Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-7479d7b7d-8zxtt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-11T11:29:06.892Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 June 2020

Stefan Voigt
Affiliation:
Universität Hamburg
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Constitutional Economics
A Primer
, pp. 120 - 135
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. (2005). Constitutions, politics and economics: A review essay on Persson and Tabellini’s The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 43(4), 1025–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–401.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2005). A response to Albouy’s “A Reexamination Based on Improved Settler Mortality Data.” Mimeo: MIT.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. (2006). Reply to the revised (May 2006) version of David Albouy’s “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, 1167–99.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–63.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic Origins of Democracy and Dictatorship. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, Ph., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565611.Google Scholar
Aghion, Ph., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2005). Choosing Electoral Rules: Theory and Evidence from US Cities. Harvard Institute of Economic Research, Discussion Paper 2065.Google Scholar
Aidt, T. S., Dutta, J., & Loukoianova, E. (2006). Democracy comes to Europe: Franchise extension and fiscal outcomes 1830–1938. European Economic Review, 50(2), 249–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aidt, T. S., & Jensen, P. S. (2014). Workers of the world, unite! Franchise extensions and the threat of revolution in Europe, 1820–1938. European Economic Review, 72, 5275.Google Scholar
Albouy, D. (2008). The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Investigation of the Settler Mortality Data (June 2008). NBER Working Paper, W14130.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., & Glaeser, E. L. (2004). Fighting Poverty in the US and Europe: A World of Difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (2003). The Size of Nations. Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Alt, J., & Lassen, D. (2003). The political economy of institutions and corruption in American States. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 5(3), 341–65.Google Scholar
Anderson, G., Martin, D., Shugart, W. II, & Tollison, R. (1990). Behind the veil: The political economy of constitutional change. In: Crain, W. & Tollison, R. (eds.), Predicting Politics: Essays in Empirical Public Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 89100.Google Scholar
Anderson, G., Shugart, W. II, & Tollison, R. (1989). On the incentives of judges to enforce legislative wealth transfers. The Journal of Law & Economics, 32, 215–28.Google Scholar
Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J. S. (2010). The credibility revolution in empirical economics: How better research design is taking the con out of econometrics. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 24(2), 330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ardanaz, M., & Scartascini, C. (2014). The economic effects of constitutions: Do budget institutions make forms of government more alike? Constitutional Political Economy, 25(3), 301–29.Google Scholar
Aristotle, (1932). The Politics, with an English translation by H. Rackham, London: W. Heinemann.Google Scholar
Arndt, Chr., & Oman, Ch. (2006). Uses and Abuses of Governance Indicators. Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Arnold, F., & Freier, R. (2015). Signature requirements and citizen initiatives: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. Public Choice, 162(1), 4356.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1951). Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Arzaghi, M., & Henderson, J. V. (2005). Why countries are fiscally decentralizing. Journal of Public Economics, 89(7), 1157–89.Google Scholar
Asatryan, Z. (2016). The indirect effects of direct democracy: Local government size and non-budgetary voter initiatives in Germany. International Tax and Public Finance, 23(3), 580601.Google Scholar
Asatryan, Z., Baskaran, T., Grigoriadis, T., & Heinemann, F. (2017). Direct democracy and local public finances under cooperative federalism. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 119(3), 801–20.Google Scholar
Asatryan, Z., & de Witte, K. (2015). Direct democracy and local government efficiency. European Journal of Political Economy, 39, 5866.Google Scholar
Asian Development Bank (2005). Country Governance Assessment: Philippines. www.adb.org/Documents/Reports/CGA.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. (2000). Redistributing income under proportional representation. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1235–69.Google Scholar
Bannon, A. L. (2007). Designing a constitution-drafting process: Lessons from Kenya. The Yale Law Journal, 116, 1824–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. (1997). Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. (2000). Rule of law, democracy, and economic performance. In: O’Driscoll, G. Jr., Holmes, K., & Kirkpatrick, M. (eds.), 2000 Index of Economic Freedom. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation, 3149.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (1997). Parliament as a wealth-maximizing institution: The right to the residual and the right to vote. International Review of Law and Economics, 17, 455–74.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. (2000). Property rights and the evolution of the state. Economics of Governance, 1(1), 2551.Google Scholar
Baskaran, T., & da Fonseca, M. L. (2016). Electoral competition and endogenous political institutions: Quasi-experimental evidence from Germany. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 122, 4361.Google Scholar
Beard, C. (1913/1986). An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States; with a New Introduction by Forrest Mc Donald. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Beath, A., Christia, F., & Enikolopov, R. (2017). Direct democracy and resource allocation: Experimental evidence from Afghanistan. Afghanistan Journal of Development Economics, 124, 199213.Google Scholar
Beetsma, R. M., & Debrun, X. (2016). Fiscal Councils: Rationale and Effectiveness. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
