Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T14:47:54.059Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Monotonicity in undirected networks

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 February 2023

Paolo Boldi
Affiliation:
Dipartimento di Informatica, Università degli Studi di Milano, Milan, Italy
Flavio Furia
Affiliation:
Dipartimento di Informatica, Università degli Studi di Milano, Milan, Italy
Sebastiano Vigna*
Affiliation:
Dipartimento di Informatica, Università degli Studi di Milano, Milan, Italy
*
*Corresponding author. Email: sebastiano.vigna@unimi.it
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Is it always beneficial to create a new relationship (have a new follower/friend) in a social network? This question can be formally stated as a property of the centrality measure that defines the importance of the actors of the network. Score monotonicity means that adding an arc increases the centrality score of the target of the arc; rank monotonicity means that adding an arc improves the importance of the target of the arc relatively to the remaining nodes. It is known that most centralities are both score and rank monotone on directed, strongly connected graphs. In this paper, we study the problem of score and rank monotonicity for classical centrality measures in the case of undirected networks: in this case, we require that score, or relative importance, improves at both endpoints of the new edge. We show that, surprisingly, the situation in the undirected case is very different, and in particular that closeness, harmonic centrality, betweenness, eigenvector centrality, Seeley’s index, Katz’s index, and PageRank are not rank monotone; betweenness and PageRank are not even score monotone. In other words, while it is always a good thing to get a new follower, it is not always beneficial to get a new friend.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

The study of centrality in networks goes back to the late forties. Since then, several measures of centrality with different properties have been proposed—see Boldi & Vigna (Reference Boldi and Vigna2014) for a survey. To sort out which measures are more apt for a specific application, one can try to classify them through some axioms that they might satisfy or not.

In Boldi & Vigna (Reference Boldi and Vigna2014), Boldi et al. (Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017), two of the authors studied in particular score monotonicity and rank monotonicity on directed graphs. The first property says that when an arc $x\to y$ is added to the graph, the score of $y$ strictly increases (Sabidussi, Reference Sabidussi1966). Rank monotonicity (Chien et al., Reference Chien, Dwork, Kumar, Simon and Sivakumar2004) states that after adding an arc $x\to y$ , all nodes with a score smaller than (or equal to) $y$ still have a score smaller than (or equal to) $y$ . Score and rank monotonicity complement themselves: score monotonicity tells us that “something good happens”; rank monotonicity tells us that “nothing bad happens.”

In some way, both axioms aim at answering the following question: is it always worth it for a node in a directed social network (say, Twitter) to have a new incoming arc (in Twitter parlance, a new follower)? The two monotonicity axioms introduced above give a different interpretation of what “worth” means. “Score monotonicity” interprets it simply as an increase of score: if you get a new follower, does your score always increase? “Rank monotonicity” interprets it with respect to the score of other nodes: if you get a new follower, do you still dominate (have a larger score than) the same nodes you used to dominate before, and possibly more? As we said, for most notions of importance (i.e., centrality measures) the answer to both questions is “yes,” under very mild assumptions (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017).

Once we move to undirected graphs, however, previous definitions and results are no longer applicable. Thus, in this paper, we aim at answering a subtly different question: is it always worth it for an actor in an undirected social network (say, Facebook) to have a new friend? Again, “worth” can be taken to refer to its score or to its rank. In this paper, we propose more precise definitions that are natural extensions of score and rank monotonicity to the undirected case and prove results about classical centrality measures: closeness (Bavelas, Reference Bavelas1948), harmonic centrality (Beauchamp, Reference Beauchamp1965), betweenness (Anthonisse, Reference Anthonisse1971; Freeman, Reference Freeman1977), and four variants of spectral ranking (Vigna, Reference Vigna2016)—eigenvector centrality (Landau, Reference Landau1895; Berge, Reference Berge1958), Katz’s index (Katz, Reference Katz1953), Seeley’s index (Seeley, Reference Seeley1949), and PageRank (Page et al., Reference Page, Brin, Motwani and Winograd1998).

As we will see, while in some cases we can witness some score increase, except for Seeley’s index none of the centrality measures we consider is rank monotone. This is somehow surprising and will yield some reflection.

