Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T11:55:28.175Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Functional Law and Economics

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2009

Mark D. White
Affiliation:
City University of New York
Get access

Summary

During its relatively short history, the law-and-economics movement has developed a wide spectrum of methodological approaches, distinguishable for their respective emphasis on positive, normative, or functional economic analysis. Ronald Coase's “The Problem of Social Cost” is generally considered to provide the foundations of the first identifiable school of thought – the Chicago school of positive law and economics. Proponents of the Chicago school argue that market forces cause the common law to develop efficient, or wealth-maximizing, legal rules. As suggested by the Coase theorem, only transaction costs will impede first-best efficiency. An important premise of law and economics is that the common law is the result of an effort, conscious or not, to induce efficient outcomes. This premise, first intimated by Coase, and known as the hypothesis of efficiency of the common law, suggests that common-law rules enjoy a comparative advantage over legislation in fulfilling this task because of the evolutionary selection of common-law rules through adjudication and the gradual accretion of precedent. Much of the early work of the positive school of law and economics aims at explaining how common-law rules provide individuals with proper incentives such that society's wealth is maximized. To the extent that positive law-and-economics scholars formulate any prescriptive corollaries, they tend to focus on the reduction of transaction costs that stand in the way of wealth maximization.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Coase, Ronald H., 1960, “The Problem of Social Cost,” Journal of Law and Economics, 3, pp. 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A., 2007, Economic Analysis of Law, 6th ed., New York: Aspen Publishing, and Paul Rubin, 1977Google Scholar
Becker, Gary, 1983, “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, pp. 371–400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wittman, Donald, 1995, The Myth of Democratic Failure: Why Political Institutions Are Efficient, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Mackaay, Ejan, 2000, “History of Law and Economics,” in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and Geest, Gerrit, eds., Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, vol. 1, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing, pp. 65–117.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., 1974, “Good Economics – Bad Law,” Virginia Law Review, 60, pp. 483–492CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rowley, Charles K., 1981, “Social Sciences and the Law: The Relevance of Economic Theories,” Oxford Journal Legal Studies, 1, pp. 391–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, Gordon, 1971, The Logic of the Law, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, 2005, “Methodological Debates in Law and Economics: The Changing Contours of a Discipline,” in Parisi, Francesco and Rowley, Charles K., eds., The Origins of Law and Economics: Essays by the Founding Fathers, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 33–52Google Scholar
Klick, Jonathan and Mitchell, Gregory, 2006, “Government Regulation of Irrationality: Moral and Cognitive Hazards,” Minnesota Law Review, 90, pp. 1620–1663.Google Scholar
Vanberg, Viktor J., 1994, Rules and Choice in Economics, London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helland, Eric and Tabarrok, Alexander, 2002, “The Effect of Electoral Institutions on Tort Awards,” American Law and Economics Review, 4, pp. 341–370CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helland, Eric and Klick, Jonathan, 2007, “The Effect of Judicial Expedience on Attorney Fees in Class Actions,” Journal of Legal Studies, 36, pp. 171–188CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert, 1994, “Structural Adjudication and the New Law Merchant: A Model of Decentralized Law,” International Review of Law and Economics, 14, pp. 215–231CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey and Buchanan, James M., 1985, The Reason of Rules: Constitutional Political Economy, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., 1987, “The Constitution of Economic Policy,” American Economic Review, 77, p. 243.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon, 1962, The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John, 1971, A Theory of Justice, Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John (1953, “Cardinal Utility in Welfare Economics and in the Theory of Risk-Taking,” Journal of Political Economics, 61, pp. 434–435CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klick, Jonathan and Parisi, Francesco, 2003, “The Disunity of Unanimity,” Constitutional Political Economy, 14, pp. 83–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Congleton, Roger D., 1998, Politics by Principle, Not Interest: Toward Nondiscriminatory Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lando, Ole, 1976, “Contracts,” in David, R. et al., International Encyclopedia of Comparative Law, Tübingen: JCB Mohr, pp. 17–23Google Scholar
Mehren, Arthur and Trautman, Donald T., 1981, “Constitutional Control of Choice of Law: Some Reflections on the Hague,” Hofstra Law Review, 10, pp. 35–57Google Scholar
Kirgis, Jr. Frederic L., 1976, “The Roles of Due Process and Full Faith and Credit in Choice of Law,” Cornell Law Review, 62, pp. 94–150.Google Scholar
Ribstein, Larry, 1993, “Choosing Law by Contract,” Journal of Corporation Law, 18, pp. 245–300Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and O'Hara, Erin, 1998, “Conflict of Laws,” in Newman, Peter, ed., New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 491–492.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and Ribstein, Larry, 1998, “Choice of Law,” in Newman, Peter, ed., New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law, New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 238–240.Google Scholar
Romano, Roberta, 1985, “Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 1, pp. 225–283.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco, 1995, “Toward a Theory of Spontaneous Law,” Constitutional Political Economy, 6, pp. 211–231CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fon, Vincy and Parisi, Francesco, 2008, “Role-Reversibility, Stochastic Ignorance, and Social Cooperation,” Journal of Socio-Economics, 37, pp. 1061–1075.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce L., 1989, “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law,” Southern Economic Journal, 55, pp. 644–661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benson, Bruce L., 1990, The Enterprise of Law without the State, San Francisco: Pacific Research InstituteGoogle Scholar
Greif, Avner, 1989, “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders,” Journal of Economic History, 49, pp. 857–882CrossRefGoogle Scholar
The Morality of Law (1969, New Haven: Yale University Press
Stearns, Max L., 1994, “The Misguided Renaissance of Social Choice,” Yale Law Journal, 103, pp. 1243–1244CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shubik, Martin, 1987, Game Theory in the Social Sciences: Concepts and Solutions, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Benson, Bruce L. (1992, “Customary Law as a Social Contract: International Commercial Law,” Constitutional Political Economy, 3, pp. 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, Andrew, 1981, Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, David, 1969, Convention: A Philosophical Study, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey, 1982, “The Prisoner's Dilemma in the Invisible Hand: An Analysis of Intrafirm Productivity,” American Economic Review, 72, pp. 92–97Google Scholar
Fon, Vincy and Parisi, Francesco, 2003, “Reciprocity-Induced Cooperation,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, pp. 76–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fon, Vincy and Parisi, Francesco, 2007, “Matching Rules,” Managerial and Decision Economics, 28, pp. 1–14Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert, 1984, The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and Ghei, Nita, 2003, “The Role of Reciprocity in International Law,” Cornell International Law Journal, 36, pp. 93–123.Google Scholar
Klick, Jonathan and Parisi, Francesco, 2008, “Social Networks, Self-Denial, and Median Preferences: Conformity as an Evolutionary Strategy,” Journal of Socio-Economics, 137, pp. 1319–1327CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James (1975, The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan, Chicago: University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
List, John A., 2004, “Neoclassical Theory versus Prospect Theory: Evidence from the Marketplace,” Econometrica, 72, pp. 615–625.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, Alan, 2008, “How Much Irrationality Does the Market Permit?Journal of Legal Studies, 37, pp. 131–159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert, 2002, The Strategic Constitution, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Klick, Jonathan and Parisi, Francesco, 2005, “Wealth, Utility, and the Human Dimension,” NYU Journal of Law and Liberty, 1, pp. 590–608Google Scholar
Parisi, Francesco and Klick, Jonathan, 2004, “Functional Law and Economics: The Search for Value-Neutral Principles of Lawmaking,” Chicago-Kent Law Review, 79, pp. 431–450.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×