Ben-Bassat, A. & Dahan, M. (2008). Social rights in the constitution and in practice. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36, 103–19.Google Scholar
Benoit, K. (2004). Models of electoral system change. Electoral Studies, 23, 363–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, K. (2007). Electoral laws as political consequences: Explaining the origins and change of electoral institutions. Political Science, 10(1), 363.Google Scholar
Benz, M., & Stutzer, A. (2004). Are voters better informed when they have a larger say in politics? – Evidence for the European Union and Switzerland. Public Choice, 119, 3159.Google Scholar
Berggren, N. (2003). The benefits of economic freedom: A survey. The Independent Review, 8(2), 193211.Google Scholar
Berggren, N., & Jordahl, H. (2005). Does free trade really reduce growth? Public Choice, 122, 99114.Google Scholar
Besley, T., & Payne, A. (2003). Judicial accountability and economic policy outcomes: Evidence from employment discrimination charges. Institute for Fiscal Studies (IFS), London, IFS Working Papers No. 03/11, http://dx.doi.org/10.1920/wp.ifs.2003.0311, Mimeo, June.Google Scholar
Besley, T. & Reynal-Querol, M. (2017). The Logic of Hereditary Rule: Theory and Evidence. CEPR Discussion Paper 11777.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch., & Rode, M. (Forthcoming). Regime types and regime change: A new dataset. Review of International Organizations.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch. and Voigt, S. (2017). Profiting from Natural Disaster? – Inquiring into the Effectiveness of Emergency Constitutions. Typescript. Universities of Aarhus and Hamburg.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch. and Voigt, S. (2018a). The architecture of emergency constitutions. International Journal of Constitutional Law, 16(1), 101–27.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch. and Voigt, S. (2018b). Why do governments call a state of emergency? European Journal of Political Economy, 54, 110–23.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch. and Voigt, S. (2019). Terrorism and Emergency Constitutions in the Muslim World. Typescript. Universities of Aarhus and Hamburg.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, Ch. and Voigt, S. (2020). When does terror induce a states of emergency? And what are the effects? Journal of Conflict Resolution, 64(4) 579613.Google Scholar
Blankart, Ch. (2000). The process of government centralization: A constitutional view. Constitutional Political Economy, 11(1), 2739.Google Scholar
Blomberg, S., Hess, G., & Weerapana, A. (2004). The impact of voter initiatives on economic activity. European Journal of Political Economy, 20(1), 207–26.Google Scholar
Blume, L., Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2014). Correlates and Determinants of Direct Democracy. Available at SSRN 2542156.Google Scholar
Blume, L., Müller, J., & Voigt, S. (2009a). The economic effects of direct democracy – A first global assessment. Public Choice, 140, 431–61.Google Scholar
Blume, L., Müller, J., Voigt, S., & Wolf, C. (2009b). The economic effects of constitutions: Replicating–and Extending – Persson and Tabellini. Public Choice, 139, 197225.Google Scholar
Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2007). The economic effects of human rights. Kyklos, 60(4), 509–38.Google Scholar
Blume, L., & Voigt, S. (2011). Federalism and decentralization – A critical survey of frequently used indicators. Constitutional Political Economy, 22(3), 238–64.Google Scholar
Boix, C. (1999). Setting the rules of the game: The choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 609–24.Google Scholar
Bordignon, M., Nannicini, T., & Tabellini, G. (2016). Moderating political extremism: Single round vs. runoff elections under plurality rule. American Economic Review, 106, 2349–70.Google Scholar
Bordo, M. D., Jonung, L., & Markiewicz, A. (2013). A fiscal union for the euro: Some lessons from history. CESifo Economic Studies, 59(3), 449–88.Google Scholar
Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–25.Google Scholar
Bradbury, J.C., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Bicameral legislatures and fiscal policy. Southern Economic Journal, 68(3), 646–59.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. (1980). The Power to Tax. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, G. & Buchanan, J. (1985). The Reason of Rules: Constitutional Political Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Hamlin, A. (2000). Democratic Devices and Desires. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Kliemt, H. (1994). Finite lives and social institutions. Kyklos, 47(4), 551–71.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Kliemt, H. (2019). Fiscal powers revisited: The Leviathan model after 40 years. In: Congleton, R., Grofman, B., & Voigt, S. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice. Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press, vol. 2, 263–85.Google Scholar
Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and Decision – The Pure Theory of Electoral Preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. (1975). The Limits of Liberty – Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. American Economic Review, 77, 243–50.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The Calculus of Consent – Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Bucur, C. & Rasch, B. E. (2019). Institutions for amending constitutions. In: Congleton, R., Grofman, B., & Voigt, S. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice. Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press, vol. 2, 156–76.Google Scholar
Carlsson, F., & Lundström, S. (2002). Economic freedom and growth: Decomposing the effects. Public Choice, 112, 335–44.Google Scholar
Caruso, G., Scartascini, C., & Tommasi, M. (2015). Are we all playing the same game? The economic effects of constitutions depend on the degree of institutionalization. European Journal of Political Economy, 38, 212–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheibub, J. A., Elkins, Z., & Ginsburg, T. (2013). Beyond presidentialism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 44(3), 515–44.Google Scholar
Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chilton, A. S., & Versteeg, M. (2015). Do constitutional rights make a difference? American Journal of Political Science.Google Scholar
