettaDiego, (ed.) 1988. Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
GambettaDiego, 1993. The Sicilian Mafia: The Business of Private Protection. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Geanakoplos, John, Pearce, David, and Stacchetti, Ennio 1989. ‘Psychological games and sequential rationality’, Games and Economic Behavior 1(1): 60–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geary, Robert Charles 1950. ‘A note on “A constant-utility index of the cost of living”’, Review of Economic Studies 18: 65–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Genovesi, Antonio 1963. Autobiografia e lettere. Milan: Feltrinelli.Google Scholar
Genovesi, Antonio 1973 [1766]. Della diceosina o sia della filosofia del giusto e dell'onesto per gli giovanetti. Milan: Marzorati.Google Scholar
Gérard-Varet, Louis-André, Kolm, Serge-Christophe and Mercier-Ythier, Jean (eds.) 2000. The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism. London and New York: Macmillan and St. Martin's Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geschiere, Peter 1995. ‘Working groups or wage labour? Cash crops, reciprocity and money among the Maka of southeastern Cameroon’, Development and Change 26(3): 503–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert 1998. ‘Incentives in organizations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 12(4): 115–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Margaret 1989. On Social Facts. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Gilligan, Carol 1982. In A Different Voice: Psychological Theory and Women's Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gintis, Herbert 1976. ‘The nature of labor exchange and the theory of capitalist production’, Review of Radical Political Economy 8(2): 36–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Laibson, David and Sacerdote, Bruce 2002. ‘The economic approach to social capital’, Economic Journal 112: 437–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Laibson, David, Sheinkman, José A. and Soutter, Christine L. 2000. ‘Measuring trust’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 65: 811–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Sacerdote, Bruce and Sheinkman, José A. 1996. ‘Crime and social interactions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 111: 507–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., and José A. Sheinkman 2000. Non-market Interactions, Working Paper 8053, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Goffman, Erwing 1961. Encounters: Two Studies in the Sociology of Interaction. Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Good, David 1988. ‘Individuals, interpersonal relations and trust’, in Gambetta, (ed.), Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 31–48.Google Scholar
Goodfriend, Marvin, and McDermott, John 1995. ‘Early development’, American Economic Review 85(1): 116–33.Google Scholar
Gossen, Hermann Heinrich 1981 [1854]. The Laws of Human Relations. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 1973. ‘The strength of weak ties’, American Journal of Sociology 78(6): 1360–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 1974. Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 1978. ‘Threshold models of collective behavior’, American Journal of Sociology 83(6): 1420–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 1985. ‘Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness’, American Journal of Sociology 91(3): 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark1990. ‘The old and the new economic sociology: a history and an agenda’, in Friedland, and Robertson, (eds.), Beyond the Marketplace: Rethinking Economy and Society. New York: Aldine de Gruyter, 89–112.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 1992. ‘Economic institutions as social constructions: a framework for analysis’, Acta Sociologica 35: 3–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark 2000. Au delà du marché. Paris: Desclée de Brouwer.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark, and Patrick McGuire 1998. ‘The making of an industry: electricity in the United States’, in Callon, (ed.), The Law of Markets. Oxford: Blackwell, 147–73.Google Scholar
Grilo, Isabel, and Thisse, Jacques F. 1999. ‘Engouement collectif et concurrence’, Revue Economique 50(3): 593–600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gui, Benedetto 1988. ‘Eléments pour une definition d'économie communautaire’, Notes et documents de l'institut international Jacques Maritain 19/20, 32–42.Google Scholar
Gui, Benedetto 1996. ‘On relational goods: strategic implications of investment in relationships’, International Journal of Social Economics 23(10/11): 260–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gui, Benedetto2000a. ‘Beyond transactions: on the interpersonal dimension of economic reality’, in Gui (ed.), Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, special issue on ‘Economics and interpersonal relations’ 71(2): 139–69.
Gui, Benedetto2000b. ‘Economics and interpersonal relations: introduction’, in Gui (ed.), Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, special issue on ‘Economics and interpersonal relations’ 71(2): 133–8.
Gui, Benedetto(ed.) 2000c. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, special issue on ‘Economics and interpersonal relations’ 71(2).
Gunnthorsdottir, Anna, Daniel Houser, Kevin McCabe and Holly Ameden 2002. Disposition, History and Contributions in a Public Goods Experiment. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics and Economic Science Laboratory, University of Arizona.
