Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-dh8gc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-18T03:17:55.194Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Lending standards, productivity, and credit crunches

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 November 2021

Jonathan Swarbrick*
Affiliation:
University of St Andrews
*
Corresponding author. Email: j.m.swarbrick@outlook.com
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

We propose a macroeconomic model in which adverse selection in investment amplifies macroeconomic fluctuations, in line with the prominent role played by the credit crunch during the financial crisis. Endogenous lending standards emerge due to an informational asymmetry between borrowers and lenders about the riskiness of borrowers. By using loan approval probability as a screening device, banks ration credit following increases in lending risk, generating large endogenous movements in TFP, explaining why productivity often falls during crises. Furthermore, the mechanism implies that financial instability is heightened when interest rates are low.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

During downturns in economic activity, banks cut back lending both by increasing interest rates and by tightening other non-price terms such as credit scores, collateral requirements or borrowing limits (see Figure 1). The use of these non-price lending standards to vary the availability of business loans is a natural result of information asymmetries; were there no asymmetries, banks could price the risk and vary lending rates accordingly, as in any frictionless market (see Lown and Morgan (Reference Lown and Morgan2006)).

Figure 1. Net percentage of domestic banks tightening non-rate standards for commercial and industrial loans to small firms. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (BGFRS), Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices.

This paper studies the dynamics of lending standards in a macroeconomic model with an informational asymmetry between small businesses and lenders relating to the riskiness of borrowers. By using the loan approval probability as a screening device, banks ration credit in the face of heightened risk. We show that the credit friction maps to endogenous movements in both total factor productivity (TFP) and the marginal efficiency of investment, measured as the spread between the savings rate and the return on capital. This is an appealing feature because economic downturns also typically coincide with falls in TFP; prominent recent examples are the large declines in TFP across many advanced economies following the 2007–08 financial crisis. Footnote 1 In the model, adverse selection in small business lending results in occasional credit crunches when lending risk is high. We find that these episodes are observationally equivalent to TFP shocks through the lens of a standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model, helping shed light on recent crisis episodes and giving insight into the factors that might contribute to future downturns.

The proposed model is motivated by the events of the financial crisis during which informational frictions played a critical role. In the consensus view of the crisis, there was a major role played by the collapse of the asset-backed securities market driven by adverse selection, Footnote 2 and while the credit crunch that followed was partly because of banks cutting lending due to liquidity constraints in the banking sector (see, e.g. Shin (Reference Shin2009)), hidden information about borrower quality played a critical role in closing credit markets to small businesses. Footnote 3

To focus attention on small/medium-sized businesses (SMBs), we assume that only half of the firms in the model are subject to the information problem. Footnote 4 These small firms can either be highly productive and risky or less productive and safe, but their type is private information. Whereas a decentralized bond market can function well for the firms without hidden information, intermediaries can perform better by screening the small firms. We characterize the firms as small in part by assuming their projects are indivisible; while large firms might choose investment across a range of projects, a small business may seek credit to open a single store or build a new factory. Defining projects as indivisible blocks is a caricature but captures salient features of smaller businesses, in particular, being unable to diversify risk.

Although banks tighten lending standards using a variety of measures, recent survey evidence indicates that borrowers are more often unsuccessful in loan applications due to a lack of credit history and perceived tighter restrictions than due to the amount of credit requested or having insufficient collateral. Footnote 5 In our model, intermediaries can separate borrowers by offering a lottery for funding, charging risky borrowers higher interest rates by promising a higher chance of being approved for a loan. Footnote 6

This paper contributes to a body of research studying the macroeconomic effects of adverse selection in investment. For example, the Stiglitz and Weiss (Reference Stiglitz and Weiss1981) model of credit rationing, which forms our starting point, has been extended in several studies, including Bester (Reference Bester1985), Mankiw (Reference Mankiw1986), Williamson (Reference Williamson1986), De Meza and Webb (Reference De Meza and Webb1987), Besanko and Thakor (Reference Besanko and Thakor1987), and House (Reference House2006). These papers draw focus on stationary equilibria, whereas we are analyzing dynamic simulation and the mapping to business cycles.

We are perhaps more closely related to recent papers studying the dynamic effects of adverse selection, such as Eisfeldt (Reference Eisfeldt2004), Kurlat (Reference Kurlat2013), Benhabib et al. (Reference Benhabib, Dong and Wang2018), and Bigio (2015), all of which focus on the implications of adverse selection under pooling equilibria. These papers speak effectively to the distorting role of adverse selection on market liquidity, such as was observed in the asset-backed securities market during the financial crisis, but less so to a lending market in which intermediaries can separate borrowers. The distinction seems important as policies and other factors that might increase liquidity in asset markets may be powerless against adverse selection in small business lending. The focus of Benhabib et al. (Reference Benhabib, Dong and Wang2018) is the presence of multiple equilibria in models of adverse selection; while we find multiple equilibria can occur in our model, our calibrations imply a steady state that is unique and locally stable.

Other related research includes Figueroa and Leukhina (Reference Figueroa and Leukhina2018) and Cui and Kaas (Reference Cui and Kaas2020) who both study financial frictions that drive movements in productivity. In Figueroa and Leukhina (Reference Figueroa and Leukhina2018), adverse selection causes compositional effects as “bad” types are less productive entrepreneurs, unlike our model, in which borrowers always have projects with equal expected value but different degrees of risk. The results of our model are closer to those of Cui and Kaas (Reference Cui and Kaas2020); the friction is limited commitment as oppose to asymmetric information, however heightened risk similarly leads to reduced lending and lower aggregate productivity. Footnote 7

The primary focus of the recent literature linking financial factors to productivity is the interaction between heterogeneity in productivity and some form of credit friction, such as collateral constraints (Jeong and Townsend (Reference Jeong and Townsend2007); Buera and Shin (Reference Buera and Shin2013); Moll (Reference Moll2014)), causing misallocation on the intensive margin whereby capital is not allocated to most productive firms (see also Pratap and Urrutia (Reference Pratap and Urrutia2012); Oberfield (2013); Caggese and CuÑat (Reference Caggese and CuÑat2013); Gilchrist et al. (Reference Gilchrist, Sim and ZakrajŠek2013)). Footnote 8 In contrast, falls in productivity in this paper are largely driven by misallocation on the extensive margin as banks store physical capital. We think of this as equivalent to an increase in cash hoarding that reduces overall lending. Footnote 9 The empirical evidence indicates that this margin is important; for example, using UK bank data, Franklin et al. (Reference Franklin, Rostom and Thwaites2020) find that an aggregate credit supply shock of 10% leads to a fall in labor productivity of 5–8%.

The model is described in detail in the next section before we outline some key analytical results in Section 3. In Section 4, we discuss some numerical results and the implications of the credit friction on financial instability and the macroeconomy. Finally, we summarize with some concluding remarks in Section 5.

2. Model

The model extends a standard real business cycle model by differentiating between three types of firm and assuming that each firm requires a fixed quantity of external finance to purchase k units of capital. This assumption ensures that firms are reliant on outside funding. Because all firms require the same capital, the friction cannot be side-stepped by only funding a single, very large corporate firm. Every period, each firm draws a project characterized by a production technology, productivity level and a risk profile. In particular, the risk profile specifies the probability the project will fail, allowing no production. There are two types of project: one is more productive but risky and the other is less productive but safe. A proportion $\eta$ of firms have a perfectly observed project and so are suitable for raising funds via a bond market. The remaining $1-\eta$ firms have a privately observed project. Whereas a proportion $\lambda$ of these firms have no risk of default, the remaining $1-\lambda$ have a risky project that will only succeed with probability $p_t$ . Throughout the paper, the former will be referred to as safe and the latter risky, and the firms with an observable project as corporates. Under a decentralized bond market, because all borrowers seek the same amount of finance, the only screening device to separate the risky and safe project holding firms is the interest rate. In such an environment, either all firms will access funds at the same rate, or the firms with a safe project will be rationed when the interest rate is set higher than their expected return, which might occur if default losses from risky loans are too high. We will show that the presence of noncorporates gives rise to a financial intermediation sector that can do better than a bond market by screening borrowers. That is, there exists a menu of contracts that firms can self-select into, allowing lenders (banks henceforth) to identify their risk profile. We begin description of the model with the banking sector.

2.1 Intermediaries

The banks take deposits from households and extend loans to the firm sector. We assume the latter follows a two-stage game whereby lenders post-contract offers that borrowers can choose to accept. Footnote 10 This takes place in an anonymous spot market that leads to a sequence of static contracts, Footnote 11 agreed at the end of period t, ahead of period $ t+1 $ production. In addition to the interest rate, the lender introduces a lottery Footnote 12 that allows the lender to set the probability of loan approval. As shown below, this will be the device that allows the lender to separate borrowers by designing incentive-compatible, or self-selecting, contracts. Specifically, the lenders post-contracts $c_t^i =\{ \tau^i_t,x_t^i \}$ for $i\in\{s,r\}$ , where $\tau_t^i$ is the repayment rate, and $x_t^i$ the financing, or approval probability. We assume that the banks have access to a low-return technology, yielding return $r^*$ and implying that they need not lend all available funds. Footnote 13

Letting $ p_{t}^i $ and $ R_{t}^i $ denote the success probability and gross rate of return on capital of a type- i project respectively, and $ \Lambda_{t,t+1} $ the stochastic discount factor, the lender must set contract terms subject to individual rationality (IR) constraints

(1) \begin{align}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] \ge 0 , \quad i = r,s,\end{align}

which promise a weakly positive surplus to the firm, and subject to incentive compatibility (IC) constraints given by

(2) \begin{align}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i x_t^i \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] \ge \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i x_t^j \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] , \quad i,j = r,s; i\ne j.\end{align}

That is, the value to each borrower of declaring their type truthfully must be weakly greater than lying. As is standard in these mechanism design problems, and straightforward to prove, the problem can be simplified by dropping two constraints. The relevant constraints are the safe IR and the risky IC constraints, which further are found will be always binding as the objective function is increasing in the repayment rates. We can write these constraints as follows: Footnote 14

(3) \begin{gather}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \right] \tau_t^s = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} R_{t+1}^s \right], \end{gather}
(4) \begin{gather}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r \right] \tau_t^r = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r R_{t+1}^r \right] - \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r \left( R_{t+1}^r - \tau_t^s\right) \right] \frac{x_t^s}{ x_t^r} . \end{gather}

It further follows from these constraints that $x_t^r \ge x_t^s$ (see Appendix E), so risky-project firms are always weakly more likely to be funded than those with safe projects. The intuition is that in order to pay higher repayment rates, the banks must offer a higher probability of being approved for finance. The banks solve

