Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nmvwc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-06T08:38:25.215Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Repercussions of negatively selective migration for the behavior of non-migrants when preferences are social

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 April 2019

Oded Stark*
Affiliation:
Universities of Bonn and Warsaw
Wiktor Budzinski
Affiliation:
University of Warsaw
*
*Corresponding author. Email: ostark@uni-bonn.de
Get access

Abstract

We study how the work effort and output of non-migrants in a village economy are affected when a member of the village population migrates. Given that individuals dislike low relative income, and that migration modifies the social space of the non-migrants, we show why and how the non-migrants adjust their work effort and output in response to the migration-generated change in their social space. When migration is negatively selective such that the least productive individual departs, the output of the non-migrants increases. While as a consequence of this migration statically calculated average productivity rises, we identify a dynamic repercussion that compounds the static one.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We are indebted to two Reviewers for advice and guidance. Oded Stark acknowledges with gratitude support of the Korea Institute for International Economic Policy.

References

Bandiera, Oriana, Barankay, Iwan, and Rasul, Imran (2010) Social incentives in the workplace. Review of Economic Studies 77(2), 417458.Google Scholar
Blanchflower, David G. and Oswald, Andrew J. (2008) Hypertension and happiness across nations. Journal of Health Economics 27(2), 218233.Google Scholar
Bossert, Walter and D'Ambrosio, Conchita (2006) Reference groups and relative deprivation. Economics Letters 90(3), 421426.Google Scholar
Callan, Mitchell J., Shead, Will N., and Olson, James M. (2011) Personal relative deprivation, delay discounting, and gambling. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 101(5), 955973.Google Scholar
Card, David, Mas, Alexandre, Moretti, Enrico, and Saez, Emmanuel (2012) Inequality at work: The effect of peer salaries on job satisfaction. American Economic Review 102(6), 29813003.Google Scholar
Clark, Andrew E., Frijters, Paul, and Shields, Michael A. (2008) Relative income, happiness, and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature 46(1), 95144.Google Scholar
Cohn, Alain, Fehr, Ernst, Herrmann, Benedikt, and Schneider, Frédéric (2014) Social comparison and effort provision: Evidence from a field experiment. Journal of the European Economic Association 12(4), 877898.Google Scholar
Duesenberry, James S. (1949) Income, Saving and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Dur, Robert and Glazer, Amihai (2008) Optimal contracts when a worker envies his boss. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 24(1), 120137.Google Scholar
Ebert, Udo and Moyes, Patrick (2000) An axiomatic characterization of Yitzhaki's index of individual deprivation. Economics Letters 68(3), 263270.Google Scholar
Fang, Hanming and Moscarini, Giuseppe (2005) Morale hazard. Journal of Monetary Economics 52(4), 749777.Google Scholar
Fliessbach, Klaus, Weber, Bernd, Trautner, Peter, Dohmen, Thomas, Sunde, Uwe, Elger, Christian E., and Falk, Armin (2007) Social comparison affects reward-related brain activity in the human ventral striatum. Science 318(5854), 13051308.Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1985) Choosing the Right Pond: Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Government of India, Office of the Registrar General & Census Commissioner (2011) Census of India: http://www.censusindia.gov.in/2011-Common/Latest_Releases.htmlGoogle Scholar
Hey, John D. and Lambert, Peter J. (1980) Relative deprivation and the Gini coefficient: Comment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 95(3), 567573.Google Scholar
Hirsch, Fred (1976) Social Limits to Growth. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon S. (1971) Economic Growth of Nations: Total Output and Production Structure. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. B. and Stark, Oded (1985) Motivations to remit. Journal of Political Economy 93(5), 901918.Google Scholar
Luttmer, Erzo F. P. (2005) Neighbors as negatives: Relative earnings and well-being. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120(3), 9631002.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl (1849) Wage-Labour and Capital. New York: International Publishers, 1933.Google Scholar
Rosenzweig, Mark R. and Stark, Oded (1989) Consumption smoothing, migration and marriage: Evidence from rural India. Journal of Political Economy 97(4), 905926.Google Scholar
Runciman, Walter G. (1966) Relative Deprivation and Social Justice. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. (1973) Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill. Ninth ed.Google Scholar
Schor, Juliet B. (1998) The Overspent American: Why We Want What We Don't Need. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Singer, Eleanor (1981) Reference groups and social evaluations. In Rosenberg, M. and Turner, R. H. (eds.), Social Psychology: Sociological Perspectives. New York: Basic Books, pp. 6693.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776) The Wealth of Nations, Book V, Chapter 2. London: Penguin Classics, 1999.Google Scholar
Smith, Heather J., Pettigrew, Thomas F., Pippin, Gina M., and Bialosiewicz, Silvana (2012) Relative deprivation: A theoretical and meta-analytic review. Personality and Social Psychology Review 16(3), 203232.Google Scholar
Stark, Oded (1993) The Migration of Labor. Oxford and Cambridge, MA: Blackwell 1993.Google Scholar
Stark, Oded (2009) Reasons for remitting. World Economics 10(3), 147157.Google Scholar
Stark, Oded (2017) Migration when social preferences are ordinal: Steady-state population distribution and social welfare. Economica 84(336), 647666.Google Scholar
Stark, Oded and Bloom, David E. (1985) The new economics of labour migration. American Economic Review 75(2), 173178.Google Scholar
Stark, Oded and Hyll, Walter (2011) On the economic architecture of the workplace: Repercussions of social comparisons among heterogeneous workers. Journal of Labor Economics 29(2), 349375.Google Scholar
Stouffer, Samuel A., Suchman, Edward A., DeVinney, Leland C., Star, Shirley A., and Williams, Robin M. Jr. (1949) The American Soldier: Adjustment During Army Life, Vol. I. Stouffer, Samuel A., Lumsdaine, Arthur A., Lumsdaine, Marion H., Williams, Robin M. Jr., Smith, Brewster M., Janis, Irving L., Star, Shirley A., and Cottrell, Leonard S. Jr. (1949). The American Soldier: Combat and its Aftermath, Vol. II. Studies in Social Psychology in World War II, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Takahashi, Hidehiko, Kato, Motoichiro, Matsuura, Masato, Mobbs, Dean, Suhara, Tetsuya, and Okubo, Yoshiro (2009) When your gain is my pain and your pain is my gain: Neural correlates of envy and schadenfreude. Science 323(5916), 937939.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. Edward (1986) Differential migration, networks, information and risk. In Stark, O. (ed.) Research in Human Capital and Development, Vol. 4: Migration, Human Capital and Development. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 147171.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. Edward and Adelman, Irma (1996) Village Economics: The Design, Estimation, and Use of Villagewide Economic Models. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1899) The Theory of the Leisure Class. Reprints of Economic Classics: New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
Yitzhaki, Shlomo (1979) Relative deprivation and the Gini coefficient. Quarterly Journal of Economics 93(2), 321324.Google Scholar
Zizzo, Daniel J. and Oswald, Andrew J. (2001) Are people willing to pay to reduce others’ incomes? Annales d'Economie et de Statistique 63–64, 3965.Google Scholar