Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T14:51:43.576Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Information Rationale for the Power of Special Interests

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Susanne Lohmann*
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles

Abstract

Political decisions are often biased in favor of special interests at the expense of the general public, and they are frequently inefficient in the sense that the losses incurred by the majority exceed the gains enjoyed by the minority. This article explains the bias in terms of information asymmetries and the free-rider problem. First, incumbents increase their reelection prospects by biasing policy toward groups that are better able to monitor their activities. Second, because smaller groups are better able to overcome the free-rider problem of costly monitoring, policy will be biased in their favor. Third, the effect of asymmetric monitoring on voter welfare is ambiguous. The inefficiencies created by the policy bias are offset by a positively valued selection bias: Incumbents of above-average quality are more likely to survive voter scrutiny than are low-quality types.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1998

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Alesina, Alberto, and Cukierman, Alex. 1990. “The Politics of Ambiguity.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105(November):829–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E., and Chrystal, K. Alex. 1983. Political Economics. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Anderson, Kym, and Tyers, Rod. 1992. “Effects of Gradual Food Policy Reforms in the 1990s.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 19(January):124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, R. Douglas. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. 1994. “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters.” American Political Science Review 88(March):3347.10.2307/2944880CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, David P., and Ferejohn, John A.. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83(December): 1181–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 1988. Presidential Primaries and the Dynamics of Public Choice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bates, Robert H. 1981. Markets and States in Tropical Africa. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98(August):371400.10.2307/1886017CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bovard, James. 1991. The Fair Trade Fraud. New York: St. Martin's.Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3(October):144.10.1086/466560CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, Stephen, and Morris, Stephen. 1995. “On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests.” Journal of Political Economy 103(December):1210–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collyns, Charles, and Dunaway, Steven. 1987. “The Cost of Trade Restraints: The Case of Japanese Automobile Exports to the United States.” International Monetary Fund Staff Papers 34(March):150–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Condorcet, Marie Jean Antoine Nicolas Caritat, Marquis de, . 1785. Essai sur l'application de l'analyse à la probabilité des decisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. Paris, France: Imprimerie Royale.Google Scholar
Conway, Margaret M. 1991. Political Participation in the United States. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
Cornwell, Rupert. 1992. “Bush Travels the Land Bearing Election Gifts.” The Independent, 3 September, p. 10.Google Scholar
DeGroot, Morris H. 1970. Optimal Statistical Decisions. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Delli Carpini, Michael X., and Keeter, Scott. 1996. What Americans Know about Politics and Why It Matters. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, and Londregan, John. 1996. “The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics.” Journal of Politics 58(November):1132–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Economist. 1992. “A Survey of Agriculture.” December 12, special section.Google Scholar
Epstein, David, and O'Halloran, Sharyn. 1997. “Modeling Madison: A Multiple Principals Model of Interest Group Competition.” Columbia University. Typescript.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy J., and Pesendorfer, Wolfgang. 1996. “The Swing Voter's Curse.” American Economic Review 86(June):408–24.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M., and Helpman, Elhanan. 1996. “Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics.” Review of Economic Studies 63(April):265–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopenhayn, Hugo, and Lohmann, Susanne. 1996. “Fire-Alarm Signals and the Political Control of Regulatory Agencies.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 12(April):199216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, and Elliott, Kimberly Ann. 1994. Measuring the Costs of Protection in the United States. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Keech, William R., and Pak, Kyoungsan. 1989. “Electoral Cycles and Budgetary Growth in Veterans' Benefit Programs.” American Journal of Political Science 33(November):901–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kinder, Donald R., Adams, Gordon S., and Gronke, Paul W.. 1989. “Economics and Politics in the 1984 American Presidential Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 33(May):491516.10.2307/2111157CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kramer, Gerald H. 1983. “The Ecological Fallacy Revisited: Aggregate versus Individual-Level Findings on Economics and Elections, and Sociotropic Voting.” American Political Science Review 77(March):92111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipton, Michael. 1977. Why Poor People Stay Poor: Urban Bias in World Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1996. “Demosclerosis, or Special Interests ‘R’ Us: An Information Rationale for Policy Gridlock.” In The Political Economy of Conflict and Appropriation, ed. Garfinkel, Michelle R and Skaperdas, Stergios. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press. Pp. 119–30.10.1017/CBO9780511619984.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1998. “Rationalizing the Political Business Cycle: A Workhorse Model.” Economics and Politics 10(March):117.10.1111/1468-0343.00035CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne, and Hopenhayn, Hugo. 1998. “Delegation and the Regulation of Risk.” Games and Economic Behavior 23(May):222–46.10.1006/game.1997.0623CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Londregan, John B., and Poole, Keith T.. 1996. “Does High Income Promote Democracy?World Politics 49(October):130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lupia, Arthur. 1992. “Busy Voters, Agenda Control, and the Power of Information.” American Political Science Review 86(June):390404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, William G. 1992. The Changing American Mind. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.10.3998/mpub.10015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. “Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3 (Winter): 2478.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., and Schwartz, Thomas. 1984. “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms.” American Political Science Review 28(February):165–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1985. “Elections with Limited Information: A Fulfilled Expectations Model Using Contemporaneous Poll and Endorsement Data as Information Sources.” Journal of Economic Theory 36(June):5585.10.1016/0022-0531(85)90079-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. 1975. “The Political Business Cycle.” Review of Economic Studies 42(April):169–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Petersen, Peter G. 1996. Will America Grow Up Before It Grows Old? New York: Random House.Google Scholar
Price, Vincent, and Zaller, John. 1993. “Who Gets the News? Alternative Measures of News Reception and Their Implications for Research.” Public Opinion Quarterly 57(Summer):133–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Sam. 1994. Who We Are: A Portrait of America Based on the Latest U.S. Census. New York: Times Books.Google Scholar
Roemer, John E. 1994. “The Strategic Role of Party Ideology When Voters Are Uncertain about How the Economy Works.” American Political Science Review 88(June):327–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogoff, Kenneth. 1990. “Equilibrium Political Budget Cydes.” American Economic Review 80(March):2136.Google Scholar
Rogoff, Kenneth, and Sibert, Anne. 1988. “Elections and Macroeconomic Policy Cycles.” Review of Economic Studies 55 (January):116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanger, David E. 1996. “President Gains Deal on Tomatoes to Help Florida,” New York Times, 12 October. Pp. 1 and 8.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1978. The Giant Jigsaw Puzzle. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Stokes, Donald E. 1963. “Spatial Models of Party Competition.” American Political Science Review 57(June):368–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R. 1979. “A Rational Choice Perspective on Congressional Norms.” American Journal of Political Science 23(May): 245–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry R., Shepsle, Kenneth A., and Johnsen, Christopher. 1981. “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs.” Journal of Political Economy 89(August):642–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, James Q. 1980. “The Politics of Regulation.” In The Politics of Regulation, ed. Wilson, James Q.. New York: Basic Books. Pp. 364–72.Google Scholar
Wittman, Donald. 1989. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” Journal of Political Economy 97(December):1395–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zaller, John. 1998. “Politicians as Prize Fighters: Electoral Selection and Incumbency Advantage.” In Party Politics and Politicians, ed. Geer, John. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Pp. 125–85.Google Scholar
Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.