(5) \begin{align}\mathcal{V} \left( c^s_{t-1},c^r_{t-1} \right) = \max_{c^s_t,c^r_t} & \left\lbrace \lambda x^s_{t-1} \left( \tau_{t-1}^{s} - r^*\right) + \left(1-\lambda \right) x^r_{t-1} \left( p_{t}^r \tau^r_{t-1} - r^* \right) + \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \mathcal{V}_{t+1} \left(c^s_t,c^r_t\right)\right] \right\rbrace\notag\\\mbox{s.t.} & \quad 0 \le x^s_t \le x^r_t \le 1 \notag \\& \quad \lambda x^s_t + \left(1-\lambda\right)x^r_t \leq \bar{x}_t, \end{align}

and subject to constraints (3) and (4). The inequality constraint (5) is a feasibility constraint where $\bar{x}_t \le 1$ is the maximum proportion of firm applications that can be approved. This is determined in general equilibrium and will be less than one if the number of possible loans the bank can make is less than the number of firms seeking funds, in which case it is the ratio of the loan supply to the loan demand. When this ratio is greater than unity, $\bar{x}_t$ is bound at one. When constraint (5) is slack, rather than lending all available funds, banks invest a portion of their capital in a low-return asset or technology. Equations (3) and (4) allow $ \tau_t^r $ and $ \tau_t^s $ to be substituted out of the problem, leaving only $ x_t^r $ and $ x_t^s $ to be chosen. For these, the solution to the bank’s problem gives

(6) \begin{align}& \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left(p_{t+1}^r R_{t+1}^r - r^* \right) \right] = \varrho_t - \psi_t \frac{1}{1-\lambda} + \varphi_t^r \frac{1}{1-\lambda}, \end{align}
(7) \begin{align}& \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left( \left(\lambda + \left(1-\lambda \right)p_{t+1}^r \right) R_{t+1}^{s} - r^* \right) \right] = \varrho_t + \varphi_t^r - \varphi_t^s ,\end{align}

where $\varrho_t$ is the Lagrange multiplier on the feasibility constraint, $\varphi^s_t$ and $\varphi^r_t$ those on $x^s_t$ and $1-x^r_t$ , respectively, and $\psi_t$ is the Lagrange multiplier on $x^r_t-x^s_t$ . These first-order conditions are also subject to Kuhn–Tucker conditions that include zero lower bounds on the four Lagrange multipliers: Footnote 15

(8) \begin{align} {\varphi}^s_t , {\varphi}^r_t, \varrho_t, \psi_t \ge 0 . \end{align}

Due to these four inequality constraints, it is possible to identify four regimes that depend on parametrization and macroeconomic conditions, including pooling and separating equilibria, and the credit rationing of safe projects. A financial crisis, or credit crunch, will be characterized by banks storing a portion of available capital rather than using it to fund productive firms. Analysis of these regimes is given in Section 3 below. We turn now to the firm sector.

2.2 Firms

When firms draw their type at the end of the period, they apply for external finance for which they may or may not be successful; if firms are successful in securing funds, they purchase k units of capital ready for production in the following period, otherwise we assume they must exit. Of the funded risky projects, a proportion $1-p_t^r$ will fail before production begins. Success probability $p_t^r \in [0,1]$ follows the AR(1) process:

(9) \begin{align}p_t^r =\left(1-\rho_p\right) \bar{p}^r + \rho_p p_{t-1}^r + \varepsilon_{p,t} .\end{align}

If the firm fails, then the capital is lost completely. Let firm type be denoted $i \in \{c,s,r\}$ for corporates, safe-, and risky-project holding firms, respectively. A successful funded project requires k units of capital that is converted into $ \omega^i_t k $ productive units, where we assume $\omega_t^r > \omega_t^c = \omega_t^s = 1$ . The firm hires $h_t\left(\omega_t^i\right)$ units of labor and produces output using

(10) \begin{align}y_t \left(\omega_t^i\right) = z_t \left[\omega_t^i k \right]^\alpha \left[ h_t\left(\omega_t^i\right)\right]^{1-\alpha},\end{align}

where aggregate technology $z_t$ follows the stationary stochastic process:

(11) \begin{align}\log\left(z_t\right) = \rho_z \log\left(z_{t-1}\right) + \varepsilon_{z,t}.\end{align}

Capital depreciates at $\delta$ , so although a fixed input k is required for production, the capital remaining after production will be $ \omega_t^i \left(1-\delta\right)k $ . The value of a successful funded type- i firm can therefore be written as

(12) \begin{align}V_t^i = \max_{h_t\left(\omega_t^i\right)} \left\lbrace y_t \left(\omega_t^i\right) - W_t h_t\left(\omega_t^i\right) - \left(\tau_{t-1}^i - \left(1 - \delta\right) \omega_t^i\right) k + V_{t} \right\rbrace , \end{align}

where $ W_t $ is the market wage rate and $ V_{t} $ the ex ante value of a firm, prior to drawing its type, given by

(13) \begin{align}V_{t} = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left(\eta V_{t+1}^c + \left(1-\eta\right) \left(\lambda x_{t}^s V_{t+1}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right)x_{t}^r p_{t+1}^r V_{t+1}^r \right) \right) \right] . \end{align}

The solution to the firm labor demand implies the real wage will equal the marginal product of labor for all firms

(14) \begin{align}W_t = \left( 1-\alpha \right) \frac{y_t \left(\omega_t^i\right)}{h_t\left(\omega_t^i\right)},\end{align}

where it follows that output per worker ${y}_t^i/h_t^i$ and the efficiency capital-labor ratio $\omega_t^i {k}/h_t^i$ will be equal across all firms, using superscripts for convenience. We can then write the gross return on capital used in the previous section as

(15) \begin{align}R_t^i \equiv \alpha \frac{y_t^i}{k} + \left(1-\delta \right) \omega_t^i , \end{align}

where the total surplus is $ \left(R_t^i - \tau_{t-1}^i\right) k$ and noting that the gross return on efficiency units of capital, $\alpha \frac{y_t \left(\omega_t^i\right)}{\omega_t^i k} + \left(1-\delta \right)$ , is equal for all firms. It follows that $R_t^r = \omega_t^r R_t^c = \omega_t^r R_t^s$ .

As firms can make profits in equilibrium, in the absence of costs of entry, new firms would enter until it is possible for banks to allocate all funds to firms holding risky projects, charging a higher lending rate and excluding the firms holding safe projects entirely. Footnote 16 To prevent this, we introduce a small fixed cost of entry. Any unfunded firms will be liquidated and must repay the entry costs to operate in the period that follows. To pay the entry costs, firms sell equity to households. Under this assumption, new firms will enter until the expected discounted profits $V_t$ , given by equation (13), equals an exogenous fixed cost F. This condition is verified in the solution to the household problem, which we turn to now.

2.3 Households

The representative household faces the usual labor supply and consumption-savings decision, but with an additional portfolio choice problem. The household can choose to either deposit savings $S_t$ at a bank, purchase bonds, $B_t$ , or purchase equity in new firms, $ E_t $ , to solve

\begin{align}\max_{\substack{C_{t+s},H_{t+s}\\S_{t+s},B_{t+s},f_{t+s}}}\mathbb{E}_t \sum_{s=0}^\infty \beta^{t+s} U{\left(C_{t+s},H_{t+s}\right)} , \notag\end{align}

subject to

\begin{align}C_t + S_t + B_t + E_t\left(f_t,f_{t-1}\right) = R_{t-1} S_{t-1} + R_{t-1}^B B_{t-1} +W_t H_t + \Pi_t\left(f_t\right) ,\notag\end{align}

where $R_t$ and $R_t^B$ are the interest earned on savings and bonds, respectively, $f_t$ is the end-of-period mass of firms in the economy and $\Pi_t$ are profits from the household-owned banks and payoffs from equity holdings. The household consumption-savings decision and portfolio allocation is characterized by

(16) \begin{align}& 1 = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \right] R_t , \end{align}

where $\Lambda_{t,t+1} = \beta \frac{U'\left(C_{t+1}\right)}{U_{t}'\left(C_t\right)} $ , and with $R_t^B = R_t$ . Labor supply is determined by

\begin{align}& W_t = - \frac{U'\left(H_t\right)}{U_{t}'\left(C_t\right)}. \notag\end{align}

The amount of equity purchased, $E_t$ , corresponds to the fixed costs paid for new entrants and is a claim on future profit streams of the new firms. The number of new entrants at t is the difference between the number of firms in t and the non-exiting firms in $t-1$ . It follows that expenditure on equity is given by

\begin{align}E_t = \left( f_t - \left(\eta + \left(1-\eta\right) \left(\lambda x_{t-1}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right)x_{t-1}^r \right) \right) f_{t-1} \right) k F . \notag\end{align}

Using the return on capital given in equation (15), the total profits earned by the firms per unit k given as the sum of the information rents received by risky-project firms and profits received by corporates can be written as

(17) \begin{align}& \pi_t = \left(1-\eta\right) \left(1-\lambda\right) p_{t}^r x_{t-1}^s \left(R_{t}^r - R_{t}^s \right) + \eta \left(R_t^s - R_{t-1}\right).\end{align}

Using these, the choice of the number of new firms to finance gives the first-order condition

(18) \begin{align}F = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left( \left(\eta + \left(1-\eta\right) \left(\lambda x_{t}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right)x_{t}^r \right) \right) F + \pi_{t+1} \right) \right],\end{align}

which, using equations (12) and (13), implies the entry condition $V_t=F$ . That is, the households will fund new firms until the present value of future profits equals the cost of entry. We can also define the ex post gross rate of return to banks as

(19) \begin{align}R_t^L = r^* + \left( \lambda {x}_{t-1}^s \left(\tau^s_{t-1}-r^*\right) + \left(1-\lambda\right){x}_{t-1}^r \left( p_t^r \tau^r_{t-1} - r^*\right) \right)\frac{1}{\phi_{t-1}}.\end{align}

$ \phi_{t}\equiv \frac{S_{t}}{\left(1-\eta\right)f_{t} k} $ is the loan supply-demand ratio where $\left(1-\eta\right)f_{t} k$ is the capital sought by firms, and $S_t$ the household savings that the bank is intermediating. Free-entry in the banking sector then implies the zero arbitrage condition must hold:

(20) \begin{align}1 = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} R_{t+1}^L \right]. \end{align}

Given that bank liabilities are risk-free deposits but assets are risky loans, it is possible for there to be ex post profits or losses in equilibrium. When there are profits, the household will receive a dividend, bailing out the banks when there are losses. Finally, it is assumed that the household utility function is in the form proposed in King et al. (Reference King, Plosser and Rebelo1988):

\begin{align}U \left(C_{t},H_{t}\right) = \frac{\left(C_t^{1-\chi} \left(1-H_t\right)^\chi\right)^{1-\sigma}}{1-\sigma} \notag.\end{align}