Güth, Werner 1995. ‘An evolutionary approach to explaining cooperative behavior by reciprocal incentives’, International Journal of Game Theory 24: 323–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, Werner, Ockenfels, Peter and Wendel, Markus 1997. ‘Cooperation based on trust: an experimental investigation’, Journal of Economic Psychology 18(1): 15–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hammer, Michael 1995. The Reengineering Revolution. London: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Hammond, Peter J. 1975. ‘Charity: altruism or egoism?’, in Phelps, (ed.), Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications, 115–31.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 1980. ‘The role of nonprofit enterprise’, Yale Law Journal 89(5): 835–901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansmann, Henry 1986. ‘A theory of status organizations’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 2(1): 119–30.Google Scholar
Hansmann, Henry1989. Politics and Markets in the Organization of the Firm. Inaugural lecture for the Sam Harris Professorship, Yale Law School, New Haven, Connecticut.
Hardin, Russell 1993. ‘The street-level epistemology of trust’, Politics and Society, 21(4): 505–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell 2001. Trust and Trustworthiness. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.Google Scholar
Hargreaves Heap, Shaun 1989. Rationality in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hargreaves-Heap, Shaun1997. When Norms Influence Behaviour: Expressive Reason and its Consequences. Paper prepared for the Freiberg Symposium on ‘Abandoning the hypothesis of omniscience in economics’, 9–10 January 1997.
Hargreaves Heap, Shaun, Hollis, Martin, Lyons, Bruce, Sugden, Robert and Weale, Albert 1992. The Theory of Choice. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John 1955. ‘Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics and interpersonal comparisons of utility’, Journal of Political Economy 63: 309–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, James S. 2002. ‘The trust paradox: a survey of economic inquiries into the nature of trust and trustworthiness’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 47(3): 291–307.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel 1998. Fairness and Trust in Game Theory. Mimeo, London School of Economics.
Helper, Susan, Bendoly, Elliot and DavidLevine, I. 1999. Employee Involvement and Pay at U.S. and Canadian Auto Suppliers. Working Paper no. 71, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Herzberg, Frederick 1966. Work and the Nature of Man. Cleveland and New York: The World Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R., 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, John R., and Allen, Roy G. D. 1934. ‘A reconsideration of the theory of value’, Economica 1: 52–76; 196–219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirsch, Fred 1976. Social Limits to Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschleifer, David 1995. ‘Social influence, information cascades and fads’, in Tommasi, and Ierulli, (eds.), The New Economics of Human Behaviour. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschleifer, Jack 1978. ‘Natural economy versus political economy’, Journal of Social and Biological Structures 1: 319–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschleifer, Jack, and Riley, John G. 1992. The Analytics of Uncertainty and Information. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas 1965 [1651]. Leviathan. Reprinted with an essay by W. G. Pogson Smith. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin, Shachat, Keith and Smith, Vernon 1994. ‘Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games’, Games and Economic Behavior 7: 346–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elisabeth, McCabe, Kevin and Smith, Vernon L. 1996. ‘Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games’, American Economic Review 86(3): 653–60.Google Scholar
Hollander, Heinz 1990. ‘A social exchange approach to voluntary cooperation’, American Economic Review 80(4): 1157–67.Google Scholar
Hollis, Martin 1998. Trust within Reason. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hollis, Martin, and Sugden, Robert 1993. ‘Rationality in action’, Mind January: 1–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homans, George C. 1954. ‘The cash posters’, American Sociological Review 19: 724–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hont, Istvan, and Ignatief, Michael 1983. Wealth and Virtue: The Shaping of Political Economy in the Scottish Enlightenment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horsburgh, H. J. N. 1960. ‘The ethics of trust’, Philosophical Quarterly 10: 343–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, David 1978 [1739]. A Treatise of Human Nature. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, David2001 [1751]. An Enquiry Concerning the Principles of Morals. Project Gutenberg, on-line edition, www.gutenberg.net/etext06/8echu10h.htm.
Hurley, Susan L. 1989. Natural Reasons. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hutcheson, Francis 1971 [1725]. ‘An inquiry into the original of our ideas of beauty and virtue’, in Collected Works of Francis Hutcheson. Hildesheim, Germany: Olms, Vol. I.
Iannaccone, Laurence R. 1992. ‘Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free riding in cults, communes, and other collectives’, Journal of Political Economy 100(2): 271–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Independent 2002. 16 May: 9.
Ireland, Norman 1994. ‘On limiting the market for status signals’, Journal of Public Economics 53: 91–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. Mark, and Walker, James M. 1988. ‘Communication and free-riding behaviour: the voluntary contributions mechanism’, Economic Inquiry 26: 585–608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. Mark and Walker, James M. 1998. ‘Nash as an organising principle in the voluntary provision of public goods: experimental evidence’, Experimental Economics 1: 191–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Isaac, R. Mark, Walker, James M. and Thomas, Susan H. 1984. ‘Divergent evidence on free-riding: an experimental investigation of possible explanations’, Public Choice 43: 113–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jap, Sandy, and Erin Anderson 1998. Vilification: Dysfunctional Dynamics in Interorganizational Collaborations. Working Paper 99/06/MKT, INSEAD, Fontainebleau, France.