Colomer, J. (2005). It’s parties that choose electoral systems (or, Duverger’s law upside down). Political Studies, 53, 121.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2003). On the merits of bicameral legislatures: Policy stability within partisan polities. Jahrbuch für Neue Politische Ökonomie, 22, 2949.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2006). On the merits of bicameral legislatures: Intragovernmental bargaining and policy stability. In Congleton, R. D. (ed.), Democratic Constitutional Design and Public Policy: Analysis and Evidence. Cambridge: MIT Press, 163–88.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. D. (2011). Perfecting Parliament: Constitutional Reform, Liberalism, and the Rise of Western Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. (1979). Constitutional change in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 165–75.Google Scholar
Cusack, T., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2007). Economic interests and the origins of electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 101(3), 373–91.Google Scholar
Cusack, T., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2010). Coevolution of capitalism and political representation: The choice of electoral systems. American Political Science Review, 104(02), 393403.Google Scholar
Cutrone, M., & McCarty, N. (2006). Does bicameralism matter? In: Weingast, B. & Wittman, D. (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 180–95.Google Scholar
Dalton, R. (2008). Direct democracy and good governance: Does it matter? In: Bowler, Sh. & Glazer, A. (eds.), Direct Democracy’s Impact on American Political Institutions. New York: Palgrave.Google Scholar
Davoodi, H., & Zou, H. F. (1998). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth: A cross-country study. Journal of Urban Economics, 43(2), 244–57.Google Scholar
Dicey, A. V. (1985). Introduction to the Study of the Law of the Constitution. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Fund.Google Scholar
Diermeier, D., & Myerson, R. (1999). Bicameralism and its consequences for the internal organization of legislatures. American Economic Review, 89(5), 1182–96.Google Scholar
Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2003). The new comparative economics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 595619.Google Scholar
Doucouliagos, H., & Ulubasoglu, M. (2008). Democracy and economic growth: A meta-analysis. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 6183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duverger, M. (1954). Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Duverger, M. (1980). A new political system model: Semi-presidential government. European Journal of Political Research, 8(2), 165–87.Google Scholar
Eggers, A., Freier, R., Grembi, V., & Nannicini, T. (2018). Regression discontinuity designs based on population thresholds: Pitfalls and solutions. American Journal of Political Science, 62(1), 210–29.Google Scholar
Eisenstadt, T. A., LeVan, A. C., & Maboudi, T. (2015). When talk trumps text: The democratizing effects of deliberation during constitution-making, 1974–2011. American Political Science Review, 109(03), 592612.Google Scholar
Elazar, D. (1995). From statism to federalism: A paradigm shift. Publius, 25(2), 518.Google Scholar
Elkins, Z., Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2009).The Endurance of National Constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elkins, Z., Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2014). The content of authoritarian constitutions. In: Ginsburg, T. & Simpser, A. (eds.), Constitutions in Authoritarian Regimes. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 141–64.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1984). Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1993). Constitution-making in Eastern Europe: Rebuilding the boat in the open sea. Public Administration, 71(1/2), 169217.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1995). Forces and mechanisms in the constitution-making process. Duke Law Journal, 45(2), 364–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. (2000a). Ulysses Unbound: Studies in Rationality, Precommitment, and Constraints. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (2000b). Arguing and bargaining in two constituent assemblies. University of Pennsylvania Journal of Constitutional Law, 2, 345421.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (2012). The optimal design of a constituent assembly. In: Landemore, H. & Elster, J. (eds.), Collective Wisdom: Principles and Mechanisms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 148–72.Google Scholar
Enikolopov, R., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2007). Decentralization and political institutions. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2261–90.Google Scholar
Facchini, G., & Testa, C. (2016). Corruption and bicameral reforms. Social Choice and Welfare, 47(2), 387411.Google Scholar
Farber, D. (2002). Rights as signals. Journal of Legal Studies, 31, 8398.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2001). The political economy of direct legislation: Direct democracy and local decision-making. Economic Policy, 33, 329–63.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P., Kirchgässner, G., & Schaltegger, Chr. (2003). Decentralized Taxation and the Size of Government: Evidence from Swiss State and Local Governments. CESifo Working Paper 1087, December.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P., & Savioz, M. (1997). Direct democracy matters for economic performance: An empirical investigation. Kyklos, 50(4), 507–38.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P., Schaltegger, Ch., & Schnellenbach, J. (2008). On government centralization and fiscal referendums. European Economic Review, 52, 611–45.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P., & Voigt, S. (2003). Economic growth and judicial independence: Cross-country evidence using a new set of indicators. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), 497527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, L. P., & Voigt, S. (2006). Making judges independent – Some proposals regarding the judiciary. In: Congleton, R. and Swedenborg, B. (eds.), Democratic Constitutional Design and Public Policy: Analysis and Evidence. Cambridge: MIT Press, 251–88.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. (1997). The politics of imperfection: The amendment of constitutions. Law and Social Inquiry, 22, 501.Google Scholar