2.4 Market Clearing and Aggregation

Labor market clearing implies that total labor demanded by the three types of firm will equal the labor supplied by households, $H_t$ . An equal efficiency-capital-labor ratio follows from the perfect labor market and so, defining the aggregate efficiency capital as

(21) \begin{align}& \hat{K}_t \equiv \left[ \eta + \left(1-\eta\right) \left( \lambda x_{t-1}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) x_{t-1}^r p_t^r \omega_t^r \right) \right] k f_{t-1}, \end{align}

we can write the aggregate labor demand equation as

\begin{align}W_t = \left(1-\alpha\right) z_t \left( \frac{\hat{K}_t}{H_t} \right)^{\alpha}. \notag\end{align}

We can likewise give aggregate output as $Y_t = z_t \hat{K}_{t}^{\alpha} H_t^{1-\alpha}$ , or rather, with aggregate productivity defined as a function of the ratio of efficiency-capital to total capital stock:

(22) \begin{align}A_t = z_t \left( \frac{\hat{K}_t}{K_{t-1}} \right)^{\alpha} , \end{align}

with the familiar looking aggregate production function

(23) \begin{align}Y_t = A_t {K}_{t-1}^{\alpha} H_t^{1-\alpha}\end{align}

that follows. Finally, we close the model with an aggregate resource constraint

(24) \begin{align}Y_t = C_t + I_t,\end{align}

where investment is the difference between the new capital stock, $K_t$ , and the sum of the depreciated returned capital and the undepreciated, unused capital

(25) \begin{align}I_t &= K_t - K_{t-1} + \delta \hat{K}_t - \left(1-\eta \right) \left(1-\lambda\right)x^r_{t-1} \left( p_t^r \omega^r_t - 1 \right)k f_{t-1}.\end{align}

3 Analytical Results

The menu of contracts on offer at time t, implied by the set of inequality constraints in equation (8), can be characterized as belonging to several regimes that depend on the risk and rate of return of each project. In the subsequent theoretical and numerical analysis, we consider the role of risk by fixing the risky-project productivity $\omega_t^r = 1/p_t^r$ so the value of each firm is equal in the first-best economy. It follows that a shock to $ p_t^r $ is a risk shock. We will draw attention to two key regimes of interest: a full-lending regime and a capital-misallocation regime.

Definition 1 ((Full-lending regime)) Under this regime, banks intermediate all available funds so $ \lambda x_t^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) x_t^r = \bar{x}_t $ .

Definition 2 ((Capital-misallocation regime)) Under this regime, banks do not intermediate all available funds, so $ \lambda x_t^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) x_t^r < \bar{x}_t $ . Instead, banks use the low-return technology for a proportion of their available funds.

As banks restrict total lending, capital-misallocation is on the extensive margin as opposed to the intensive margin, whereby funds would be inefficiently allocated across projects of differing productivities. Footnote 17 By assuming $\omega_t^r = 1/p_t^r$ , we are drawing focus on the margin of interest. We can think of this misallocation as representing a credit crunch or financial crisis. In the numerical analysis discussed below, we find this to be an occasional, relatively short-lived phenomenon, much as we observe in the data.

Proposition 1 If $\omega_t^r = 1/p_t^r \forall t$ , $\bar{x}_t > 1-\lambda$ , and $R_t \ge r^*$ , then banks will choose $x_t^s \le x_t^r = 1$ .

Proposition 1 highlights that the contract outcomes simplify when only considering the role of risk. Footnote 18 In particular, if $\omega_t^r = 1/p_t^r$ , a pooling equilibrium is ruled out except for when $\bar{x}_t=1$ . Footnote 19 However, under our model calibrations, pooling rarely occurs in numerical simulations. To see why, suppose that household saving increases such that all firms looking for funds could receive them (that is, $\bar{x}_t$ increases to 1) and suppose a single non-separating contract was on offer. Given these conditions, because the lender absorbs all default losses, successful risky-project firms will earn higher profits as their repayment rate falls. This increase in the return on equity will encourage higher firm entry. As more firms enter, $\bar{x}_t$ falls, causing $x_t^s$ to fall, reducing the information rents and the value of equity. As well as keeping $\bar{x}_t$ from the upper abound, these competing forces prevent $\bar{x}_t$ from falling low. Indeed, it follows the condition $\bar{x}_t > 1-\lambda$ required in Proposition 1 always holds in our numerical simulations under empirically plausible parameterizations. Footnote 20 Let us consider the two regimes of interest.

Corollary 1 There is a threshold expected default rate, $d_t^* = \mathbb{E}_t\left[ 1 - {p_{t+1}^*} \right]$ , that satisfies

\begin{align} & \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^* R_{t+1}^{s}\right] = \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left(R_{t+1}^{s} - \frac{\lambda } {1-\lambda } \left( R_{t+1}^{s} - r^* \right) \right) \right], \notag \end{align}

whereby the economy will be in the full-lending regime when $\mathbb{E}_t\left[ 1 - {p_{t+1}^r} \right] \le d_t^*$ and the capital-misallocation regime when $\mathbb{E}_t\left[ 1 - {p_{t+1}^r} \right] > d_t^*$ .

Proposition 2 The threshold expected default rate, $d_t^*$ , rises in the interest rate.

The point at which the economy switches regimes occurs when the expected default rate of risky projects rises above the threshold $d_t^*$ . This is found by combining the first-order conditions (6) into (7) and finding the point at which $\varrho_t$ , the Lagrange multiplier on the feasibility constraint, equals zero. In the deterministic case, we can state, more succinctly, that if the expected default rate

(26) \begin{align}& d_t >\frac{\lambda } {1-\lambda } \left( 1 - \frac{r^*}{R_{t+1}^{s}} \right) , \end{align}

then banks will restrict credit to firms with safe projects. We can see that, conditional on $ r^* $ , $d_t^*$ depends positively on both the proportion of safe projects in the economy and on the return on capital. Proposition 2 follows given the link between the expected return to capital $\mathbb{E}_t \left[ R_{t+1}^s\right]$ and the real interest rate, $R_t$ . This threshold and its partial equilibrium relationship with the real rate of return is represented in Figure 2. This shows the information rents increasing in the default rate up to the point at which the lender will optimally ration credit to safe projects. Footnote 21 This result helps rationalize evidence on whom credit tightening is concentrated. While lenders tighten credit standards during downturns, a puzzling feature of these episodes is that, conditional on observables, loan rejection rates often increase more for lower-risk small businesses than higher-risk small businesses. We present evidence in support of this in Appendix A. Footnote 22

Figure 2. Partial equilibrium results: division of returns under asymmetric information under different first-best rates of return on capital.

While this might seem inconsistent with evidence that the quality of corporate borrowers rises in downturns (see, e.g. Greenwood and Hanson (Reference Greenwood and Hanson2011)), note that the phenomena is observed on bank lending to small business as oppose to the corporate bond market. In the data, increased uncertainty can drive investors to look for safer or more liquid assets during recessions (Baele et al. (Reference Baele, Bekaert, Inghelbrecht and Wei2020)). The informational friction we study prevents increased lending to safe small firms, rather the flight-to-safety in our model drives investors to corporate borrowing and to the safe storage technology. So although lending to safe small businesses falls, because of an increase in corporate borrowing, we still capture the feature that borrower quality rises in downturns.

In general equilibrium, when $d_t > d_t^*$ , the lender stores capital rather than provide finance to all firms with safe projects. This reduces the efficiency of the aggregate capital stock, as captured in equation (21), and so appears as a shock to aggregate productivity. In addition to this mechanism, we find that the information rents introduce a time-varying spread between the expected return to capital, $\mathbb{E}_t \left[ R_{t+1}^s\right]$ , and savings rate, $R_t$ . While changes in risk will have no effect on the spread in the first-best economy, with hidden information, the firms holding risky projects earn higher rents when risk is greater, reducing the marginal efficiency of investment. In this way, the agency problem acts to increase the volatility of movements in the spread beyond what can be accounted for with evolutions in the default risk, linking our results to literature discussing the “credit spread puzzle” (see Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek (Reference Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek2012)). Footnote 23 We note that this produces a countercyclical spread and can magnify the propagation of other shocks to the extent they effect default rates. We refer to these effects as the financial accelerator mechanism.

3.1 Two Channels

To draw comparison with the RBC model, we can identify two channels by which financial disturbances affect real macroeconomic outcomes. The first is an “investment-wedge” channel, whereby the adverse selection affects the marginal efficiency of investment primarily through movements in the information rents. This inefficiency is measured by the spread between the savings rate and the return to capital which, using the average return on bank lending (19) and the firm lending rates (3)–(4), can be given by

(27) \begin{align}\Delta_t \equiv \mathbb{E}_t \left[\left(1-\lambda\right) \left( 1 - p_{t+1}^r\right) {x}_{t}^s R_{t+1}^s + \left( R_{t+1}^s - r^* \right) \left(\phi_t - \lambda x_t^s - \left(1-\lambda\right)x_t^r\right) \right] \frac{1}{\phi_t} . \end{align}

From this we can see that two factors contribute to this wedge: the information rents, measured by $ \left(1-\lambda\right) \left( 1 - p_{t+1}^r\right) {x}_{t}^s$ , and a capital-misallocation effect in the second term. This misallocation occurs when banks use their low-return technology, rationing credit to borrowers, as the average rate of return on lending must fall relative to the return on capital. Recall that $\phi_t$ is the loan supply-demand ratio, so if all household savings are intermediated to firms, it follows that the condition $\phi_t = \bar{x}_t = \lambda x_t^s + \left(1-\lambda\right)x_t^r$ holds and this effect disappears. The information rents increase in the expected default rate, and because banks can only reduce them by lowering $ x_t^s $ and rationing credit to firms with safe projects, one can see that if the default rate increases sufficiently, the contribution of the misallocation effect will rise.

The second channel is the efficiency wedge, whereby the credit friction generates movements in total factor productivity during the capital-misallocation regime. From equation (22), this can be written as

(28) \begin{align}A_t = z_t \left( \frac{\eta + \left(1-\eta\right) \left( \lambda x_{t-1}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) x_{t-1}^r \right)}{ \eta + \left(1-\eta\right) \phi_{t-1} } \right)^{\alpha} \le z_t . \end{align}

If banks are intermediating all available funds, then, as before, $\phi_t = \bar{x}_t = \lambda x_t^s + \left(1-\lambda\right)x_t^r$ , and TFP just depends on exogenous technology $ z_t $ . When the adverse selection problem for the bank increases, due to increased risky-project firm default, for example, then banks restrict credit to firms by reducing $ x_t^s $ and $A_t$ falls. Footnote 24

4. Numerical Analysis

To provide an appropriate benchmark case, we use the same model with the information asymmetry removed. This first-best economy is analogous to a standard real business cycle model; absent the information problem, all firms can be considered equivalent to corporates, and so are able to raise funds in the bond market. Another version of the model is also considered in the analysis to assess the mapping from the credit friction to the interest spread and TFP. For this exercise, the real business cycle model is simulated with the fluctuations in the spread between the savings rate and the expected return to capital implied by the adverse selection economy. Because this introduces a wedge in the marginal efficiency of investment, we refer to this as the “investment wedge” model; it allows us to effectively “switch off” the TFP channel. The exercise reinforces the results from the previous section: if one assumes the economy to be in the full-lending regime in steady state, in the region of the steady state, the credit friction only maps to fluctuations in the interest spread. This produces a financial accelerator mechanism that magnifies the effects of changes to default risk. Larger adverse shocks, however, can cause the economy to switch to a capital-misallocation regime in which lenders restrict credit, choosing to store capital rather than finance all safe projects. For instance, if the default rate of firms with risky projects increases by around 3% from the ergodic mean, credit rationing occurs, and, through the lens of a real business cycle model, appears as a negative shock to TFP, dominating the effects of the investment wedge in all but the marginal cases.