Jevons, William Stanley 1879. The Theory of Political Economy. London: Macmillan, 2nd edn.Google Scholar
Johnson, Paul A., and Temple, Jonathan 1998. ‘Social capability and economic growth’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3): 965–90.Google Scholar
Jones, Karen 1996. ‘Trust as an affective attitude’, Ethics, 107: 4–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, Stephen R. G. 1984. The Economics of Conformism. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Jussim, Lee 1986. ‘Self-fulfilling prophecies: a theoretical and integrative review’, Psychological Review 93: 429–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos (eds.) 2000. Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kant, Immanuel 1991 [1797]. The Metaphysic of Morals, [translated by Gregor]. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kelley, Harold H. 1986. ‘Personal relationships: their nature and significance’, in Gilmour, and Duck, (eds.), The Emerging Field of Personal Relationships. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, 3–19.Google Scholar
Keser, Claudia 1996. ‘Voluntary contributions to public goods when partial contribution is a dominant strategy’, Economics Letters 50: 359–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khanna, Jyoti, Posnett, John, and Sandler, Todd 1995. ‘Charity donations in the UK: new evidence based on panel data’, Journal of Public Economics 56: 257–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirman, Alan 1997. ‘The economy as an evolving network’, Journal of Evolutionary Economics 7: 339–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin, Crawford, Robert G. and Alchian, Armen A. 1978. ‘Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process’, Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe, 1981a. ‘Altruisme et efficacité’: le sophisme de Rousseau', Social Science Information 20: 293–344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe 1981b. ‘Efficacité et altruisme: le sophisme de Mandeville, Smith et Pareto’,Revue Economique 1: 5–31.
Kolm, Serge-Christophe 1983. ‘Altruism and efficiency’, Ethics 94: 18–65. [Reprinted in Zamagni (ed.), The Economics of Altruism. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.]
Kolm, Serge-Christophe 1984. La bonne économie: la reciprocité générale. Paris: Presses Universitaire de France.Google Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe 1996. Modern Theories of Justice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe 1998. Justice and Equity. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, [English translation of Justice et équité, 1971].Google Scholar
Kolm, Serge-Christophe2000. ‘The theory of reciprocity’, in Gérard-Varet, Kolm and Mercier-Ythier (eds.), The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving and Altruism. London and New York: Macmillan and St. Martin's Press, 15–141.
Kolm, Serge-Christophe2005. ‘Reciprocity: its scope, rationales, and consequences’, in Gérard-Varet, Kolm and Mercier-Ythier (eds.), Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism. Amsterdam: NorthHolland, ch. 2.
Kramer, Roderick M., and Lisa Goldman 1995. ‘Helping the group or helping yourself? Social motives and group identity in resource dilemmas’, in Schroeder, (ed.), Social Dilemmas: Perspectives on Individuals and Groups. Westport, CT: Praeger, 49–67.Google Scholar
Kramer, Roderick M., and Tyler, Tom R. (eds.) 1995. Trust in Organisations: Frontiers of Theory and Research. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Kranton, Rachel E., and Minehart, Deborah F. 2001. ‘A theory of buyer–seller networks’, American Economic Review 91(3): 485–508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, David M., Milgrom, Paul Robert, Roberts, John and Wilson, Robert 1982. ‘Rational cooperation in the finitely repeated prisoner's dilemma’, Journal of Economic Theory 27: 245–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurz, Mordecai 1978. ‘Altruism as an outcome of social interaction’, Journal of Public Economics 36: 369–86.Google Scholar
Kurz, Mordecai1979. ‘Altruism equilibrium’, in Balassa, and Nelson, (eds.), Economic Progress, Private Values, and Policy. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 177–200.Google Scholar
Laband, David N., and Lentz, Bernard F., 1998. ‘The effects of sexual harassment on job satisfaction, earnings, and turnover among female lawyers’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 51(4): 594–607.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lalonde, Richard N., and Silverman, Randy A. 1994. ‘Behavioural preferences in response to social injustice: the effects of group permeability and social identity salience’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 66: 78–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lane, Christel, and Bachmann, Reinhard (eds.) 1998. Trust Within and Between Organisations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lea, Stephen E. G., Tarpy, Roger M. and Webley, Paul 1987. The Individual in the Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ledyard, John O. 1995. ‘Public goods: a survey of experimental research’, in Roth, and Kagel, (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 111–81.Google Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey 1979. ‘A branch of economics is missing: micro-micro theory’, Journal of Economic Literature 17(2): 477–502.Google Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel 1973. ‘Life among the econ’, Western Economic Journal 11: 327–37.Google Scholar