Figueiredo, R. & Weingast, B. (2005). Self-enforcing federalism. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 21(1), 103–35.Google Scholar
Fish, M. S. (2006). Stronger legislatures, stronger democracies. Journal of Democracy, 17(1), 520.Google Scholar
Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2000). Happiness, economy and institutions. The Economic Journal, 110, 918–38.Google Scholar
Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2006). Direct democracy: Designing a living constitution. In: Congleton, R. (ed.), Democratic Constitutional Design and Public Policy: Analysis and Evidence. Cambridge: MIT Press, 3980.Google Scholar
Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2018). Public choice and happiness. In: Congleton, R., Grofman, B., & Voigt, S. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice. Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., & Eavey, Ch. (1987). Laboratory results on Rawls’s distributive justice. British Journal of Political Science, 17, 121.Google Scholar
Fuller, L. (1964). The Morality of Law. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Funk, P., & Gathmann, C. (2011). Does direct democracy reduce the size of government? New evidence from historical data, 1890–2000. The Economic Journal, 121(557), 1252–80.Google Scholar
Funk, P., & Gathmann, C. (2013). How do electoral systems affect fiscal policy? Evidence from cantonal parliaments, 1890–2000. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(5), 1178–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gagliarducci, S., Nannicini, T., & Naticchionia, P. (2011). Electoral rules and politicians’ behavior: A micro test. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 3(3), 144–74.Google Scholar
Gallie, W. (1956). Essentially contested concepts. Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society, 56, 167–98.Google Scholar
Gandhi, J. (2008). Dictatorial institutions and their impact on economic growth. European Journal of Sociology, 49(01), 330.Google Scholar
Gassebner, M., Lamla, M. J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2013). Extreme bounds of democracy. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(2), 171–97.Google Scholar
Geddes, B. (1999). What do we know about democratization after twenty years? Annual Review of Political Science, 2(1), 115–44.Google Scholar
Geddes, B., Wright, J., & Frantz, E. (2014). Autocratic breakdown and regime transitions: A new data set. Perspectives on Politics, 12(02), 313–31.Google Scholar
Gerring, J. (2006). Case Study Research: Principles and Practices. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gerring, J., & Thacker, Str. (2004). Political institutions and corruption: The role of unitarism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 295330.Google Scholar
Gerring, J., Thacker, Str., & Moreno, C. (2006). Are Federal Systems Better Than Unitary Systems? Mimeo: Boston University.Google Scholar
Gerring, J., Ziblatt, D., Van Gorp, J., & Arevalo, J. (2011). An institutional theory of direct and indirect rule. World Politics, 63(03), 377433.Google Scholar
Gilardi, F. (2002). Policy credibility and delegation to independent regulatory agencies: A comparative empirical analysis. Journal of European Public Policy, 9(6), 873–93.Google Scholar
Gilardi, F., & Maggetti, M. (2011). The independence of regulatory authorities. In: Levi Faur, D. (ed.), Handbook on the Politics of Regulation, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, Chapter 14, 201–15.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T. (2002). Economic analysis and the design of constitutional courts. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 3(1), 4985.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T. (2003). Judicial Review in New Democracies: Constitutional Courts in Asian Cases. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T., Elkins, Z., & Blount, J. (2009). Does the process of constitution-making matter? Annual Review of Law and Social Sciences, 5(5), 84105.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T., & Melton, J. (2015). Does the constitutional amendment rule matter at all? Amendment cultures and the challenges of measuring amendment difficulty. International Journal of Constitutional Law, 13(3), 686713.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T., & Versteeg, M. (2014). Why do countries adopt constitutional review? Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 30, 587622.Google Scholar
Goderis, B., & Versteeg, M. (2014). The diffusion of constitutional rights. International Review of Law and Economics, 39, 119.Google Scholar
Golden, M., & Picci, L. (2005). Proposal for a new measure of corruption, illustrated with Italian data. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 3775.Google Scholar
Goldwin, R., & Kaufman, A. (eds.). (1988). Constitution-Makers on Constitution-Making. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Gutmann, J., Hayo, B. & Voigt, S. (2017). Correlates and Determinants of Direct Democracy. Typescript.Google Scholar
Gutmann, J., Padovano, F., & Voigt, S. (2019). Perception vs. Experience: Explaining Differences in Corruption Measures Using Microdata. Munich: CESifo Working Paper No. 8027, December 2019.Google Scholar
Gutmann, J., & Voigt, S. (2016). Why Adopt a Federal Constitution? And Why Decentralize? – Searching for Proximate and Deep Causes. Typescript. Institute of Law & Economics, University of Hamburg.Google Scholar
Gutmann, J., & Voigt, S. (2018). Judicial independence in the EU: A puzzle. European Journal of Law and Economics, 1–18.Google Scholar
Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Block, W. (1996). Economic Freedom of the World: 1975–1995. Vancouver et al.: The Fraser Institute et al.Google Scholar
de Haan, J. (2007). Political institutions and economic growth reconsidered. Public Choice, 131, 281–92.Google Scholar
de Haan, J. & Eijffinger, S. (2019). The politics of central bank independence. In: Congleton, R., Grofman, B., & Voigt, S. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice. Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press, vol. 2, 499519.Google Scholar
de Haan, J., & Sturm, J. E. (2000). On the relationship between economic freedom and economic growth. European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 215–41.Google Scholar
Hadfield, G. K., & Weingast, B. R. (2014). Constitutions as coordinating devices. In: Galiani, S. & Sened, I. (eds.), Institutions, Property Rights, and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 121–50.Google Scholar
Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. R. (1995). The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. R. (1997). The political economy of democratic transitions. Comparative Politics, 29(3), 263–83.Google Scholar
Hall, R. & Jones, Ch. (1999). Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83116.Google Scholar
Hamilton, A., Madison, J., & Jay, J. (1788/1961). The Federalist Papers – With an Introduction, Table of Contents, and Index of Ideas by C. Rossiter. New York: Mentor.Google Scholar
Hanretty, C., & Koop, C. (2012). Measuring the formal independence of regulatory agencies. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(2), 198216.Google Scholar
Hanssen, A. (2004). Is there a politically optimal level of judicial independence? American Economic Review, 94(3), 712–29.Google Scholar
Hardin, R. (1989). Why a constitution? In: Grofman, B. & Wittman, D. (eds.), The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism. New York: Agathon Press, 100–20.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1939). Economic conditions of inter-state federalism. The New Commonwealth Quarterly, 5(2), 131–49.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. The American Economic Review, 35(4), 519–30.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1973). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. 1: Rules and Order. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1976). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. 2: The Mirage of Social Justice. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1979). Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol. 3: The Political Order of a Free People. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. (1988). The Fatal Conceit – The Errors of Socialism, ed. by Bartley III, W. W.. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2007). Explaining de facto judicial independence. International Review of Law and Economics, 27(3), 269–90.Google Scholar
Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2010). Determinants of constitutional change: Why do countries change their form of government? Journal of Comparative Economics, 38(3), 283305.Google Scholar
Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2013). Endogenous constitutions: Politics and politicians matter, economic outcomes don’t. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 88, 4761.Google Scholar
Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2016). Explaining constitutional change: The case of judicial independence. International Review of Law and Economics, 48, 113.Google Scholar
Hayo, B., & Voigt, S. (2019). The long-term relationship between de jure and de facto judicial independence. Economics Letters, 183, 108603.Google Scholar
Heller, W. (1997). Bicameralism and budget deficits: The effect of parliamentary structure on government spending. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 22(4), 485516.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. (2000). The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12(1), 131.Google Scholar
Hinnerich, B. T., & Pettersson‐Lidbom, P. (2014). Democracy, redistribution, and political participation: Evidence from Sweden 1919–1938. Econometrica, 82(3), 961–93.Google Scholar
Holmes, S. (1988). Precommitment and the paradox of democracy. In: Elster, J. & Slagstad, R. (eds.), Constitutionalism and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 195240.Google Scholar
Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Schakel, A., Niedzwiecki, S., Chapman Osterkatz, S., & Shair-Rosenfield, S. (2016). Measuring Regional Authority: A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance, vol. I. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hume, D. (1777/1987). Essays – Moral, Political, and Literary, ed. and with a Foreword, Notes, and Glossary by Miller, Eugene F., Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Classics.Google Scholar
Inman, R., & Rubinfeld, D. (2016). Economics of federalism. In: Parisi, F. (ed.), Oxford Handbook of Law and Economics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100, 165181.Google Scholar
Justesen, M. (2008). The effect of economic freedom on growth revisited: New evidence on causality from a panel of countries 1970–1999. European Journal of Political Economy, 24, 642–60.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2007). Worldwide Governance Indicators Project: Answering the Critics. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4149, Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=965077.Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, G., & Frey, B. (1990). Volksabstimmung und direkte Demokratie: Ein Beitrag zur Verfassungsdiskussion. In: Klingmann, H. D. & Kaase, M. (eds.), Wahlen und Wähler – Analysen aus Anlaß der Bundestagswahl. Westdeutscher Verlag: Opladen, 4269.Google Scholar
Knack, St. (2006). Measuring Corruption in Eastern Europe and Central Asia: A Critique of the Cross-Country Indicators. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3968.Google Scholar
Knack, St., & Keefer, Ph. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207–27.Google Scholar
Kocher, M., Strauß, S., & Sutter, M. (2006). Individual or team decision-making – Causes and consequences of self-selection. Games and Economic Behavior, 56, 259–70.Google Scholar
Kreuzer, M. (2010). Historical knowledge and quantitative analysis: The case of the origins of proportional representation. American Political Science Review, 104(02), 369–92.Google Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2000). The constitutional economics of autocratic succession. Public Choice, 103(1-2), 6384.Google Scholar
Kurtz, M., & Schrank, A. (2007a). Growth and governance: Models, measures, and mechanisms. Journal of Politics, 69(2), 538–54.Google Scholar
Kurtz, M., & Schrank, A. (2007b). Conceptualizing and measuring institutions: A view from political science. Mimeo: Prepared for Second Workshop on Measuring Law & Institutions held in Paris December 14–15, 2007.Google Scholar
Landes, W., & Posner, R. (1975). The independent judiciary in an interest-group perspective. The Journal of Law & Economics, 18(3), 875911.Google Scholar
Lascher, E., & Wassmer, R. (2007). Reconsidering Claims about the Secondary Benefits of Direct Democracy. Mimeo: Department of Public Policy and Administration, California State University at Sacramento.Google Scholar