4.1 Parametrization and Calibration

In addition to the parameters common to the real business cycle (RBC) literature, we are left with several parameters specific to the adverse selection economy. The size of firms is pinned down by the required capital, k; however, this has no effect on aggregate outcomes, and so we set $ k=1 $ without loss of generality. Footnote 25 The share of corporate firms, $\eta$ , is set to 0.5 in line with the proportion of employment at establishments with greater than 500 employees. Footnote 26 We calibrate $\lambda=0.775$ , $p=0.971$ , and $ F =0.149$ to target the proportion of risky bank loans, the mean firm entry rate, and the mean loan default rate. For the former, we target 24%, which is the average share of bank loans classified as “acceptable risk” over the interval 1997Q2–2017Q2. Footnote 27 For the latter, we target a value of 2.8% per annum, taken from the average delinquency rate on commercial and industrial loans over the period 1987Q1–2017Q1. Footnote 28 Finally, we target a mean annual firm entry rate of 12.5% in line with the average entry of US establishments over the period 1977–2014. Footnote 29 We set $ r^* $ to 1 so the low-return asset is a storage technology. Footnote 30

These calibrations are listed in Table 1. For the remaining parameters, we closely follow the RBC literature. The capital share of output $\alpha = 0.3$ ; capital depreciates at $\delta = $ 2.3% per quarter; and the household discount factor $\beta =$ 0.99. The utility weight on leisure, $\chi = 0.64$ to target a steady-state labor supply $H=1/3$ , and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, $\sigma = 2$ . These are all shown in Table 2. We calibrate the shock processes using a simulated method of moments approach; some further detail is given in the next section.

Table 1. Calibrations of adverse selection model parameters

Table 2. Parametrization of common real business cycle parameters.

4.2 Simulations

We compute a second-order pruned perturbation approximation to the model and impose the inequality constraints following the algorithm of Holden (Reference Holden2016). Footnote 31 We draw comparison to the first-best economy, which is equivalent to the standard RBC model. Footnote 32 To calibrate the persistence parameter, we estimate an autoregression of TFP with a linear trend, Footnote 33 finding $ \rho_z = 0.978$ . The remaining parameters controlling the shock processes are calibrated to target second moments and cross-correlations. The standard deviation of the technology shock was calibrated to $ \sigma_a = 0.00619 $ , Footnote 34 while the standard deviation and persistence of the risk shock were calibrated to $ \sigma_p = 0.00633 $ and $ \rho_p = 0.800 $ , respectively. Footnote 35 We did initially include a shock to the relative value of risky projects, but this was calibrated to zero.

4.2.1 Unconditional moments

To gain some insight into the empirical performance of the model as compared to the financially efficient model, we report simulated and empirical moments in Table 3. The model does well at matching the observed skewness in output and investment despite not being targeted in the calibration. Including the risk shock reduces the procyclicality of consumption and leads to a negative correlation between the interest spread and output. Although a countercyclical response of consumption might seem to count against the model setup, the response is non-monotonic; for risk shocks large enough to cause financial crisis, because the mechanism maps to a decline in TFP, consumption can fall, as it would in the RBC model with a negative technology shock. The simulated moments reflect that the risk shock has no effect on the RBC model. Furthermore, although not targets in the calibration, the mean and standard deviation of the spread between the average rate of return on capital and the risk-free rate, $ \Delta_t $ , is 0.64 and 0.181 percentage points, respectively. This is close to 0.57 and 0.178 percentage points, which are the observed first and second moments of the spread between Moody’s BAA corporate bond and 10-year Treasury bond yields. Footnote 36

Table 3. Simulated and empirical moments. Data for Y, I, and C is HP-filtered US time series 1983Q2–2016Q2; investment wedge, $ \Delta $ , is the spread between Moody’s BAA-rated corporate bond yields and 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity. Simulated time series of Y, I, and C are HP-filtered. Standard deviations are in percent for Y, I, and C and percentage points for $\Delta$ .

4.2.2 Impulse response functions

We now turn to the analysis of the propagation of the risk shock, which is an exogenous increase in the default rate of firms with risky projects, caused by a decline in the success probability, $p_t^r$ . Footnote 37 The central result is that risk matters as a first-order issue. While the disturbance generates economic fluctuations in our model, the value of projects remain equal under symmetric information because $\omega_t^r = 1/p_t^r$ , leaving the first-best economy unaffected. Whereas without hidden information, the only important factor regarding firm finance is the expected discounted value, with adverse selection, the increased risk leads to higher information rents and so an increase in the investment wedge. Figure 3 shows impulse response functions to a 1 standard deviation risk shock, that is, an increase in the default rate of 0.63 percentage points. By widening the investment wedge, the increased default rate leads to a sharp 2% downturn in investment. Facing a lower interest rate, households substitute investment for consumption, dampening the overall fall in aggregate demand, which only shrinks by 0.2%. The share of risky loans increases as banks reduce funding to firms holding safe projects, allowing the banks to charge risky borrowers a higher repayment rate, $ \tau^r $ .

Figure 3. Impulse response functions to a 1 standard deviation (SD) transitory risk shock. Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, and C, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $ , $ \Delta $ , and R.

Figure 4 shows expected impulse responses found by increasing the shock to reach the default threshold, $d_{t}^*$ . In this case, the probability of risky-project firm default increases by 3 percentage points, and, due to higher information rents, leads to banks rationing credit to firms with safe projects to charge firms with risky ones higher repayment rates. While the proportion of safe projects that are approved for finance, $ x^s $ , falls in both Figures 3 and 4, the former is a general equilibrium result caused by the fall in household saving being greater than the fall in firm numbers, whereas the latter is due, in part, to banks being unwilling to lend all available funds. This leads to a sharp decline in TFP and much sharper contractions in investment and output. Figure 4 also plots a version of the model with the TFP channel “switched off.” This allows us to assess the relative contribution from the endogenous variation in the investment wedge and TFP. For smaller shocks, as in Figure 3, the financial friction is affecting the real economy via the investment wedge, whereas for larger shocks, fluctuations can be mapped to both the investment wedge and TFP.

Figure 4. Impulse response functions to a transitory risk shock of 3% points comparing our model (black line) with a version with the TFP “switched off” (gray line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, C, and A, and percent point deviation for $ x^s $ and $ \Delta $ .

In this framework, the focus is on supply-side frictions. To model episodes such as the 2007–09 recession, it is necessary to add an exogenous demand-side disturbance. In Figure 5, we plot expected impulse response functions to a combination of the risk shock and a negative demand shock. For the latter, we employ an unexpected increase in $ \beta $ of 0.0015. Footnote 38 The time preference shock occurs simultaneously with a 4.1% shock to the default of firms holding risky projects. Footnote 39 The financial friction affects real outcomes via the same channels just discussed. Quantitatively, the crisis experiment can capture much of the observed movements in 2008. In the UK, for example, between 2008Q1 and 2009Q2, new loans to SMEs fell by 21%, real GDP fell by 6.13%, real investment by 21.8%, and real consumption by 5.89%. Footnote 40 With the exception of consumption, the magnitudes of responses shown in Figure 5 are close to that in the data. Furthermore, the 3.3% decline in TFP closely matches that of the OECD measure of multifactor productivity for the UK over the same period, found to be 3.24%. Footnote 41 Note that given the size of the contraction in investment, without the sharp fall in TFP, it would not be possible to generate the size of the decline in output. Other papers employ shortcuts to account for this issue, including exogenous TFP shocks (e.g. Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Trabandt2015)) and capital quality shocks (e.g. Gertler and Kiyotaki (Reference Gertler and Kiyotaki2010)).

Figure 5. Impulse response functions to a simultaneous time-preference shock and risk shock comparing our model (black line) with the RBC model (blue dashed). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, C, and A, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $ and $ \Delta $ .

4.3 Robustness

Some robustness checks of the parametrization were carried out on both the implied deterministic steady state and the model dynamics. The choice of parameters controlling preferences and production technology are standard; we focus on the novel parametrization, beginning with their impact on the steady-state equilibrium. Specifically, we test the parameter calibration by ignoring the target, choosing alternative values, but recalibrating the other parameters to hit the other calibration targets. Increasing the share of firms that have an observable state, $ \eta $ , dilutes the asymmetric information problem. The financial constraints in the banking sector are independent of $\eta $ , so the default threshold leading to credit tightening is unchanged. However, because the proportion of firms affected by adverse selection falls in $ \eta $ , the impact of credit crunches on aggregate outcomes weakens, and fluctuations in TFP are smaller. If we consider secular increases in $ \eta $ , Footnote 42 holding other parameters constant, we find that, although having a smaller impact on the macroeconomy, credit crunches occur with higher frequency. Because new firms have an increased probability of being a corporate, and receiving surplus $ \mathbb{E}_t \left[ R_{t+1}^s-R_t \right]$ , firm entry goes up. The larger number of firms and, in particular, the larger proportion of observable-project corporates reduces the interest spread and the average return on capital. As highlighted in Proposition 2, a lower capital return shifts the default threshold down, so it takes a smaller rise in default to generate credit contractions.

The fixed cost of entry, F, is chosen to target the rate of firm entry. Increasing F will reduce firm entry and thus raise profits until the value of a new firm, $ V_t = F $ . Fewer firms will result in a higher return on capital and increased investment wedge. This would cause the default threshold, $ d^* $ , to shift down; however, with fewer firms seeking loans, the proportion of firms with safe projects that receive funds, $ x^s $ , increases, raising $ d^* $ . To hit the calibration target of the share of risky loans, $ \lambda $ is calibrated to a lower value so there are fewer safe projects in the economy. This moves $ d^* $ down again, reinforcing the effect of a higher return to capital and causing an overall increase in financial instability under higher entry costs. The combined effect, however, is fairly modest.