Note that adding a single edge to an undirected graph is equivalent to adding two opposite arcs in a directed graph, which may suggest why the situation is so different, at least from the mathematical viewpoint. Understanding under which conditions a centrality measure does not satisfy an axiom will be a theme that we will try to pursue in the course of the discussion.

We provide classes of counterexamples of arbitrary size; moreover, we always provide both a counterexample in which the loss of rank happens in the less important endpoint of the new edge and a counterexample in which the loss of rank happens in the more important endpoint of the new edge. In this way, we will show that it is impossible for the two actors in the social network creating the new edge to predict whether the edge will be beneficial even knowing their relative importance. The results obtained in this paper are summarized in Table 1.

Table 1. Summary of the results of this paper for the case of connected undirected graphs. For comparison, recall that (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017) all the centrality measures listed are both score and rank monotone on strongly connected directed graphs, with the only exception of betweenness that is neither. We include degree (which is trivially score monotone and strictly rank monotone on all graphs) for completeness

To prove general results in the case of spectral rankings, we exploit the connection between spectral rankings and graph fibrations (Boldi & Vigna, Reference Boldi and Vigna2002; Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Lonati, Santini and Vigna2006), which makes us able to reduce computations on graphs with a variable number of nodes to similar computations on graphs with a fixed number of nodes. This approach to proofs, which we believe is of independent interest, makes it possible to use analytic techniques to control the values assumed by eigenvector centrality, Katz’s index, and PageRank.

We conclude the paper with some anecdotal evidence from a medium-sized real-world network, showing that violations of monotonicity do happen also in practice.

Most of the computations in this paper (in particular, the manipulation of complex rational functions) have been performed using Sage (The Sage Developers, 2018). All our Sage worksheets are available as public-domain software on the Zenodo platform.Footnote 1

2. Graph-theoretical preliminaries

While we will focus on simple undirected graphs, we are going to make use of some proof techniques that require handling more general types of graphs.

A (directed multi)graph $G$ is defined by a set $N_G$ of nodes, a set $A_G$ of arcs, and by two functions $s_G,t_G\,:\,A_G\to N_G$ that specify the source and the target of each arc; a loop is an arc with the same source and target; the main difference between this definition and the standard definition of a directed graph is that we allow for the presence of multiple arcs between a pair of nodes. When we do not need to distinguish between multiple arcs, we write $x\to y$ to denote an arc with source $x$ and target $y$ .

Since we do not need to discriminate between graphs that only differ because of node names, we will often assume that $N_G=\{\,0,1,\dots,n_G-1\,\}$ where $n_G$ is the number of nodes of $G$ . Every graph $G$ has an associated $n_G \times n_G$ adjacency matrix, also denoted by $G$ , where $G_{xy}$ is the number of arcs from $x$ to $y$ .

A (simple) undirected graph is a looplessFootnote 2 graph $G$ such that for all $x,y \in N_G$ we have $G_{xy}=G_{yx}\leq 1$ . In other words, there is at most one arc between any two nodes, and if there is an arc from $x$ to $y$ , there is also an arc in the opposite direction. In an undirected graph, an edge between $x$ and $y$ is a pair of arcs $x\to y$ and $y\to x$ , and it is denoted by $x\mbox{---}y$ . This definition is equivalent to the more common notion that an edge is an unordered set of nodes, but it makes it possible to mix undirected and directed graphs: indeed, even in drawings we will freely mix arcs and edges. For undirected graphs, we prefer to use the word “vertex” instead of “node.”

3. Score and rank monotonicity axioms on undirected graphs

One of the most important notions that researchers have been trying to capture in various types of graphs is “node centrality”: ideally, every node (often representing an individual) has some degree of influence or importance within the social domain under consideration, and one expects such importance to be reflected in the structure of the social network; centrality is a quantitative measure that aims at revealing the importance of a node.

Formally, a centrality (measure or index) is any function $c$ that, given a graph $G$ , assigns a real number $c_G(x)$ to every node $x$ of $G$ , with larger values implying more importance. Countless notions of centrality have been proposed over time, for different purposes and with different aims; some of them were originally defined only for a specific category of graphs. Later some of these notions of centrality have been extended to more general classes; all centrality measures discussed in this paper can be defined properly on all undirected graphs (even disconnected ones). We assume from the beginning that the centrality measures under examination are invariant by isomorphism; that is, that they depend just on the structure of the graph and not on a particular name chosen for each node. In particular, all nodes exchanged by an automorphism necessarily share the same centrality score, and we will use this fact to simplify our computations.