Law, D., & Versteeg, M. (2013). Sham constitutions. California Law Review, 101(4), 863ff.Google Scholar
Lederman, D., Loayza, N., & Soares, R. (2005). Accountability and corruption. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 135.Google Scholar
Lessmann, C. (2014). Spatial inequality and development: Is there an inverted-U relationship? Journal of Development Economics, 106, 3551.Google Scholar
Levmore, S. (1992). Bicameralism: When are two decisions better than one? International Review of Law and Economics, 12, 145–62.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1994). A Study of Twenty-Seven Democracies 1945–1990. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of Democracy – Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
List, J. A. (2011). Why economists should conduct field experiments and 14 tips for pulling one off. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 315.Google Scholar
Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91(1), 225–39.Google Scholar
Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2004). Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to Britain’s “Age of Reform”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 705–63.Google Scholar
Ludwikowski, R. (1996). Constitution-Making in the Region of Former Soviet Dominance. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Lutz, D. (1994). Toward a theory of constitutional amendment. American Political Science Review, 88(2), 355–70.Google Scholar
Lutz, D. (2006). Principles of Constitutional Design. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Majone, G. (1996). Temporal Consistency and Policy Credibility: Why Democracies Need Non-majoritarian Institutions. San Domenico di Fiesole: Robert Schuman Centre Working Paper RSC No. 95/57.Google Scholar
Marshall, G., & Trotter, D. (1984). Constitutional Conventions: The Rules and Forms of Political Accountability. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2018). Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2016. Vienna, VA: Center for Systemic Peace.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, J. (1995). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative: Evidence from the last 30 years. Journal of Political Economy, 102(2), 587623.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, J. (2000). Fiscal effects of the voter initiative in the first half of the twentieth century. The Journal of Law & Economics, 43, 619–50.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, J. (2004). For the Many or the Few. The Initiative, Public Policy, and American Democracy. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCormick, R., & Tollison, R. (1981). Politicians, Legislation, and the Economy – An Inquiry into the Interest-Group Theory of Government. Boston: Nijhoff.Google Scholar
McGuire, M., & Olson, M. (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: The invisible hand. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 7296.Google Scholar
Melton, J., & Ginsburg, T. (2014). Does de jure judicial independence really matter? A reevaluation of explanations for judicial independence. Journal of Law and Courts, 2(2), 187217.Google Scholar
Meltzer, A., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–27.Google Scholar
Metelska-Szaniawska, Katarzyna (2016). Economic Effects of Post-Socialist Constitutions 25 Years from the Outset of Transition. Polish Studies in Economics, vol. 7. Frankfurt a. M.: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
Michel, S., & Cofone, I. N. (2017). Majority rules in constitutional referendums. Kyklos, 70(3), 402–24.Google Scholar
Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., Perotti, R., & Ristagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spendine. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 609–57.Google Scholar
Miller, G., & Hammond, T. (1989). Stability and efficiency in a separation-of-powers constitutional system. In: Grofman, B. & Wittman, D. (eds.), The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism. New York: Agathon Press, 8599.Google Scholar
Miller, L. (2010). Framing the State in Times of Transition – Case Studies in Constitution Making. Washington, DC: United States Institute of Peace.Google Scholar
Muthoo, A., & Shepsle, K. (2008). The constitutional choice of bicameralism. In: Helpman, E. (ed.), Institutions and Economic Performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 249–92.Google Scholar
Mueller, D. (1996). Constitutional Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mulligan, C. B., Gil, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Do democracies have different public policies than nondemocracies? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 5174.Google Scholar
North, D. (1981). Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D., Wallis, J., & Weingast, B. (2009). Violence and Social Orders – A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., Webb, S. B., & Weingast, B. R. (eds.). (2013). In the Shadow of Violence: Politics, Economics, and the Problems of Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Oates, W. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1120–49.Google Scholar
Oates, W. (2005). Toward a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and Public Finance, 12, 349–73.Google Scholar
Olken, B. (2007). Monitoring corruption: Evidence from a field experiment in Indonesia. Journal of Political Economy, 115(2), 200–49.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87(03), 567–76.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, P. (1992). Constitutional stability. Constitutional Political Economy, 3(2), 137–75.Google Scholar
Ordeshook, P. (1993). Some rules of constitutional design. In: Frankel, P. E., Miller, F., & Paul, J. (eds.), Liberalism and the Economic Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 198232.Google Scholar
Padovano, F., Sgarra, G., & Fiorino, N. (2003). Judicial branch, checks and balances and political accountability. Constitutional Political Economy, 14(1), 4770.Google Scholar
Panizza, U. (2001). Electoral rules, political systems, and institutional quality. Economics & Politics, 13(3), 311–42.Google Scholar
Patterson, S. C., & Mughan, A. (1999). Senates: Bicameralism in the Contemporary World. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press.Google Scholar
Persson, T. (2005). Forms of Democracy, Policy and Economic Development. Mimeo, January.Google Scholar
Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (1997). Separation of powers and political accountability. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 310–27.Google Scholar
Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Comparative politics and public finance. Journal of Political Economy, 108(6), 1121–61.Google Scholar
Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2007). Electoral rules and government spending in parliamentary democracies. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2(2), 155–88.Google Scholar
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2000). Political Economics – Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge et al.: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2002). Do Electoral Cycles Differ across Political Systems? Mimeo: Universities of Stockholm and Bocconi.Google Scholar
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2006). Democracy and development. American Economic Review, 96(2), 319–24.Google Scholar
Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2007). The Growth Effect of Democracy: Is It Heterogeneous and How Can It Be Estimated? CESifo Working Paper, 2016.Google Scholar
Pommerehne, W. (1983). Private vs. öffentliche Müllabfuhr: Nochmals betrachtet. Finanzarchiv, 41, 466–75.Google Scholar
Pommerehne, W. (1990). The empirical relevance of comparative institutional analysis. European Economic Review, 34, 458–68.Google Scholar
Plümper, Th., & Martin, Chr. (2003). Democracy, government spending, and economic growth: A political-economic explanation of the Barro-effect. Public Choice, 117, 2750.Google Scholar
Przeworski, A. (1991). Democracy and the Market – Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), 5169.Google Scholar
Ramseyer, M. (1994). The puzzling (in)dependence of courts: A comparative approach. Journal of Legal Studies, 23(2), 721–47.Google Scholar
Rasch, B. E., & Congleton, R. (2006). Constitutional amendment procedures. In: Congleton, R. (ed.), Democratic Constitutional Design and Public Policy: Analysis and Evidence. Cambridge: MIT Press, 319–42.Google Scholar
Raudla, Ringa (2010). Explaining Constitution-Makers’ Preferences: The Cases of Estonia and the United States. Constitutional Political Economy, 21(3):249–69.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge: Belknap.Google Scholar
Reynolds, A. (2002). The Architecture of Democracy – Constitutional Design, Conflict Management, and Democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1975). Federalism. In: Greenstein, Fred I. & Polsby, Nelson (eds.), The Handbook of Political Science, Vol. V: Government Institutions and Processes. Reading, MA: Addison Wesley.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1983). Political theory and the art of heresthetics. In: Finifter, A. (ed.), Political Science: The State of the Discipline. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association, 4767.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1984). The heresthetics of constitution-making: The presidency in 1787, with comments on determinism and rational choice. American Political Science Review, 78, 116.Google Scholar
Robinson, J., & Torvik, R. (2016). Endogenous presidentialism. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(4), 907–42.Google Scholar
Rockey, J. (2012). Reconsidering the fiscal effects of constitutions. European Journal of Political Economy, 28(3), 313–23.Google Scholar
Rodden, J. (2002). The dilemma of fiscal federalism: Grants and fiscal performance around the world. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 670–87.Google Scholar
Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving Leviathan: Fiscal federalism and the growth of government. International Organization, 57, 695729.Google Scholar
Rodden, J., & Wibbels, E. (2002). Beyond the fiction of federalism – Macroeconomic management in multitiered systems. World Politics, 54, 494531.Google Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2008). Second-best Institutions. Mimeo. Downloadable at: http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~drodrik/Second-best%20institutions%20paper.pdf.Google Scholar
Roll, R., & Talbott, J. (2001). Why Many Developing Countries Just Aren’t. Mimeo: University of California, Los Angeles.Google Scholar
Sanz, C. (2017). Direct Democracy and Government Size: Evidence from Spain. Available at ssrnc.com.Google Scholar
Sartori, G. (1994). Comparative Constitutional Engineering. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Scully, G. (2001). Institutions, policy, and economic growth. In: Shughart, W. & Razzoli, L. (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Public Choice, Cheltenham et al.: Edward Elgar, 611–27.Google Scholar
Seabright, P. (1996). Accountability and decentralization in government: An incomplete contracts model. European Economic Review, 40, 6189.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1999). Development as Freedom. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shugart, W. & Tollison, R. (1998). Interest groups and the courts. George Mason Law Review, 6, 953–69.Google Scholar
Smith, D., & Tolbert, C. (2004). Educated by Initiative. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Spamann, H. (2015). Empirical comparative law. Annual Review of Law and Social Science, 11, 131–53.Google Scholar
Spindler, Z., & de Vanssay, X. (2002). Constitutions and economic freedom: An international comparison. South African Journal of Economics, 70(6), 1135–46.Google Scholar
Stadelmann, D., Portmann, M., & Eichenberger, R. (2014). The law of large districts: How district magnitude affects the quality of political representation. European Journal of Political Economy, 35, 128–40.Google Scholar
Sutter, D. (1995). Potholes along the transition from authoritarian rule. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 39(1), 110–28.Google Scholar
Sutter, D. (2006). The deterrent effects of the International Criminal Court. In: Voigt, S., Albert, M., & Schmidtchen, D. (eds.), International Conflict Resolution Conferences on New Political Economy, vol. 23.Google Scholar
Sutter, M., Haigner, S., & Kocher, M. (2010). Choosing the carrot or the stick? Endogenous institutional choice in social dilemma situations. Review of Economic Studies online first.Google Scholar
Tanzi, V. (2000). Some politically incorrect remarks on decentralization and public finance. In: Dethier, J.-J. (ed.), Governance, Decentralization and Reform in China, India and Russia. Boston et al.: Kluwer, 4763.Google Scholar
Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, R. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45, 1341–78.Google Scholar
Tergiman, C. (2015). Institution design and public good provision: An experimental study of the vote of confidence procedure. Experimental Economics, 18(4), 697717.Google Scholar
Testa, C. (2010). Bicameralism and corruption. European Economic Review, 54(2), 181–98.Google Scholar
Thatcher, M. (2002). Delegation to independent regulatory agencies: Pressures, functions and contextual mediation. West European Politics, 25(1), 125–47.Google Scholar
Thießen, U. (2003a). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in high income OECD countries. Fiscal Studies, 24(3), 237–74.Google Scholar
Thießen, U. (2003b). Fiscal Federalism in Western European and Selected Other Countries: Centralization or Decentralization? What Is Better for Economic Growth. Berlin: DIW.Google Scholar
Thomas, M. (2006). What Do the Worldwide Governance Indicators Measure? Mimeo: Johns Hopkins University.Google Scholar
Ticchi, D., & Vindigni, A. (2010). Endogenous constitutions. Economic Journal, 120(543), 139.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Ch. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64, 416–24.Google Scholar
Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: A cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 399457.Google Scholar
Treisman, D. (2007). What have we learned about the causes of corruption from ten years of cross-national empirical research? Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 211–44.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G., & Money, J. (1997). Bicameralism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1974). The Social Dilemma: The Economics of War and Revolution. Blacksburg, VA: University Publications.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer.Google Scholar
de Vanssay, X., & Spindler, Z. (1994). Freedom and growth: Do constitutions matter? Public Choice, 78, 359–72.Google Scholar
Vaubel, R. (1996). Constitutional safeguards against centralization in federal states: An independent cross-section analysis. Constitutional Political Economy, 7(2), 79102.Google Scholar
Vibert, F. (2007). The Rise of the Unelected: Democracy and the New Separation of Powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (1997). Positive constitutional economics – A survey. Public Choice, 90, 1153.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (1999). Explaining Constitutional Change – A Positive Economics Approach. Cheltenham et al.: Elgar.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (2009). Explaining constitutional garrulity. International Review of Law and Economics, 29, 290303.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (2015). Veilonomics: On the use and utility of veils in constitutional political economy. In: Imbeau, Louis M. & Jacob, Steve (eds.), Behind a Veil of Ignorance? Power and Uncertainty in Constitutional Design. Heidelberg: Springer, 933.Google Scholar
Voigt, S. (2019). Institutional Economics – An Introduction. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & Blume, L. (2012). The economic effects of federalism and decentralization – A cross-country assessment. Public Choice, 151(1–2), 229–54.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & Blume, L. (2015). Does direct democracy make for better citizens? A cautionary warning based on cross-country evidence. Constitutional Political Economy, 26(4), 391420.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & El-Bialy, N. (2016). Identifying the determinants of aggregate judicial performance: Taxpayers’ money well spent? European Journal of Law and Economics, 41(2), 283319.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & Gutmann, J. (2013). Turning cheap talk into economic growth: On the relationship between property rights and judicial independence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(1), 6673.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., Gutmann, J., & Feld, L. P. (2015). Economic growth and judicial independence, a dozen years on: Cross-country evidence using an updated set of indicators. European Journal of Political Economy, 38, 197211.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & Kiwit, D. (1998). The role and evolution of beliefs, habits, moral norms, and institutions. In: Giersch, H. (Hrsg.), Merits and Limits of Markets. Berlin et al.: Springer, 83108.Google Scholar
Voigt, S., & Salzberger, E. (2002). Choosing not to choose: When politicians choose to delegate powers. Kyklos, 55(2), 247–68.Google Scholar
Wagemann, C., & Schneider, C. (2010). Qualitative Comparative Analysis (QCA) and fuzzy sets: Agenda for a research approach and a data analysis technique. Comparative Sociology, 9, 376–96.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. (1997). The political foundations of democracy and the rule of the law. American Political Science Review, 91(02), 245–63.Google Scholar
Wildasin, D. (1997). Externalities and Bailouts: Hard and Soft Budget Constraints in Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations. Nashville, TN: Mimeo.Google Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: An economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84(3), 849–72.Google Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1998). The Political Economy of Dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (2019). Are there types of dictatorship? In: Congleton, R., Grofman, B., & Voigt, S. (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Public Choice. Oxford et al.: Oxford University Press, vol. 2, 286310.Google Scholar
Wright, J. (2008). Do authoritarian institutions constrain? How legislatures affect economic growth and investment. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 322–43.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Stefan Voigt, Universität Hamburg
  • Book: Constitutional Economics
  • Online publication: 01 June 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108764445.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Stefan Voigt, Universität Hamburg
  • Book: Constitutional Economics
  • Online publication: 01 June 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108764445.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Stefan Voigt, Universität Hamburg
  • Book: Constitutional Economics
  • Online publication: 01 June 2020
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108764445.009
Available formats
×