As would be expected given their role in the optimal contract, the calibrations of p and $\lambda$ do have a significant impact on both the stationary and dynamic equilibrium. If $\lambda$ is increased, the adverse selection problem weakens because, with fewer risky borrowers, the information rents are reduced. Footnote 43 Furthermore, a lower $ \lambda $ or $ \bar{p} $ also imply great financial instability. Footnote 44 Fewer safe projects imply higher information rents, shifting in the default threshold so credit contractions become more likely (see equation (26)). Likewise, a higher steady-state default rate would be closer to the threshold, $ d^* $ , so a smaller risk shock would be needed to reach it.

4.4 Instability and the Real Interest Rate

As stated in Proposition 2, the interest rate affects the likelihood of a credit contraction as the default threshold, $ d^* $ , above which the economy will be in the capital-misallocation regime, rises in the interest rate. Figure 6 plots the impulse response functions to a 1 standard deviation risk shock, as in Figure 3, but this time including a simulation with $ \beta = 0.993 $ , thus cutting $ \bar{R} $ by a bit more than 1% annualized. The reduced interest rate shifts $ d^* $ such that a 1 standard deviation shock is large enough to cause banks to restrict lending, leading to a sharp downturn.

Figure 6. Impulse response functions to a 1 SD transitory risk shock comparing baseline calibration (black line) with a low $ \bar{R} $ calibration (gray line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, and C, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $ , $ \Delta $ , and R.

The result of financial instability with lower interest rates finds support in the data. Figure 7 plots 10-year rolling averages of the real interest rate and output volatility. Footnote 45 There is a negative trend on the whole dataset; however, it is interesting to sort the data into three subsets. The red squares represent the middle episode, 1977–1987, which, by virtue of the rolling window, captures observations from 1972 and includes the impact of the 1973 oil crisis and heightened volatility in the 1970s and early 1980s. The green circles include data between 1988 and 2011, covering the Great Moderation, and the black diamonds represent observations between 1966 and 1976. The negative relationship between the real interest rate and volatility supports our results. Shifts in these curves are likely due to structural factors not in the model, such as the evolving size and nature of financial markets, but could also be partly explained by the share of small establishments, which has been in steady decline. Footnote 46 A higher share of large firms would reduce the adverse selection and indicate a dampening of volatility and could, in part, lie behind the reduced volatility during the Great Moderation, off-setting the declining real interest rate.

Figure 7. Ten-year rolling average US real interest rates against 10-year rolling average US output volatility. 1966–1976 black diamonds; 1978–1987 red squares; and 1988–2011 green circles.

Figure 8. Average impulse response functions to a positive transitory shock to technology $z_t$ of 1% for our model (black line) and the RBC (blue dashed). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage point deviation from ergodic mean for R and $ \Delta $ , and percent deviation for other variables.

Figure 9. Percent of reporting small and medium businesses that applied for loans but were denied credit. United Kingdom, 2011–2017. Four quarter moving average. Source: SME Finance Monitor, BDRC Continental.

5. Conclusion

Banks vary the availability of business loans in response to economic conditions by both adjusting interest rates and by varying credit standards. These non-price standards play a potentially important but underexamined role in generating business cycles in advanced economies. In this paper, we have presented a model in which endogenous credit standards emerge from an information asymmetry between bank and borrower relating to a project’s riskiness, the result of which are occasional credit crunches that are observationally equivalent to exogenous productivity shocks through the lens of a standard DSGE model. This contributes to a literature studying models with endogenous volatility in TFP. The existing macroeconomic literature on financial frictions has largely concentrated on mechanisms in which movements are due to misallocation of factors on the intensive margin, that is, capital not being allocated to the most productive firms. In this paper, the misallocation occurs on the extensive margin, where banks restrict the total volume of lending and store capital instead. Footnote 47 The evidence has indicated that both margins affect cyclical movements in TFP (see, e.g. Franklin et al. (Reference Franklin, Rostom and Thwaites2020)).

The mechanism is simple. Firms vary in their privately observed risk, even when expected pay-offs are the same. Lenders can separate borrowers by offering loans with different pairs of interest rates and loan approval ratings; risky borrowers will choose higher interest rates with higher approval probabilities, while safer borrowers will choose lower interest rates with lower approval probabilities. This positive correlation between loan interest rates and approval probabilities finds support in the data. When risky projects are very risky, the lenders will ration credit to firms holding safe projects in order to raise risky borrowing rates, causing drops in TFP. Due to the effect on productivity, through the lens of an RBC model, the risk shock appears as a combination of a negative technology shock and a tax on the return to capital. In the majority of existing macroeconomic models, however, the financial friction only emerges as the latter. This difference allows the model to capture the size of the fall in output observed during the financial crisis without requiring exogenous capital quality or productivity shocks.

The mechanism also introduces a financial accelerator that can help explain why spreads are more volatile than would be expected by changes in the default premia (the credit spread puzzle, see Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek (Reference Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek2012)). Furthermore, the default threshold increases in the interest rate, implying that financial instability, and therefore volatility, is heightened with low interest rates, as supported by the empirical evidence (see Figure 7).

In the model, credit rationing is concentrated on safe SMEs, while risky and corporate firms do not face non-price borrowing restrictions. During the 2008–2009 financial crisis, contractions in credit primarily affected the bank lending channel, so, as corporate firms have access to alternative sources of finance (see De Fiore and Uhlig (Reference De Fiore and Uhlig2015)), the adverse effects fell predominantly on SMEs (see also Fraser (Reference Fraser2012)). Furthermore, we have presented evidence that while credit standards were tightened overall during the downturn with a significant increase in loan rejection rates for less-risky small businesses conditional on observables, riskier firms did not face significantly higher rejection rates (see also Armstrong et al. (Reference Armstrong, Davis, Liadze and Rienzo2013)).

In summary, we have presented a novel contribution to our understanding of the channels by which financial disturbances might have real effects. Particularly relevant currently are the increased risks associated with lower interest rates.

The paper was previously circulated with the title: “Adverse Selection and Financial Crises.” I am grateful to Tom Holden, Cristiano Cantore, Paul Levine, Vasco Gabriel, Antonio Mele, Dave Cannell, Martin Eichenbaum, Ben Moll, Charles Kahn, Stefano Gnocchi, William Barnett, an associate editor, and two anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. I am also grateful for comments from discussants and participants at several workshops and conferences. This paper was based on a doctoral thesis chapter; the financial support by the Economic and Social Research Council [grant number ES/J500148/1] during this time is gratefully acknowledged.

Appendix A. Regression Results

Table 3 presents results from a probit regression using 2011–2017 UK survey data from the SME Finance Monitor Footnote 48 from which we find that low and average risk firms experienced significantly increased rejection probabilities during periods of higher loan rejection rates relative to the 2017, whereas above average risk firms did not.

The dependent variable is the probability of loan rejection conditional on application and several control variables, including the legal status of the firm, the sector, turnover, age and number of employees. Following Armstrong et al. (Reference Armstrong, Davis, Liadze and Rienzo2013), the regression is run separately for low, average and above average risk firms using the Dun and Bradstreet risk ratings included in the dataset. The relevant takeaway is that loan rejection rates were significantly higher between 2011 and 2013 when compared to 2017 for low and average risk firms, but not so for above average risk firms.

Although the survey only begins in 2011, because loan rejection rates remained heightened and, indeed, peaked in late 2013, the sample is still indicative. See Figure 9 in the Appendix D which plots the rate of firms rejected for loans over time.

A.1 Data Source

Data from the Small- and Medium-Sized Enterprise Finance Monitor, 2011–2017 was used. Footnote 49 . Loan rejection is the proportion of firms reporting yes to having “Applied for a new bank loan or commercial mortgage (whether agreed or not)” in the last 12 months, that reported the initial response of the bank: “You were turned down for a loan”. With the loan rejection the dependant variable, conditional on having applied for a loan, we estimate a pooled probit model with bootstrap standard errors. The following indicator variables were used: wave (2011q2–2017q4); legal status; age of the business; sector; turnover bracket; number of employees. Replication codes are provided on request.

Appendix B. Description of Solution Method

This appendix briefly describes the solution and simulation method used to generate model moments and impulse response functions. The presence of inequality constraints stemming from the lending problem are incorporated into the model solution using the algorithm used is that proposed in Holden (Reference Holden2016, Reference Holden2019) for which there is a toolkit available at https://github.com/tholden/dynareOBC.

We first compute a second-order policy function using Dynare, employing the pruning algorithm of Lan and Meyer-Gohde (Reference Lan and Meyer-Gohde2013), then use the Holden (Reference Holden2016) shadow-shock approach to impose the occasionally binding constraints (OBCs) during model simulation. This approach adds partially anticipated, endogenous “shocks” to the bounded equations to ensure the constraints are satisfied. During simulation, a stochastic extended path approach is employed to capture uncertainty about these shocks (see Adjemian and Juillard (Reference Adjemian and Juillard2013); Swarbrick (Reference Swarbrick2021)). Every period of the simulation, expectations of the future shadow-shocks are integrated out up to 32 periods. This captures the effects of the future risk of the inequality constraints binding up to 32 periods into the future. We find that increasing this horizon further has negligible impact on simulation results.

Appendix C. Propagation of Technology Shocks

Following a positive transitory shock to aggregate productivity, $z_t$ , in both our model and the RBC model there is an increase in all variables via the standard channel. Plots of impulse response functions to a positive shock to $z_t$ of 1% are shown in Figure 8. In the adverse selection economy, both risky and safe project returns increase, and there is a small rise in the interest spread, $ \Delta_t $ . On first look, investment and consumption appear more volatile in the model with adverse selection, but output less so. This is a compositional effect; while the steady-state share of investment in our model is about 17.4% of GDP, in line with the US data, the share is 20.8% of GDP in the RBC model. This follows from the parameterization of $ \delta $ , $ \beta $ and $ \alpha $ . The additional volatility is caused by the presence of a positive steady-state spread, reducing the average level of investment and consumption. If the RBC model were solved with a constant spread equal to the average spread in our model, we would actually observe a small deceleration effect as the information rents increase, mildly reducing the marginal efficiency of investment. However, the effect is quantitatively negligible.