Axioms are useful to isolate properties of different centrality measures and make it possible to compare them. One of the oldest papers to propose this approach is Sabidussi (Reference Sabidussi1966), which introduced score monotonicity, and many other proposals have appeared in the last few decades.

In this paper, we will be dealing with two properties of centrality measures:

Definition 1. (Score monotonicity) Given an undirected graph $G$ , a centrality $c$ is said to be score monotone on $G$ iff for every pair of non-adjacent vertices $x$ and $y$ we have that

\begin{equation*} c_G(x) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(x) \quad \text {and}\quad c_G(y) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(y), \end{equation*}

where $G^{\prime}$ is the graph obtained adding the new edge $x-y$ to $G$ . We say that $c$ is score monotone on undirected graphs iff it is score monotone on all undirected graphs.

Definition 2. (Rank monotonicity) Given an undirected graph $G$ , a centrality $c$ is said to be rank monotone Footnote 3 on $G$ iff for every pair of non-adjacent vertices $x$ and $y$ we have that for all vertices $z\neq x,y$

\begin{equation*} c_G(z) \lt c_{G}(x) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(x) \quad {and}\quad c_G(z) \lt c_{G}(y) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(y), \end{equation*}

and moreover

\begin{equation*} c_G(z) \leq c_{G}(x) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z)\leq c_{G^{\prime}}(x) \quad {and}\quad c_G(z)\leq c_{G}(y) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z) \leq c_{G^{\prime}}(y), \end{equation*}

where $G^{\prime}$ is the graph obtained adding the new edge $x-y$ to $G$ . It is said to be strictly rank monotone on $G$ if instead

\begin{equation*} c_G(z) \leq c_{G}(x) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(x) \quad {and}\quad c_G(z) \leq c_{G}(y) \Rightarrow c_{G^{\prime}}(z) \lt c_{G^{\prime}}(y) \end{equation*}

We say that $c$ is (strictly) rank monotone on undirected graphs iff it is (strictly) rank monotone on all undirected graphs.

Score monotonicity tells us that in absolute terms, the new edge is beneficial to $x$ and $y$ . Rank monotonicity tells us that in relative terms, the new edge is not hurting them, in the sense that nodes that were (strictly) dominated by $x$ or $y$ are still (strictly) dominated. Finally, strict rank monotonicity is a stronger property that implies, besides preservation of dominance, an improvement, as additionally all nodes in a score tie with $x$ or $y$ will have a strictly smaller score after adding the new edge. As a sanity check, we note that degree, the simplest centrality measure, is both score monotone and strictly rank monotone.

These three properties can be studied on the class of all undirected graphs or only on the class of connected graphs, giving rise to six possible “degrees of monotonicity” that every given centrality may satisfy or not. This paper studies these different degrees of monotonicity for some of the most popular centrality measures, also comparing the result obtained with the corresponding properties in the directed case.

With respect to the directed case, there is an important difference: violation of the axioms may happen on one of the nodes involved, or on both. While we never witnessed the latter situation, there is in the first case a distinction that we feel important enough to deserve a name:

Definition 3. A violation of score monotonicity is a top violation if the endpoint of the new edge whose scores decreases is more important than the other. It is a bottom violation otherwise. The same distinction applies to violations of rank monotonicity.

Top violations are somewhat sociologically natural: if a network superstar becomes friend with a nobody, it is not surprising that the nobody increases their popularity, whereas the superstar loses a bit of charm. Bottom violations, however, are much less natural: in the same context, the nobody sees their importance decrease, nurturing in a bizarre inversion of flow the superstar popularity.

As we already anticipated, and differently from the directed case, all centrality measures we consider, except for Seeley’s index (which however is trivial in this context—see Section 9) will turn out to be not rank monotone. Moreover, most centralities are not score monotone. As a consequence, this paper is a sequence of counterexamples (to score monotonicity and to rank monotonicity, hence a fortiori to its strict version): all counterexamples exhibit an undirected graph $G$ and two non-adjacent vertices $x$ and $y$ such that when you add the edge $x-y$ to $G$ , $x$ decreases its score, or its rank with respect to some other vertex $z$ . We may call $x$ the “losing endpoint” (i.e., the one that is hurt by the addition of the edge).

