Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T16:30:02.821Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

SOCIAL CAPITAL, TRUST, AND MULTIPLE EQUILIBRIA IN ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 September 2012

Katarzyna Growiec
Affiliation:
Warsaw School of Social Sciences and Humanities
Jakub Growiec*
Affiliation:
Warsaw School of Economics and National Bank of Poland
*
Address correspondence to: Jakub Growiec, Instytut Ekonometrii, Szkoła Główna Handlowa, al. Niepodległości 162, 02-554 Warszawa, Poland; e-mail: jakub.growiec@sgh.waw.pl.

Abstract

We propose a novel mechanism giving rise to poverty traps and multiple equilibria in economic performance. It is a potentially important source of persistent underdevelopment across countries and regions. At the core of this mechanism, bridging social capital and social trust feed back on each other, interdependently affecting individuals' earnings and subjective well-being. High trust and abundant bridging social capital reinforce each other, leading to a “high” equilibrium where both these variables take persistently high values, and earnings and well-being are high as well, whereas low trust and lack of bridging social capital create a vicious circle, leading to a “low trust trap” where all these variables are persistently low. The workings of our theoretical model are in agreement with a wide range of findings from the contemporary literature in sociology and social psychology.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron (2009) Introduction to Modern Economic Growth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Bolton, Patrick (1997) A theory of trickle-down growth and development. Review of Economic Studies 64, 151172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Giuliano, Paola (2010) The power of family. Journal of Economic Growth 15 (2), 93125.Google Scholar
Alesina, Alberto and Ferrara, Eliana La (2000) Participation in heterogeneous communities. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115 (3), 847904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Algan, Yann and Cahuc, Pierre (2010) Inherited trust and growth. American Economic Review 100 (5), 20602092.Google Scholar
Ashraf, Quamrul and Galor, Oded (in press) The “out of Africa” hypothesis, human genetic diversity and comparative economic development. American Economic Review.Google Scholar
Azariadis, Costas and Drazen, Allan (1990) Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (2), 501526.Google Scholar
Belzil, Christian and Hansen, Jörgen (2002) Unobserved ability and the return to schooling. Econometrica 70 (5), 20752091.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland (1996) Inequality and growth. In Bernanke, Ben S. and Rotemberg, Julio J. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1996, pp. 1174. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Spiegel, Mark M. (2005) Human capital and technology diffusion. In Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, pp. 935966. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Beugelsdijk, Sjoerd and Smulders, Sjak (2003) Bonding and bridging social capital: Which type is good for economic growth? In Arts, Wilhelmus A., Hagenaars, Jacques A., and Halman, Loek (eds.), The Cultural Diversity of European Unity, pp. 147184. Brill: Leiden.Google Scholar
Bogardus, Emory S. (1926) Social distance in the city. Proceedings and Publications of the American Sociological Society 20, 4046.Google Scholar
Bourdieu, Pierre (1986) The forms of capital. In Richardson, John C. (ed.), Handbook of Theory and Research of Sociology of Education, pp. 117142. New York: Greenwood Press.Google Scholar
Bowlby, John (1969) Attachment. London: Hogarth Press.Google Scholar
Burt, Ronald S. (1992) Structural Holes. The Social Structure and Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Burt, Ronald S. (2005) Brokerage and Closure. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, Varadarajan V. and Hopenhayn, Hugo (1991) Vintage human capital, growth, and the diffusion of new technology. Journal of Political Economy 99 (6), 11421165.Google Scholar
Chiang, Alpha C. (1992) Elements of Dynamic Optimization. Prospect Heights, IL: Waveland Press.Google Scholar
Cook, Karen S., Yamagishi, Toshio, Cheshire, Coye, Cooper, Robin, Matsuda, Masafumi, and Mishima, Rie (2005) Trust building via risk taking: A cross-societal experiment. Social Psychology Quarterly 68 (2), 121142.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha (1988) Trust as a commodity. In Gambetta, Diego (ed.), Trust: Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations, pp. 4971. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha (2002) Social Capital and Economic Performance: Analytics. Mimeo, University of Cambridge.Google Scholar
Davies, James B. (2003) Empirical Evidence on Human Capital Externalities. RBC Financial Group Economic Policy Research Institute working paper 20035, University of Western Ontario.Google Scholar
Diener, Ed, Suh, Eunkook M., Lucas, Richard E., and Smith, Heidi L. (1999) Subjective well-being: Three decades of progress. Psychological Bulletin 125, 276302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunbar, Robin (1993) Coevolution of neocortex size, group size, and language in humans. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16, 681735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durlauf, Steven N. and Fafchamps, Marcel (2005) Social capital. In Aghion, Philippe and Durlauf, Steven N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, pp. 16371699. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Fall, Falilou (2005) Endogenous Persistent Inequality. CORE discussion paper 2005/94.Google Scholar
Florida, Richard (2004) The Rise of the Creative Class. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Franzen, Axel and Hangartner, Dominik (2006) Social networks and labour market outcomes: The non-monetary benefits of social capital. European Sociological Review 22 (4), 353368.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, Francis (1995) Trust: The Social Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded (1996) Convergence? Inferences from theoretical models. Economic Journal 106 (437), 10561069.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded (2010) The 2008 Lawrence R. Klein lecture—Comparative economic development: Insights from unified growth theory. International Economic Review 51 (1), 144.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded and Zeira, Joseph (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60 (1), 3552.Google Scholar