Appendix D. Figures

Appendix E. Contract Conditions

The IR and IC constraints are

(29) \begin{gather}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] \ge 0 , \quad i = r,s, \end{gather}
(30) \begin{gather}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i x_t^i \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] \ge \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^i x_t^j \left( R_{t+1}^i - \tau_t^i \right) \right] , \quad i,j = r,s; i\ne j .\end{gather}

There must be one binding IR and one binding IC constraint. Given that $ R_{t+1}^r > R_{t+1}^s \ge \tau^s_t $ , we can write

(31) \begin{align}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r x_t^r \left( R_{t+1}^r - \tau_t^r \right) \right] &\ge \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r x_t^s \left( R_{t+1}^r - \tau_t^s \right) \right], \end{align}
(32) \begin{align}&> \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r x_t^s \left( R_{t+1}^s - \tau_t^s \right) \right] \ge 0 .\end{align}

Then $\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^s \left( R_{t+1}^s - \tau_t^s \right) \right] \ge 0$ must be the binding IR constraint, which implies that (31) is the binding IC constraint. Using the binding safe IR constraint, the safe IC constraint can be written as

(33) \begin{gather}0 \ge \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^s x_t^r \left( \tau_t^s - \tau_t^r \right) \right],\end{gather}

implying $ \tau_t^r \ge \tau_t^s $ . Substituting this into the binding risky IC constraint yields

(34) \begin{align}\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r x_t^r \left( R_{t+1}^r - \tau_t^r \right) \right] \ge \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} p_{t+1}^r x_t^s \left( R_{t+1}^r - \tau_t^r \right) \right],\end{align}

from which $ x_t^r \ge x_t^s $ follows.

E.1 Solution

The solution to the lenders’ problem yields

(35) \begin{align}& \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left(p_{t+1}^r R_{t+1}^r - r^* \right) \right] = \varrho_t - \psi_t \frac{1}{1-\lambda} + \varphi_t^r \frac{1}{1-\lambda}, \end{align}
(36) \begin{align}& \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \left( \left(\lambda + \left(1-\lambda \right)p_{t+1}^r \right) R_{t+1}^{s} - r^* \right) \right] = \varrho_t + \varphi_t^r - \varphi_t^s.\end{align}

These taken with the following Kuhn–Tucker conditions:

(37) \begin{align}& {\varphi}^s_t \ge 0, \end{align}
(38) \begin{align}& {\varphi}^r_t \ge 0, \end{align}
(39) \begin{align}& \varrho_t \ge 0, \end{align}
(40) \begin{align}& \psi_t \ge 0, \end{align}
(41) \begin{align}& {\varphi}^s_t x^s_t = 0, \end{align}
(42) \begin{align}& {\varphi}^r_t \left(1-x^r_t\right) = 0, \end{align}
(43) \begin{align}& \psi_t \left(x^r_t - x^s_t \right) =0, \end{align}
(44) \begin{align}& \varrho_t \left(\bar{x}_t - \lambda x_t^s - \left(1-\lambda\right) x_t^r\right) = 0 ,\end{align}

imply the outcome to the contract problem

Appendix F. Proofs

Proof 1 (Proof of Proposition 1). Using equations (19) and (20) with $ p_{t}^rR_{t}^r = R_t^s $ , we find

\begin{align} \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} R_{t+1}^s \right] = \frac{\phi_t + \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} \right] \left( \lambda {x}_{t}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) {x}_{t}^r - \phi_t\right) r^*}{ \lambda {x}_{t}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) \left( {x}_{t}^r - {x}_{t}^s \left(1- \mathbb{E}_t \left[ p_{t+1}^r \right]\right) \right) } , \notag \end{align}

where $\phi_t\equiv \frac{S_{t}}{\left(1-\eta\right)f_{t} k}\ge \lambda {x}_{t}^s + \left(1-\lambda\right) {x}_{t}^r$ . It follows that $\mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1} R_{t+1}^s \right] > 1$ if

\begin{align} \mathbb{E}_t \left[1 - \Lambda_{t,t+1} r^* \right] \left( \phi_t - \lambda {x}_{t}^s - \left(1-\lambda\right) {x}_{t}^r \right) > - \left(1-\lambda\right) \left( {x}_{t}^s \mathbb{E}_t\left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1}\left(1- p_{t+1}^r \right)R_t \right] \right) ,\notag \end{align}

which must hold when $\mathbb{E}_t \left[\Lambda_{t,t+1}r^*\right] \le 1$ , which will when $ r^* \le R_t$ . It follows from equation (6) that $\varrho + \varphi_t^r > 0$ . Substituting equation (6) into (7) then yields

\begin{align} & \mathbb{E}_t \left[ \Lambda_{t,t+1}\left(1-p_{t+1}^r\right) R_{t+1}^s \right] = \varphi_t^s - \psi_t \frac{1}{1-\lambda} + \varphi_t^r \frac{\lambda}{1-\lambda}, \notag \end{align}

$p_t^r < 1 \forall t$ , and therefore $\varphi_t^s + \varphi_t^r > 0$ . It is straightforward to see from conditions (41)–(44) that if $\varphi_t^s>0$ , then $\varrho = 0$ . Therefore, $\varphi_t^r > 0$ and $x_t^r = 1$ .

Table 4. Predictive margins of year effect on rejection probabilities relative to 2017. Details are in Appendix A.

p-values in parentheses

$^{\star} p<0.05$ , $^{\star\star} p<0.01$ , $^{\star\star\star} p<0.001$

p-values in parentheses

$^{\star} p<0.05$ , $^{\star\star} p<0.01$ , $^{\star\star\star} p<0.001$

Footnotes

1 One notable exception to this was rising productivity in the USA during the Great Recession. However, productivity fell during previous recessionary episodes in the USA, for example, in 1982 (Chari et al. (Reference Chari, Kehoe and McGrattan2007)), and fell in most other advanced economies during the Great Recession.

2 See, for example, Beltran and Thomas (Reference Beltran and Thomas2010), Morris and Shin (Reference Morris and Shin2012), Bertsch (Reference Bertsch2013) and Camargo and Lester (Reference Camargo and Lester2014).

3 For instance, former Bank of England Governor Mervyn King attributed the collapse of small business and mortgage lending to adverse selection in his Mansion House speech, June 2012 (http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/economics/9332296/Sir-Mervyn-Kings-Mansion-House-speech-in-full.html). Although fairly uncontroversial, the empirical literature assessing the importance of adverse selection in credit markets is relatively limited and inconclusive. Crawford et al. (Reference Crawford, Pavanini and Schivardi2018) and Albertazzi et al. (Reference Albertazzi, Bottero, Gambacorta and Ongena2017) separately find evidence for adverse selection in Italian lending markets. Cressy and Toivanen (Reference Cressy and Toivanen2001) find no evidence for adverse selection in 1987–1990 UK bank lending data, whereas Tang (Reference Tang2009) provides evidence of asymmetric information in the US credit markets using a Moody’s credit rating refinement in 1982, and finds that it has significant impact on economic outcomes.

4 Between 1988 and 2015 small and medium-sized businesses made up approximately 50% of employment in the USA. Source: The Statistics of US Businesses (SUSB). See also footnote 4.1.

5 See, for example, Table 2, p. 5 of Robb and Farhat (Reference Robb and Farhat2013) and p. 8 of Battisto et al. (Reference Battisto, de Zeeuw, Mills, Lieberman and Wiersch2018). See, also, Figure 9 in the appendix which highlights how much loan approval rates can vary; rising, in the UK, from 65% in late 2013 to around 85% less than 3 years later.

6 There is evidence for this relationship in the data because banks that are more likely to approve loan applications tend to charge higher interest rates. In 2015, 58% of business loan applications to large banks were approved, whereas 76% of applications to small banks were; the average interest rate charged on business loans classed as moderate risk was 2.38% by large domestic banks, but 4.13% by small domestic banks. Source for approval rating from Barkley et al. (Reference Barkley, Mills, Recto, Terry and Wavering2016) and for interest rates from the FRB E.2. Survey of Terms of Business Lending.

7 Other recent research includes Reichlin and Siconolfi (Reference Reichlin and Siconolfi1998) who analyzes a similar adverse selection problem in a stationary overlapping-generations model, finding it can generate persistent endogenous cycles; Martin (Reference Martin2009), who analyzes the relationship between entrepreneur wealth and investment under adverse selection; Guerrieri et al. (2010), who examine search equilibria with adverse selection (see also Williamson and Wright (Reference Williamson and Wright1994); Rocheteau (Reference Rocheteau2011); Lester et al. (Reference Lester, Postlewaite and Wright2011); Chiu and Koeppl (Reference Chiu and Koeppl2016)); Scheuer (Reference Scheuer2013), who analyzes business tax policy with adverse selection in credit markets and occupational choice; Tomura (Reference Tomura2012), who studies secondary capital market shutdowns caused by adverse selection;and Clementi and Hopenhayn (Reference Clementi and Hopenhayn2006), who study the impact on firm behavior of borrowing constraints that emerge from an asymmetric information problem.

8 Banerjee and Moll (Reference Banerjee and Moll2010) do look at both the intensive and extensive margins of capital misallocation where the collateral constraints prevent efficient allocation; there is misallocation on the intensive margin when the marginal product of capital is unequal across entrepreneurs and on the extensive margin when there are entrepreneurs with no capital at all. The latter might occur due to entry costs, for example, and is likely to lead to much greater persistence in TFP fluctuations than misallocation on the intensive margin.

9 The implications of this might differ in the meaningful ways from a model in which capital is inefficiently allocated across firms. For example, in our model, the central bank deposit rate would have important effects during credit crunches.

10 Following, for example, Rothschild and Stiglitz (Reference Rothschild and Stiglitz1976) and Wilson (Reference Wilson1977). There are some consequences of the choice of sequence as discussed in Hellwig (Reference Hellwig1987); choosing a three-stage game, for instance, could lead to pooling or separating equilibria depending on the starting agent. However, based on what we observe in the data, the natural choice of agent to make the initial offer is the bank and allowing three stages would imply loan offers could be withdrawn once accepted. This is not something we observe in reality.

11 Because firm-type is drawn every period, there is no process by which banks learn the firm type over time. During numerical simulations, we find that dynamic contracts are not Pareto improving in most states of the world.

12 See Bolton and Dewatripont (Reference Bolton and Dewatripont2005), pp. 59–60.

13 This could be considered as a storage technology such as cash or excess reserves, a foreign or government bond, or some other lower-return asset.

14 Note that the contract rate, $ \tau $ is non-contingent on the aggregate return to capital, thus moving aggregate risk to firm equity holders. This assumption does not have an important effect on the results.

15 The conditions are listed in Appendix E in full.

16 To see this, suppose a bank has sufficient funds to only lend to one type of firm. Without asymmetric information, the bank would be indifferent between lending to firms holding risky or safe projects as the net present value is equal. With asymmetric information, because the firms holding risky projects earn information rents, the banks prefer to either (i) lend only to firms with safe projects, or (ii) lend only to firms with risky projects because no information rents would need to be paid. Because firms holding risk projects can pretend to safe ones, (i) is never possible.

17 One could view the storage technology as productive activity in which case the extensive margin description is a little misleading. However, we consider this characterization to be reasonable if this is interpreted as central bank reserves, noting that excess reserves often increases significantly during crises.