Not all counterexamples are equally good, though. We will make an effort to have the theoretically strongest counterexamples we can find, and we will also look for properties that have a practical interpretation. More in detail:

  • all our counterexamples are connected;

  • all our counterexamples are parametric graphs that can be instantiated in graphs of arbitrarily large size;

  • we always give both top and bottom violation counterexamples; thus, even knowing whether you are more or less important than your new neighbor will not help in knowing if you will gain or lose from the new edge;

  • in all our counterexamples the losing endpoint of the new edge is also demoted; that is, the number of nodes with a larger score than the losing endpoint increases after adding the new edge.

The last point is particularly important because demotion is not implied by the lack of rank monotonicity: it may be the case that $x$ used to be more important than $z$ and it becomes less important than $z$ after the addition of the edge $x-y$ , but still the number of nodes that are more important than $x$ becomes smaller with the addition of $x-y$ . The lack of demotion might suggest a weaker notion of rank monotonicity, in which the number of nodes whose score dominates $x$ (or $y$ ) decreases (such a notion is strictly weaker as it is implied by rank monotonicity). However, this weaker notion is not very appealing from a practical viewpoint, because it is not locally testable—it has no immediate consequence for the relative importance of an endpoint of the edge and another vertex. Proving demotion implies that the counterexamples in this paper are strong enough to violate also the weaker notion of monotonicity described above.

4. Geometric centralities

Since adding a new edge can only shorten existing shortest paths or create new ones, it is immediate to show that harmonic centrality is score monotone; for the same reason, closeness centrality is score monotone on connected graphs, whereas counterexamples similar to those of the directed case of Boldi & Vigna (Reference Boldi and Vigna2014) prove that closeness is not score monotone in the general case.

Less intuitively, neither closeness nor harmonic centrality are rank monotone in the undirected case. The family of counterexamples we found shows that adding an edge can shorten distances in ways that are much more useful for some vertices not incident on the new edge than on its endpoints.

Our counterexample for rank monotonicity of closeness and harmonic centrality is shown in Figure 1. The idea behind the graph is that the edge $0-1$ reduces the distance between vertex $0$ and the vertices labeled with $4$ , but does not reduce the distance between vertex $0$ and vertex $3$ (and more importantly between vertex $0$ and the star around vertex $3$ ). Thus, the vertices labeled with $4$ will gain more centrality from the new edge than vertex $0$ , and for appropriate values of $j$ and $k$ , we will be able to prove a violation of rank monotonicity (all vertices labeled with $4$ share the same centrality). The stars of size $r$ around vertex $1$ and vertex $2$ will instead be useful by giving us some more space to play with the relative importance of the endpoints of the new edge, tuning the graph in Figure 1 to be an example of top or bottom violation.

Figure 1. A counterexample to rank monotonicity for closeness and harmonic centrality. There is a star with $j$ leaves around vertex $0$ , a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $3$ , a star with $r$ leaves around vertex $1$ , and a star with $r$ leaves around vertex $2$ . Before adding the edge $0-1$ , the score of vertex $0$ is larger than the score of the vertices labeled with $4$ ; after, it is smaller.

4.1 Closeness

We recall that closeness of a vertex $x$ is defined as the reciprocal of its peripherality

\begin{equation*} p(x)=\sum _{y\in N_G}d(x,y), \end{equation*}

where $d(x,y)$ is the distance (i.e., the length of a shortest path) between $x$ and $y$ .