Giddens, Anthony (1991) Modernity and Self-Identity. Self and Society in the Late Modern Age. Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Laibson, David, and Sacerdote, Bruce (2002) An economic approach to social capital. Economic Journal 112 (483), 437458.Google Scholar
Glanville, Jennifer L. and Paxton, Pamela (2007) How do we learn to trust? A confirmatory tetrad analysis of the sources of generalized trust. Social Psychology Quarterly 70 (3), 230242.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldin, Claudia and Katz, Lawrence F. (1999) Human capital and social capital: The rise of secondary schooling in America, 1910 to 1940. Journal of Interdisciplinary History 29 (4), 683723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, Mark S. (1973) The strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology 78 (6), 13601380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greenberg, Jay (1991) Oedipus and Beyond: A Clinical Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Growiec, Jakub (2010) Human capital, aggregation, and growth. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14 (2), 189211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Growiec, Jakub and Growiec, Katarzyna (2010) Social capital, well–being, and earnings: Theory and evidence from Poland. European Societies 12 (2), 231255.Google Scholar
Growiec, Katarzyna (2009) Związek między sieciami społecznymi a zaufaniem społecznym—Mechanizm wzajemnego wzmacniania? [The relationship between social capital and social trust—A self-fulfilling prophecy?]. Psychologia społeczna 1/2, Article 4.Google Scholar
Growiec, Katarzyna (2011) Kapitał społeczny. Geneza i społeczne konsekwencje [Social capital. Origins and social consequences]. Warsaw: Academica.Google Scholar
Growiec, Katarzyna and Growiec, Jakub (2011) Trusting Only Whom You Know, Knowing Only Whom You Trust: The Joint Impact of Social Capital and Trust on Individuals' Economic Performance and Happiness in CEE Countries. Working paper 94, National Bank of Poland.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Robert E. and Jones, Charles I. (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1), 83116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helliwell, John F. (2003) How's life—Combining individual and national variables to explain subjective well-being. Economic Modelling 20 (2), 331360.Google Scholar
Helliwell, John F. and Putnam, Robert D. (2007) Education and social capital. Eastern Economics Journal 33, 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsieh, Chang-Tai and Klenow, Peter J. (2009) Misallocation and manufacturing TFP in China and India. Quarterly Journal of Economics 124 (4), 14031448.Google Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald and Baker, Wayne E. (2000) Modernization, cultural change and the persistent of traditional values. American Sociological Review 65, 1951.Google Scholar
Jovanovic, Boyan (1998) Vintage capital and inequality. Review of Economic Dynamics 1, 497530.Google Scholar
Kadushin, Charles (2002) The motivational foundation of social networks. Social Networks 24, 7791.Google Scholar
Kalish, Yuval and Robins, Garry (2006) Psychological predispositions and network structure: The relationship between individual predispositions, structural holes and network closure. Social Networks 28, 5684.Google Scholar
Klapwijk, Anthon and Van Lange, Paul A. M. (2009) Promoting cooperation and trust in “noisy” situations: The power of generosity. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 96 (1), 83103.Google Scholar
Knack, Stephen and Keefer, Philip (1997) Does social capital have an economic payoff? A cross-country investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (4), 12511288.Google Scholar
Leonard, Madeleine (2008) Social and subcultural capital among teenagers in Northern Ireland. Youth and Society 40 (2), 224244.Google Scholar
Li, Yaojun, Pickles, Andrew, and Savage, Mike (2005) Social capital and social trust in Britain. European Sociological Review 21 (2), 109123.Google Scholar
Lin, Nan (2001) Social Capital. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (2000) Endogenous inequality. Review of Economic Studies 67, 743759.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moav, Omer (2002) Income distribution and macroeconomics: The persistence of inequality in a convex technology framework. Economics Letters 75, 187192.Google Scholar
Molm, Linda D., Takahashi, Nobuyuki, and Peterson, Gretchen (2000) Risk and trust in social exchange. American Sociological Review 105 (5), 13961427.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Brien, Karen M. and Quimby, Julie L. (2006) Predictors of well-being among non-traditional female students with children. Journal of Counseling and Development 84, 451460.Google Scholar
Podolny, Joel M. and Baron, James N. (1997) Resources and relationships: Social networks and mobility in the workplace. American Sociological Review 62, 673693.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas (1997) The dynamics of the wealth distribution and the interest rate with credit rationing. Review of Economic Studies 64, 173189.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. (2000) Bowling Alone. Collapse and Revival of American Community. New York: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D., Leonardi, Robert, and Nanetti, Raffaella Y. (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rangazas, Peter C. (2005) Human capital and growth: An alternative accounting. Topics in Macroeconomics 5 (1), Article 20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simmel, Georg (1950) The isolated individual and the dyad. In Wolff, Kurt H. (ed.), The Sociology of Georg Simmel, pp. 118144. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Simmel, Georg (1971) Individuality and social structure. In Levine, Donald N. (ed.), Georg Simmel on Individuality and Social Forms. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Słomczyński, Kazimierz M. and Tomescu-Dubrow, Irina (2005) Friendship patterns and upward mobility: A test of social capital hypothesis. Polish Sociological Review 151 (3), 221235.Google Scholar
Sztompka, Piotr (1999) Trust: A Sociological Theory. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tamura, Robert (2001) Teachers, growth, and convergence. Journal of Political Economy 109 (5), 10211059.Google Scholar
Yamagishi, Toshio (1998) The Structure of Trust: The Evolutionary Game of Mind and Society. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.Google Scholar
Zak, Paul J. and Knack, Stephen (2001) Trust and growth. Economic Journal 111 (470), 295321.Google Scholar