18 Proofs are given in Appendix E.

19 In fact, the pooling constraint, $x_t^r - x_t^s \ge 0$ , can no longer bind because, even when $x_t^r = x_t^s=1$ , the lender is indifferent between pooling and separating due to the linearity of the IC constraint. That is, an additional dollar earned by increasing the rate charged to risky borrowers is perfectly offset by a dollar lost when the number of loans is reduced by cutting $x_t^s$ .

20 In particular, this refers to observed share of risky loans on bank balance sheets.

21 If there were a continuum of types rather than two, the vertical slope in Figure 2 would be more shallow because firms rationed gradually according to their riskiness. It follows that financial instability is greater in a low interest rate environment and the proportion of risky assets in the economy higher. This is supported by data (see, e.g. Lian et al. (Reference Lian, Ma and Wang2018)), but contrary to conventional models of adverse selection where the reverse is true (cf. Stiglitz and Weiss (Reference Stiglitz and Weiss1981)).

22 Using 2011–2017 UK survey data from the SME Finance Monitor, we run a probit regression, finding that low and average risk firms experienced significantly increased rejection probabilities during periods of higher loan rejection rates relative to the 2017, whereas above average risk firms did not. See Appendix A for more details.

23 Note that the spread of interest in our analysis is that between the savings rate and the return on capital which is larger than that required to cover losses due to default. So while our paper does not explain the excess bond premium as discussed by Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek (Reference Gilchrist and ZakrajŠek2012), we do speak to a source of the same inefficiency.

24 There is another way that capital misallocation can occur: if there are fewer firms seeking funds than there is capital available, that is, $ \phi_t > \bar{x}_t $ , then banks must store surplus capital. However, these surplus funds reduce total return on lending but do not affect the information rents; it follows this misallocation never occurs in numerical simulations unless there is a negative real interest rate because households would rather choose to increase consumption.

25 That is, k is just a normalization device. This follows from constant returns to scale in production. k and $f_t$ only appear in the model multiplied together, so adjusting k only implies a change in $f_t$ without affecting any other variable.

26 The Statistics of US Businesses (SUSB) considers establishments with fewer than 500 employees as small. According to the SUSB, the share of small business fell from over 54% in 1988 to under 47% in 2015, with a mean of just over 50%.

27 The interval includes all observations in the time series. Source: BGFRS, Total Value of Loans for All Commercial and Industry Loans, Other Risk (Acceptable), All Commercial Banks [EVAONQ], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/EVANQ, November 27, 2017; and Total Value of Loans for All Commercial and Industry Loans, All Commercial Banks [EVANQ], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/EVANQ, November 27, 2017.

28 The interval includes all observations in the time series. Source: BGFRS, Delinquency Rate on Commercial and Industrial Loans, All Commercial Banks [DRBLACBS], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis; https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DRBLACBS, September 4, 2016.

29 The interval includes all observations in the time series. Source: The Longitudinal Business Database, Center for Economic Studies, US Census Bureau (collected November 2017 from https://www.census.gov/ces/dataproducts/bds/data.html).

30 This technology can represent bank excess reserves, which often increase sharply during downturns. See Figure 11 in Appendix D.

31 The algorithm extends Dynare (Adjemian et al. (Reference Adjemian, Bastanie, KaramÉ, Juillard, Maih, Mihoubi, Perendia, Pfeifer, Ratto and Villemot2011)) to solve models featuring inequality constraints. The method allows higher-order perturbation approximations and incorporates the role of risk of constraints binding in the future, achieving this via the stochastic extended path algorithm, integrating over future uncertainty period-by-period in model simulations. This is discussed further in Appendix B.

32 First-best and RBC are used interchangeably.

33 Employing the series of TFP constructed by Fernald (Reference Fernald2014), which accounts for variable utilization.

34 $ \sigma_a = 0.00686 $ in the RBC model.

35 The risk shock has no effect in the RBC model and so is ignored.

36 Data used is since 1971—the average spread is slightly lower over the entire available time series. This spread is often used as a proxy for the investment wedge (see, e.g. Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Motto and Rostagno2014)).

37 We discuss the propagation of a positive transitory technology shock in Appendix C. We leave this from here as there is little difference from the RBC model.

38 This shock follows an AR(1) process with persistence parameter equal to 0.99. If the change were completely persistent, this would be equivalent to a change in the steady-state interest rate from 4% to 3.5%.

39 Although we abstract from the sources of default risk, likely to arise largely from balance sheet factors and an interaction with reduced demand, the shock captures the impact of these factors on bank lending and seems a natural choice of shock to include. The choice of demand shock follows much recent literature to generate large falls in demand (see, e.g. FernÁndez-Villaverde et al. (Reference FernÁndez-Villaverde, Gordon, GuerrÓn-Quintana and Rubio-RamÍrez2015); Aruoba et al. (Reference Aruoba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide2018)).

40 Data on lending from OECD, Financing SMEs and Entrepreneurs: An OECD Scoreboard, “New business lending, SMEs”, 2008–2009, retrieved on November 14, 2017 (http://stats.oecd.org/). Remaining data retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis on December 11, 2017. GDP: Eurostat, Real Gross Domestic Product for United Kingdom [CLVMNACSCAB1GQUK] (https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CLVMNACSCAB1GQUK). Investment: Bank of England, Real Investment Expenditures in the United Kingdom [RIVEXUKQ] (https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RIVEXUKQ). Consumption: Bank of England, Real Consumption Expenditures in the United Kingdom [RLCMEXUKQ] (https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/RLCMEXUKQ).

41 Source: OECD Productivity Database, multifactor productivity index 2008–2009, retrieved on December 19, 2017 (http://stats.oecd.org/).

42 The share of large businesses has increased from 46% of establishments in 1988 to 53% in 2015 (see footnote 4.1).

43 For example, a 1% increase in TFP, $ z_t $ , causes a 4.3% rise in investment under the baseline calibration. This would be 4.4% with either the steady-state default rate, $ d = 1-p $ , 1 percentage point higher, or the share of safe projects, $ \lambda $ , 10% lower. See impulse responses in Figures 10, 11, 12, 13, and 14 in Appendix B.

Figure 10. Impulse response functions to a positive transitory shock to technology $z_t$ of 1% comparing baseline calibration (black line) with high $ \lambda $ (+10%) (blue dashed) and low $ \lambda $ (-10%) (green line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percent point deviation from ergodic mean.

Figure 11. Percentage change in excess reserves of US depository institutions. Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, H.3 Aggregate Reserves of Depository Institutions and the Monetary Base.

Figure 12. Impulse response functions to a positive transitory shock to technology $z_t$ of 1% comparing baseline calibration (black line) with high steady state p (+1% pt) (blue dashed) and low p (-1% pt) (green line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percent point deviation from ergodic mean.

Figure 13. Impulse response functions to a negative transitory 1 SD shock to $p_t^r$ comparing baseline calibration (black line) with high $ \lambda $ (+10%) (blue dashed) and low $ \lambda $ (-10%) (green line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percent point deviation from ergodic mean.

Figure 14. Impulse response functions to a negative transitory 1 SD shock to $p_t^r$ comparing baseline calibration (black line) with high steady-state p (+1 % pt) (blue dashed) and low p (-1 % pt) (green line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percent point deviation from ergodic mean.

44 The implication is that stochastic volatility in $ \lambda $ could be an additional source of macroeconomic volatility. An exogenous fall in $ \lambda $ has a similar impact to a positive risk shock, so we only consider the latter. This seems a natural choice given the clear countercyclical time series of firm default.

45 Centered on sixth year. Real interest rate from International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics and data files using World Bank data on the GDP deflator. Output deflated using GDP deflator (both US Bureau of Economic Analysis) and divided by civilian noninstitutional population (US Bureau of Labor Statistics), then logged and HP-filtered.

46 For example, the share of small establishments has decreased from 54% in 1988 to 47% in 2015 (see footnote 4.1)

47 This storage could, for example, be thought of as excess capital reserves.

48 This surveys small businesses in the UK regarding their recent experience obtaining finance. Source: BDRC Continental. (2018). Small- and Medium-Sized Enterprise Finance Monitor, 2011-2017. [data collection]. 19th Edition. UK Data Service. SN: 6888, http://doi.org/10.5255/UKDA-SN-6888-20

49 BDRC Continental. (2018). Small- and Medium-Sized Enterprise Finance Monitor, 2011-2017. [data collection]. 19th Edition. UK Data Service. SN: 6888, http://doi.org/10.5255/UKDA-SN-6888-20