Ley, Eduardo 1997. ‘Optimal provision of public goods with altruistie individuals’, Economics Letters 54(1): 23–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebrand, Wim G. B., Jansen, R. W. T. L. and Rijken, V. M., 1986. ‘Might over morality: social values and the perception of other players in experimental games’, Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 22: 203–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebrand, Wim G. B., Wilke, Henk A. M., Vogel, Rob and Wolters, Fred J. M. 1986. ‘Value orientation and conformity’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 30: 77–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liu, Michel 1981. ‘Technologie, organisation du travail et comportement des salariés’, Revue française de sociologie 22: 205–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, George 2000. ‘Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior’, American Economic Review 90(2): 426–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macaulay, J., and Berkowitz, L. (eds.) 1970. Altruism and Helping Behavior. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Mackenzie, Catriona, and Stoljar, Natalie (eds.) 2000. Relational Autonomy: Feminist Perspectives on Autonomy, Agency, and the Social Self. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Macneil, Ian R. 1987. ‘Relational contract theory as sociology: a reply to Professors Lindenberg and de Vos’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 143: 272–90.Google Scholar
Mailath, George, and Postlewaite, Andrew 1990. ‘Workers versus firms: bargaining over a firm's value’, Review of Economic Studies 57(3): 369–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malthus, Thomas Robert 1966 [1798]. Essay on the Principle of Population. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Malthus, Thomas Robert1986 [1820]. ‘Principles of political economy’, in Wrigley, and Souden, (eds.), The Works of Thomas Robert Malthus. London: W. Pickering, Vol. V.Google Scholar
Manski, Charles F. 2000. ‘Economic analysis of social interactions’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 4(3): 115–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marglin, Stephen 1974. ‘What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production’, Review of Radical Political Economics 6(2): 60–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margolis, Howard 1982. Selfishness, Altruism and Rationality: A Theory of Social Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred 1927 [1919]. Industry and Trade. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred 1946 [1890]. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl 1906 [1867]. Capital: A Critical Analysis of Capitalist Production. London: Engels, Sonnenschein & Co.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl1994 [1857–8]. Grundrisse: Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy, reprinted (the first three sections) in Hausman (ed.), The Philosophy of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 119–42.
Masclet, David, Noussair, Charles, Tucker, Steven and Villeval, Marie-Claire 2003. ‘Monetary and nonmonetary punishment in the voluntary contributions mechanism’, American Economic Review 93(1): 366–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauss, Marcel 1995. Sociologie et anthropologie. Paris: PUF.Google Scholar
McGuire, Patrick, Mark Granovetter and Michael Schwartz 1993. ‘Thomas Edison and the social construction of the early electricity industry in America’, in Swedberg, (ed.), Explorations in Economic Sociology. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications, 213–46.Google Scholar
Meade, James E. 1973. The Theory of Economic Externalities: The Control of Environmental Pollution and Similar Social Cost. Leiden, Netherlands: Nijhoff.Google Scholar
Ménard, Claude 1990. L'économie des organisations. Paris: La Découverte.Google Scholar
Ménard, Claude 1994. ‘Organizations as coordinating devices’, Metroeconomica 45(3): 224–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menchik, Paul L., and Weisbrod, Burton A. 1987. ‘Volunteer labor supply’, Journal of Public Economics 32(2): 159–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menger, Carl 1871. Grundsätze der Volkswirtschaftslehre. Vienna: Braumüller.Google Scholar
Michael, Robert T., and Becker, Gary S. 1973. ‘On the new theory of consumer behavior’, Swedish Journal of Economics 75: 378–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, John S. 1848. Principles of Political Economy. London: John W. Parker.Google Scholar
Mill, John S. 1897 [1836]. Early Essays. London: George Bell and Sons.Google Scholar
Miller, Nancy J. 2001. ‘Contributions of social capital theory in predicting rural community inshopping behavior’, Journal of Socio-Economics 30: 475–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirowski, P. 1999. ‘Review of A Beautiful Mind, by S. Nasar’, Economics and Philosophy 15: 302–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mirvis, Philip H., and Hackett, Edward J. 1983. ‘Work and workforce characteristics in the nonprofit sector’, Monthly Labour Review 106(4): 3–12.Google Scholar
Misztal, Barbara A. 1996. Trust in Modern Societies. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Mocan, Naci H., and Deborah Viola 1997. The Determinants of Child Care Workers' Wages Compensation: Sectoral Difference, Human Capital, Race, Insiders and Outsiders. Working Paper 6328, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Modigliani, Kathy 1993. Child Care as an Occupation in a Culture of Indifference. Dissertation, Wheelock College, Boston.Google Scholar
Mosca, Manuela, Marco Musella and Francesco Pastore 2003. Compensation Mechanism and Firm Performance in Italy's Nonprofit Sector. Mimeo, Faculty of Economics, University of Naples ‘Federico II’.
Moscovici, Serge 1985. ‘Social influence and conformity’, in Gardner, and Aronson, (eds.), The Handbook of Social Psychology. New York: Random House, Vol. II, 347–412.Google Scholar
Moss, M. K., and Page, R. A. 1972. ‘Reinforcement and helping behavior’, Journal of Applied Psychology 2: 360–71.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A. 1994. ‘I, thou, and them: capabilities, altruism, and norms in the economics of marriage’, American Economic Review 84(2): 126–31.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A. 1996. Feminism, Objectivity, and Economics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A. 1999. ‘Of markets and martyrs: is it OK to pay well for care?’, Feminist Economics 5(3): 43–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, Julie A.2003. ‘Separative and soluble firms: androcentric bias in business ethics’, in Ferber, and Nelson, (eds.), Feminist Economics Today: Beyond Economic Man. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 81–99.Google Scholar
Nelson, Julie A., and England, Paula 2002. ‘Feminist philosophies of love and work’, Hypatia: A Journal of Feminist Philosophy 17(2): 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ng, Yew-Kwang 1975. ‘Non-economic activities, indirect externalities, and third-best policies’, Kyklos 28(3): 507–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nicole, Pierre 1675. Essais de morale. Paris.Google Scholar
Nohria, Nitin 1992. ‘Introduction: is a network perspective a useful way of studying organizations?’, in Nohria, and Eccles, (eds.), Networks and Organizations: Structure, Form, and Action. Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1–22.Google Scholar
Normann, Richard 1984. Service Management: Strategy and Leadership in Service Business. Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Martha C. 1986. ‘The vulnerability of the good human life: relational goods’, in The Fragility of Goodness: Luck and Ethics in Greek Tragedy and Philosophy. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 343–72.
Olson, Mancur 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ones, Umut, and Louis Putterman 2004. The Ecology of Collective Action: A Public Goods and Sanctions Experiment with Controlled Group Formation. Working Paper no. 2004–01, Department of Economics, Brown University, Providence, Rhode Island.
Orbell, John M., Dawes, Robyn, and Kragt, Alphons 1988. ‘Explaining discussion-induced cooperation’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 54(5): 811–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Reilly, Charles A., and Pfeffer, Jeffrey 2000. Hidden Value: How Great Companies Achieve Extraordinary Results with Ordinary People. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Orléan, André 1995. ‘Bayesian interactions and collective dynamics of opinion: herd behavior and mimetic contagion’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organizations 28: 257–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orléan, André1998. ‘Informational influences and the ambivalence of imitation’, in Lesourne, and Orléan, (eds.), Advances in Self-organization and Evolutionary Economics. Paris: Economica, 39–56.Google Scholar
Ortmann, Andreas, Kathleen M. Hansberry and John M. Fitzgerald 1997. Voluntary Contributions to a Public Good when Partial Contribution is a Dominant Strategy. Discussion paper, Bowdoin College, Brunswick Maine.
Ostrom, Elinor 1990. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor 2003. Reciprocity and Trust. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.Google Scholar
Oswald, Andrew 1997. ‘Happiness and economic performance’, Economic Journal 107: 1815–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Talbot, Louis Putterman and Bulent Unel (forthcoming). ‘Voluntary association in public goods experiments: reciprocity, mimicry, and efficiency’, Economic Journal.
Paldam, Martin 2000. ‘Social capital: one or many? Definition and measurement’, Journal of Economic Surveys 14(5): 629–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, Tom R., and Prisbey, Jeffrey E. 1996. ‘Altruism, reputation and noise in linear public goods experiments’, Journal of Public Economics 61: 409–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pantaleoni, Maffeo 1889. Principii di economia pura. Florence: Barbera. [English translation: 1898. Pure Economics. London: Macmillan.]
Pantaleoni, Maffeo 1925. Erotemi di economia.Bari, Laterza, 2 volumes.Google Scholar
Paquè, Karl Heinz 1982. Do Public Transfers ‘Crowd Out' Private Charitable Giving? Some Econometric Evidence for the Federal Republic of Germany, Working Paper no.152, Kiel University.
Pareto, Vilfredo 1896–7. Cours d'économie politique professé à l'Université de Lausanne. Lausanne: Rouge, 2 volumes.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo 1900a. ‘Sunto di alcuni capitoli di un nuovo trattato di economia politica del Prof. Pareto’, Giornale degli economisti 10: 216–35; 511–49.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo 1900b. ‘Sul fenomeno economico: lettera a Benedetto Croce’, Giornale degli economisti 21: 139–62.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo 1909. Manual d'économie politique. Geneva: Librairie Droz. [English translation: Pareto, 1971.]Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo1916. Trattato di sociologia generale. Florence: Barbera. [English translation: 1963 [1935]. The Mind and Society: A Treatise on General Sociology. New York: Dover.]