References

Adjemian, S. and Juillard, M. 2013 Stochastic extended path approach. Centre for Economic and International Studies.Google Scholar
Adjemian, S., Bastanie, H., KaramÉ, F., Juillard, M., Maih, J., Mihoubi, F., Perendia, G., Pfeifer, J., Ratto, M. and Villemot, S. 2011 Dynare: Reference Manual Version 4, Dynare Working Paper Series 1, 160.Google Scholar
Albertazzi, U., Bottero, M., Gambacorta, L. and Ongena, S. 2017 Asymmetric Information and the Securitization of SME Loans, No. 601, BIS Working Papers, Bank for International Settlements.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, A., Davis, P. E., Liadze, I. and Rienzo, C. 2013 Evaluating changes in bank lending to UK SMEs over 2001-12 – Ongoing tight credit? National Institute Economic Review 225(1), 151.Google Scholar
Aruoba, S. B., Cuba-Borda, P. and Schorfheide, F. 2018 Macroeconomic dynamics near the ZLB: A tale of two countries. Review of Economic Studies 85(1), 87118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baele, L., Bekaert, G., Inghelbrecht, K. and Wei, M. 2020 Flights to Safety. The Review of Financial Studies 33(2), 689746.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. V. and Moll, B. 2010 Why does misallocation persist? American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2(1), 189–206.Google Scholar
Barkley, B., Mills, C. K., Recto, M. C., Terry, E. and Wavering, E. 2016 2015 Small Business Credit Survey: Report on Employer Firms, Technical report, Federal Reserve Banks of New York, Atlanta, Boston, Cleveland, Philadelphia, Richmond, St. Louis.Google Scholar
Battisto, J., de Zeeuw, M., Mills, C. K., Lieberman, S. and Wiersch, A. M. 2018 2017 Small Business Credit Survey: Report on Employer Firms, Technical report, Federal Reserve Banks of Atlanta, Boston, Chicago, Cleveland, Dallas, Kansas City, Minneapolis, New York, Philadelphia, Richmond, St. Louis and San Francisco.Google Scholar
Beltran, D. O. and Thomas, C. P. 2010 Could asymmetric information alone have caused the collapse of private-label securitization? No. 1010, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Papers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benhabib, J., Dong, F. and Wang, P. 2018 Adverse selection and self fulfilling business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 94, 114130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertsch, C. 2013 A Detrimental Feedback Loop: Deleveraging and Adverse Selection, No. 108, Sveriges Riksbank Research Paper Series.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besanko, D. and Thakor, A. V. 1987 Competitive equilibrium in the credit under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Theory 42(1), 167–182.Google Scholar
Bester, H. 1985 Screening vs rationing in credit markets with imperfect information. The American Economic Review 75(4), 850855.Google Scholar
Bigio, S. 2015 Endogenous liquidity and the business cycle. American Economic Review 105(6), 1883–1927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, P. and Dewatripont, M. 2005 Contract Theory, 1st edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Buera, F. J. and Shin, Y. 2013 Financial frictions and the persistence of history: A quantitative exploration. Journal of Political Economy 121(2), 221–272.Google Scholar
Caggese, A. and CuÑat, V. 2013 Financing constraints, firm dynamics, export decisions, and aggregate productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(1), 177–193.Google Scholar
Camargo, B. and Lester, B. 2014 Trading dynamics in decentralized markets with adverse selection. Journal of Economic Theory 153(1), 534–568.Google Scholar
Chari, V. V., Kehoe, P. J. and McGrattan, E. R. 2007 Business cycle accounting. Econometrica 75(3), 781836.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiu, J. and Koeppl, T. V. 2016 Trading dynamics with adverse selection and search: market freeze, intervention and recovery. Review of Economic Studies 83(3), 969–1000.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. S. and Trabandt, M. 2015 Understanding the great recession. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7(1), 110167.Google Scholar
Christiano, L., Motto, R. and Rostagno, M. 2014 Risk shocks. American Economic Review 104(1), 2765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clementi, G. L. and Hopenhayn, H. A. 2006 A theory of financing constraints and firm dynamics. Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(1), 229–265.Google Scholar
Crawford, G. S., Pavanini, N. and Schivardi, F. 2018 Asymmetric information and imperfect competition in lending markets. American Economic Review 108(7), 16591701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cressy, R. and Toivanen, O. 2001 Is there adverse selection in the credit market? Venture Capital 3(3), 215–238.Google Scholar
Cui, W. and Kaas, L. 2020 Default cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Fiore, F. and Uhlig, H. 2015 Corporate debt structure and the financial crisis. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47(8), 1571–1598.Google Scholar
De Meza, D. and Webb, D. C. 1987 Too much investment: A problem of asymmetric information. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 102(2), 281–292.Google Scholar
Eisfeldt, A. L. 2004 Endogenous liquidity in asset markets. The Journal of Finance 59(1), 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernald, J. 2014 A Quarterly, Utilization-Adjusted Series on Total Factor Productivity, Working paper 2012-19, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
FernÁndez-Villaverde, J., Gordon, G., GuerrÓn-Quintana, P. and Rubio-RamÍrez, J. F. 2015 Nonlinear adventures at the zero lower bound. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 57, 182204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figueroa, N. and Leukhina, O. 2018 Cash flows and credit cycles. Journal of Banking & Finance 87, 318–332.Google Scholar
Franklin, J., Rostom, M. and Thwaites, G. 2020 The banks that said no: Banking relationships, credit supply and productivity in the United Kingdom. Journal of Financial Services Research 57, 149179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fraser, S. 2012 The Impact of the Financial Crisis on Bank Lending to SMEs, Technical report, UK Government Department for Business Innovation and Skills. Report Prepared for BIS/ Breedon Review.Google Scholar
Gertler, M. and Kiyotaki, N. 2010 Financial intermediation and credit policy in business cycle analysis. Handbook of Monetary Economics 3(11), 547–599.Google Scholar
Gilchrist, S. and ZakrajŠek, E. 2012 Credit spreads and business cycle fluctuations. American Economic Review 102(4), 1692–1720.Google Scholar
Gilchrist, S., Sim, J. W. and ZakrajŠek, E. 2013 Misallocation and financial market frictions: Some direct evidence from the dispersion in borrowing costs. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(1), 159176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenwood, R. and Hanson, S. G. 2011 Issuer Quality and the Credit Cycle , Working paper series, No. 17197, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge MA, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Guerrieri, V., Shimer, R. and Wright, R. 2010 Adverse selection in competitive search equilibrium. Econometrica 78(6), 1823–1862.Google Scholar
Hellwig, M. F. 1987 Some recent developments in the theory of competition in markets with adverse selection. European Economic Review 31(1–2), 319325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holden, T. 2016 Computation of Solutions to Dynamic Models with Occasionally Binding Constraints, Econstor preprints, 144569, ZBW – Leibniz Information Centre for Economics.Google Scholar
Holden, T. 2019 Existence, Uniqueness and Computation of Solutions to Dynamic Models with Occasionally Binding Constraints, EconStor Preprints 144570, ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics.Google Scholar
House, C. L. 2006 Adverse selection and the financial accelerator. Journal of Monetary Economics 53(6), 11171134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jeong, H. and Townsend, R. M. 2007 Sources of TFP growth: Occupational choice and financial deepening. Economic Theory 32(1), 179–221.Google Scholar
King, R. G., Plosser, C. I and Rebelo, S. T. 1988 Production, growth and business cycles. Journal of Monetary Economics 21(2–3), 309341.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurlat, P. 2013 Lemons markets and the transmission of aggregate shocks. American Economic Review 103(4), 14631489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lan, H. and Meyer-Gohde, A. 2013 Pruning in Perturbation DSGE Models – Guidance from Nonlinear Moving Average Approximations Pruning in Perturbation DSGE Models, Sfb 649 discussion paper 2013-024, Humboldt-UniversitÄt zu Berlin, Berlin.Google Scholar
Lester, B., Postlewaite, A. and Wright, R. 2011 Information and liquidity. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43(Suppl. 2), 355377.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lian, C., Ma, Y. and Wang, C. 2018 Low interest rates and risk taking: Evidence from individual investment decisions. Review of Financial Studies (Forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lown, C. S. and Morgan, D. P. 2006 The credit cycle and the business cycle: New findings using the loan officer opinion survey. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38(6), 1575–1597.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. 1986 The allocation of credit and financial collapse. Quarterly Journal of Economics 101(3), 455470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, A. 2009 A model of collateral, investment, and adverse selection. Journal of Economic Theory 144(4), 15721588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moll, B. 2014 Productivity losses from financial frictions: Can self-financing undo capital misallocation? American Economic Review 104(10), 31863221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morris, S. and Shin, H. S. 2012 Contagious adverse selection. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4(1), 1–21.Google Scholar
Oberfield, E. 2013 Productivity and misallocation during a crisis: Evidence from the Chilean Crisis of 1982. Review of Economic Dynamics 16(1), 100119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pratap, S. and Urrutia, C. 2012 Financial frictions and total factor productivity: Accounting for the real effects of financial crises. Review of Economic Dynamics 15(3), 336–358.Google Scholar
Reichlin, P. and Siconolfi, P. 1998 Adverse selection of investment projects and the business cycle. Temi di discussione, Banca d’Italia 326(November), 1–28.Google Scholar
Robb, A. and Farhat, J. 2013 An Overview of the Kauffman Firm Survey: Results from 2011 Business Activities, Technical report, Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocheteau, G. 2011 Payments and liquidity under adverse selection. Journal of Monetary Economics 58(3), 191205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rothschild, M. and Stiglitz, J. 1976 Equilibrium in competitive insurance markets: An essay on the economics of imperfect information. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 90(4), 629–649.Google Scholar
Scheuer, F. 2013 Adverse selection in credit markets and regressive profit taxation. Journal of Economic Theory 148(4), 13331360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shin, H. S. 2009 Reflections on northern rock: The bank run that heralded the global financial crisis. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1), 101119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. E. and Weiss, A. 1981 Credit rationing in markets with imperfect information. American Economic Review 71(3), 393–410.Google Scholar
Swarbrick, J. 2021, Occasionally Binding Constraints in Large Models: A Review of Solution Methods, Discussion Papers 2021-5, Bank of Canada.Google Scholar
Tang, T. T. 2009 Information asymmetry and firms’ credit market access: Evidence from Moody’s credit rating format refinement. Journal of Financial Economics 93(2), 325351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tomura, H. 2012 Asset illiquidity and market shutdowns in competitive equilibrium. Review of Economic Dynamics 15, 283294.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, S. D. 1986 Costly monitoring, financial intermediation, and equilibrium credit rationing. Journal of Monetary Economics 18(2), 159179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, S. and Wright, R. 1994 Barter and monetary exchange under private information. The American Economic Review 84(1), 104–123.Google Scholar
Wilson, C. 1977 A model of insurance markets with incomplete information. Journal of Economic Theory 16(2), 167207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Net percentage of domestic banks tightening non-rate standards for commercial and industrial loans to small firms. Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (BGFRS), Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Partial equilibrium results: division of returns under asymmetric information under different first-best rates of return on capital.

Figure 2

Table 1. Calibrations of adverse selection model parameters

Figure 3

Table 2. Parametrization of common real business cycle parameters.

Figure 4

Table 3. Simulated and empirical moments. Data for Y, I, and C is HP-filtered US time series 1983Q2–2016Q2; investment wedge, $ \Delta $, is the spread between Moody’s BAA-rated corporate bond yields and 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity. Simulated time series of Y, I, and C are HP-filtered. Standard deviations are in percent for Y, I, and C and percentage points for $\Delta$.

Figure 5

Figure 3. Impulse response functions to a 1 standard deviation (SD) transitory risk shock. Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, and C, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $, $ \Delta $, and R.

Figure 6

Figure 4. Impulse response functions to a transitory risk shock of 3% points comparing our model (black line) with a version with the TFP “switched off” (gray line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, C, and A, and percent point deviation for $ x^s $ and $ \Delta $.

Figure 7

Figure 5. Impulse response functions to a simultaneous time-preference shock and risk shock comparing our model (black line) with the RBC model (blue dashed). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, C, and A, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $ and $ \Delta $.

Figure 8

Figure 6. Impulse response functions to a 1 SD transitory risk shock comparing baseline calibration (black line) with a low $ \bar{R} $ calibration (gray line). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage deviation from ergodic mean for Y, I, and C, and percentage point deviation for $ x^s $, $ \Delta $, and R.

Figure 9

Figure 7. Ten-year rolling average US real interest rates against 10-year rolling average US output volatility. 1966–1976 black diamonds; 1978–1987 red squares; and 1988–2011 green circles.

Figure 10

Figure 8. Average impulse response functions to a positive transitory shock to technology $z_t$ of 1% for our model (black line) and the RBC (blue dashed). Time is quarterly, and plots show percentage point deviation from ergodic mean for R and $ \Delta $, and percent deviation for other variables.

Figure 11

Figure 9. Percent of reporting small and medium businesses that applied for loans but were denied credit. United Kingdom, 2011–2017. Four quarter moving average. Source: SME Finance Monitor, BDRC Continental.

Figure 12

Table 4. Predictive margins of year effect on rejection probabilities relative to 2017. Details are in Appendix A.