Pareto, Vilfredo1966 [1898]. ‘Comment se pose le problème de Véconomie pure’, Oeuvres complètes 9. Geneva: Droz.
Pareto, Vilfredo 1971 [1906]. Manual of Political Economy. New York: Kelley.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo 1980 [1897]. ‘Il compito della sociologia fra le scienze sociali’, Rivista italiana di sociologia July: 45–54.Google Scholar
Pareto, Vilfredo1984. ‘Letters to Maffeo Pantaleoni’, Oeuvres complètes 28, Vol. II. Geneva: Droz.
Parfit, Derek 1984. Reasons and Persons. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Pelligra, Vittorio 2002. ‘Fiducia r(el)azionale’, in Sacco, and Zamagni, (eds.), Complessità relazionale e comportamento economico. Bologna: Il Mulino, 291–335.
Pelligra, Vittorio2003. Trust and Economics: Theoretical and Experimental Investigations. Ph.D. thesis, University of East Anglia, Norwich.
Pelligra, Vittorio2004. ‘The not-so-fragile fragility of goodness’, in Porta, and Bruni, (eds.), Handbook of Happiness in Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Pettit, Philip 1995. ‘The cunning of trust’, Philosophy and Public Affairs 24(3): 202–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. 1975. Altruism, Morality and Economic Theory. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.Google Scholar
Pigou, Arthur C. 1920. Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pocock, John Greville Agard 1975. The Machiavellian Moment: Florentine Political Thought and the Atlantic Republican Tradition. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl 1944. The Great Transformation. [French translation: 1983. La grande transformation: aux origines politiques et économiques de notre temps. Paris: Gallimard.]
Prescott, Edward C., and Visscher, Michael 1980. ‘Organizational capital’, Journal of Political Economy 88(3): 446–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preston, Anne E. 1989. ‘The nonprofit worker in a for-profit world’, Journal of Labor Economics 7(4): 438–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Preston, Stephanie D., and Waal, Frans B. M. 2002. ‘Empathy: its ultimate and proximate bases’, Behavioral and Brain Sciences 25(1): 1–20.Google ScholarPubMed
Putnam, Robert D. 1993a. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1993b. ‘The prosperous community: social capital and public life’, American Prospect 4(13): 35–42.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1995. ‘Bowling alone: America's declining social capital’, Journal of Democracy 6(1): 65–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon and Schuster.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pyke, Frank, Becattini, Giacomo and Sengenberger, Werner (eds.) 1990. Industrial Districts and Inter-Firm Co-operation in Italy. Geneva: International Institute for Labour Studies.Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew 1993. ‘Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics’, American Economic Review 83(5): 1281–302.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, Tiziano 2002. Marshall's Evolutionary Economics. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Reynaud, Jean-Daniel 1997. Les règles du jeu. Paris: Armand Colin.Google Scholar
Rizzolatti, Giacomo, Fogassi, Leonardo and Gallese, Vittorio 2001. ‘Neurophysiological mechanisms underlying action, understanding and imitation’, Nature Reviews: Neuroscience 2: 661–70.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robbins, Lionel 1932. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel1933. ‘Introduction’, in Wicksteed, The Common Sense of Political Economy. London: Routledge.
Rose, Richard 1998. Getting Things Done in an Anti-Modern Society: Social Capital Networks in Russia. Social Capital Initiative Working Paper no. 6, World Bank.Google Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J. 1994a. ‘Human relations in the workplace’, Journal of Political Economy 102(4): 684–717.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio J. 1994b. Prices, Output and Hours: An Empirical Analysis Based on a Sticky Price Model. Working Paper 4948, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, Michael, and White, Lawrence J. 1995. ‘The analytics of pricing of higher education and other services in which customers are inputs’, Journal of Political Economy 103(3): 573–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, Denise M. 1995. Psychological Contracts in Organisations: Understanding Written and Unwritten Agreements. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Sacco, Pier Luigi, and Paolo Vanin 2000. ‘Network interaction with material and relational goods: an exploratory simulation’, in Gui, (ed.), Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, special issue on ‘Economics and interpersonal relations’ 71(2): 229–59.Google Scholar
Sacco, Pier Luigi, Paolo Vanin and Stefano Zamagni 2005. ‘Altruism and beyond: the economics of human relationships’, in Gérard-Varet, Kolm and Mercier-Ythier, (eds.), Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism.Amsterdam: North-Holland, ch. 3.Google Scholar
Saijo, Tatsuyoshi, and Nakamura, Hideki 1995. ‘The spite dilemma in voluntary contribution mechanism experiments’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 39: 535–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sally, David 1995. ‘Conversation and cooperation in social dilemmas: a meta-analysis of experiments from 1958 to 1992’, Rationality and Society 7(1): 58–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sally, David 2000. ‘A general theory of sympathy, mind-reading, and social interaction, with an application to the prisoner's dilemma’, Social Science Information 39: 567–634.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sally, David 2001. ‘On sympathy and games’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 44: 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saxon-Harrold, Susan, and Kendall, Jeremy 1995. Dimensions of the Voluntary Sector. Tonbridge: Charities Aid Foundation.Google Scholar
Schiff, Maurice 1999. Labor Market Integration in the Presence of Social Capital. Development Research Group, World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiff, Maurice 2002. ‘Love thy neighbor: trade, migration and social capital’, European Journal of Political Economy 18(1): 87–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmid, A. Allan 2000. ‘Affinity as social capital: its role in development’, Journal of Socio-Economics 29: 159–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schram, Arthur, and Sonnemans, Joep 1996. ‘Why people vote: experimental evidence’, Journal of Economic Psychology 17: 417–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1997 [1952]. Ten Great Economists: From Marx to Keynes. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, T. 1982. ‘What welfare is not’, in Miller, and Williams, (eds.), The Limits of Utilitarianism. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Scott, Alan 1990. Ideology and the New Social Movements. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Searle, John R. 1995. The Construction of Social Reality. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Sefton, Martin, Shupp, Robert S. and Walker, James M. 2002. The Effect of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods. Discussion paper, Centre for Decision Research and Experimental Economics, University of Nottingham.Google Scholar
Sefton, Martin, and Steinberg, Richard S. 1996. ‘Reward structures in public goods experiments’, Journal of Public Economics 61: 263–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya 1977. ‘Rational fools: a critique of the behavioral foundations of economic theory’, Philosophy and Public Affairs 6: 314–44.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya 1987. The Standard of Living. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shields, Michael A., and Price, Stephen W. 2002. ‘Racial harassment, job satisfaction and intentions to quit: evidence from the British nursing profession’, Economica 69: 295–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1951. ‘A formal theory of the employment relationship’, Econometrica 19: 293–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1978. ‘Rationality as process and as product of thought’, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 68: 1–16.Google Scholar
Slovic, Paul, Finucane, Melissa L., Peters, Ellen and MacGregor, Donald G. 2002. ‘Rational actors or rational fools: implications of the affect heuristic for behavioral economics’, Journal of Socio-Economics 31(4): 329–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smelser, Neil J., and Richard Swedberg 1994. ‘The sociological perspective on the economy’, in Smelser, and Swedberg, (eds.), Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 3–26.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam 1976 [1759]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam 1976 [1776]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sobel, Joel 2002. ‘Can we trust social capital?’, Journal of Economic Literature 40(1): 139–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sober, Elliott, and Wilson, David Sloan 1998. Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert 1999. ‘Notes on social capital and economic performance’, in Dasgupta, and Serageldin, (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World Bank, 6–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sousa-Poza, A., and , A. A. Sousa-Poza 2000. ‘Taking another look at the general job-satisfaction paradox’, Kyklos Review 53(2): 135–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinberg, Richard 1985. ‘Empirical relations between government spending and charitable donations’, Journal of Voluntary Action Research 14: 54–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinberg, Richard 1991. ‘Does government spending crowd out donations? Interpreting the evidence’, Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics 62(2): 591–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J., and Becker, Gary S. 1977. ‘De gustibus non est disputandum’, American Economic Review 67(2):76–90.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1988. Economics of the Public Sector. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Stimson, Robert J., and Minnery, John 1998. ‘Why people move to the “Sun-belt”: a case study of long-distance migration to the Gold Coast, Australia’, Urban Studies 35(2): 193–214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stone, Richard 1954. ‘Linear expenditure systems and demand analysis: an application to the pattern of British demand’, Economic Journal 64: 511–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert 1982. ‘On the economics of philanthropy’, Economic Journal 92: 341–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert 1984. ‘Reciprocity: the supply of public goods through voluntary contributions’, Economic Journal 94: 772–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert 1986. The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sugden, Robert 1993. ‘Thinking as a team: towards an explanation of non-selfish behavior’, Social Philosophy and Policy 10: 69–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert1998. ‘Normative expectations: the simultaneous evolution of institutions and norms’, in Ben-Ner, and Putterman, (eds.), Economics, Values and Organisation. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 73–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert 2000a. ‘Team preferences’, Economics and Philosophy 16: 175–204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert2000b. ‘The motivating power of expectations’, in Nida-Rümelin, and Spohn, (eds), Rationality, Rules and Structure. Dordrecht: Kluwer, 103–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert 2002. ‘Beyond sympathy and empathy: Adam Smith's concept of fellow-feeling’, Economics and Philosophy 18(1): 63–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swaney, J. 1990. ‘Common property, reciprocity, and community’, Journal of Economic Issues 24(2): 451–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swedberg, Richard 1997. ‘Vers une nouvelle sociologie économique: bilan et perspectives’, [translated into French] ‘Sociologie économique’ Cahiers internationaux de sociologie 103 (July–December): 237–63.Google Scholar
Szompka, Pjotr 1999. Trust: A Sociological Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tinel, Bruno 2000. Origines et fonctions de la hiérarchie: trente ans de débats, 1968–1998. Ph.D. thesis, University of Lyon 2.Google Scholar
Titmuss, Robert 1970. The Gift Relationship. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Toffler, Alvin 1980. The Third Wave. New York: William Morrow & Co.Google Scholar
Tomer, John F. 1987. Organizational Capital: The Path to Higher Productivity and Well-Being. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Topa, Giorgio 2001. ‘Social interactions, local spillovers and unemployment’, Review of Economic Studies 68(2): 261–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuomela, Raimo 1995. The Importance of Us. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Turner, Jonathan H. 1999. ‘The formation of social capital’, in Dasgupta, and Serageldin, (eds.), Social Capital: A Multifaceted Perspective. Washington, DC: World Bank, 94–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyler, Tom R., and DeGoey, Peter 1995. ‘Collective restraint in social dilemmas – procedural justice effects and social identification effects on support for authorities’, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 69: 482–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlaner, Carole J. 1989. ‘Relational goods and participation: incorporating sociability into a theory of rational action’, Public Choice 62: 253–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dijk, Frans, and Winden, Frans 1997. ‘Dynamic of social ties and public good provision’, Journal of Public Economics 64(3): 323–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neumann, John, and Morgenstern, Oskar 1964 [1944]. Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Walker, James M., Roy, Gardner and Elinor, Ostrom 1990. ‘Rent dissipation in limited access common pool resource environments: experimental evidence’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 19: 203–11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Max 1956 [1922]. Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. [French translation: 1970, Economie et société. Paris: Plon. English translation: 1968, Economy and Society. New York: Bedminster Press.]
Weimann, Joachim 1994. ‘Individual behaviour in a free-riding experiment’, Journal of Public Economics 54: 185–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1983. ‘Nonprofit and proprietary sector behavior: wage differentials among lawyers’, Journal of Labor Economics 1(3): 246–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksteed, Philip H. 1906. ‘Review to Pareto's Manuale di economia politica’, Economic Journal 16: 814–18.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, Philip H. 1914. ‘The scope and method of political economy in the light of the “marginal” theory of value and distribution’, Economic Journal 24: 772–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksteed, Philip H. 1933 [1910]. The Common Sense of Political Economy. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1991. ‘Introduction’, in Williamson, and Winter, (eds.), The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, 3–17.
Williamson, Oliver E. 1993. ‘Contested exchange versus the governance of contractual relations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(1): 103–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1996. The Mechanisms of Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E., Wachter, Michael L. and Harris, Jeffrey E. 1975. ‘Understanding the employment relation: the analysis of idiosyncratic exchange’, Bell Journal of Economics 6: 250–78CrossRef
Winch, Donald 1978. Adam Smith's Policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wit, Arjaan P., and Wilke, Henk A. M. 1992. ‘The effect of social categorisation on cooperation in three types of social dilemmas’, Journal of Economic Psychology 13: 135–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittgenstein, Ludwig 1953. Philosophical Investigations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Zahn-Waxler, Carolyn, Barbara Hollenbeck and Marian Radke-Yarrow 1984. ‘The origins of empathy and altruism’, in Fox, and Mickely, (eds), Advances in Animal Welfare Science. Humane Society of the United States.Google Scholar
Zahn-Waxler, Carolyn, Radke-Yarrow, Marian, Wagner, E. and Chapman, M. 1992. ‘Development of concern for others’, Developmental Psychology 28: 126–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zak, Paul J., and Knack, Stephen 2001. ‘Trust and growth’, Economic Journal 111: 295–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zamagni, Stefano 1995. The Economics of Altruism. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Zamagni, Stefano1999. ‘Social paradoxes of growth and civil economy’, in Gandolfo, and Marzano, (eds.), Economic Theory and Social Justice. London: Macmillan, 212–36.CrossRef

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Edited by Benedetto Gui, Università degli Studi di Padova, Italy, Robert Sugden, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Economics and Social Interaction
  • Online publication: 15 December 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511522154.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Edited by Benedetto Gui, Università degli Studi di Padova, Italy, Robert Sugden, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Economics and Social Interaction
  • Online publication: 15 December 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511522154.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Edited by Benedetto Gui, Università degli Studi di Padova, Italy, Robert Sugden, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Economics and Social Interaction
  • Online publication: 15 December 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511522154.016
Available formats
×