We denote for simplicity with $\textrm{pre}({-})$ and $\textrm{post}({-})$ the peripherality of the graph in Figure 1 before and after adding the edge $0-1$ . Then,

\begin{align*} \textrm{pre}(0)&=15 + j + 4 k + 11r & \textrm{post}(0)&=9 + j + 4 k + 5r \\ \textrm{pre}(1)&=15 +6j + 3 k + 3r & \textrm{post}(1)&=9 + 2j + 3 k + 3r \\ \textrm{pre}(4)&=15 + 6j + 3 k + 5r & \textrm{post}(4)&=13 + 4j + 3 k + 5r. \end{align*}

We are interested in finding solutions, if they exists, to the set of inequalities

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \gt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\lt \textrm {pre}(4), \textrm {post}(0)\gt \textrm {post}(4), \end{equation*}

which specify that vertex $0$ violates rank monotonicity with respect to vertices labeled with $4$ and that it is less important than vertex $1$ (recall we are manipulating the reciprocal of closeness), and

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \lt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\lt \textrm {pre}(4), \textrm {post}(0)\gt \textrm {post}(4), \end{equation*}

that correspond to the analogous case in which vertex $0$ is more important than vertex $1$ . There are infinite solutions for both sets of inequalities, and in particular, $j=5r$ , $k=18r$ ( $r\geq 2$ ), and $j=4r+4$ , $k=12r+17$ ( $r\geq 1$ ) satisfy the first and second set, respectively.

Theorem 1. Closeness is not rank monotone on the graphs of Figure 1 for $r\geq 2$ , $j=5r$ , and $k=18r$ (bottom violation) and for $r\geq 1$ , $j=4r+4$ , and $k=12r+17$ (top violation).

While the family of graphs we consider contains graphs of unbounded size, each graph has just ten distinct peripherality scores. We can thus compare exactly the peripherality of all vertices with that of vertex $0$ before and after adding the new edge. It is easy to see that for the parameter sets of the previous theorem, all vertices, except the $j$ vertices labeled with $4$ and sometimes vertex 1, maintain the same relative position to vertex $0$ after adding the edge $0-1$ . Thus, in both cases vertex $0$ is demoted by at least $j-1$ positions.

4.2 Harmonic centrality

The counterexample in Figure 1 works also for harmonic centrality, which is not surprising as the only difference between closeness and harmonic centrality is the usage of a harmonic mean instead of an arithmetic mean.

Denoting this time with $\textrm{pre}({-})$ and $\textrm{post}({-})$ the harmonic centrality of the graph in Figure 1 before and after adding the edge $0-1$ , we have

\begin{align*} \textrm{pre}(0)&=\frac{137}{60} + j + \frac 14k + \frac{11}{30}r & \textrm{post}(0)&=\frac{10}{3} + j + \frac 14k + \frac 56r \\[4pt] \textrm{pre}(1)&=\frac{137}{60} + \frac 16j + \frac 13k +\frac 32r & \textrm{post}(1)&=\frac{10}{3} + \frac 12j + \frac 13k + \frac 32r\\[4pt] \textrm{pre}(4)&= \frac{137}{60}+ \frac 16j + \frac 13k + \frac 56r & \textrm{post}(4)&=\frac{29}{12} + \frac 14j + \frac 13k + \frac 56r . \end{align*}

This time we are interested in finding solutions, if they exists, to the set of inequalities

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \lt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\gt \textrm {pre}(4), \textrm {post}(0)\lt \textrm {post}(4) \end{equation*}

and

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \gt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\gt \textrm {pre}(4), \textrm {post}(0)\lt \textrm {post}(4). \end{equation*}

There are again infinite solutions for both sets of inequalities, and in particular, $j=26r$ , $k=247r$ ( $r\geq 1$ ), and $j=26r$ , $k=246r$ ( $r\geq 1$ ) satisfy the first and second set, respectively.

Theorem 2. Harmonic centrality is not rank monotone on the graphs of Figure 1 for $r\geq 1$ , $j=26r$ , and $k=247r$ (bottom violation) and for $r\geq 1$ , $j=26r$ , and $k=246r$ (top violation).

Also in this case, for the same parameter sets, all vertices, except the $j$ vertices labeled with $4$ and sometimes vertex $1$ , maintain the same relative position to vertex $0$ after adding the edge $0-1$ . Thus, vertex $0$ is demoted by at least $j-1$ positions.

5. Betweenness

Betweenness is neither score nor rank monotone on directed graphs (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017); the same is true in the undirected case, as shown in the graph of Figure 2. Intuitively, the new edge puts $2$ on many shortest paths (e.g., those between any vertex labeled with $3$ and any vertex labeled with $4$ ) that before needed to pass on the upper route of the rectangle. Vertex $0$ , instead, does not gain as much by the addition of the edge.

Figure 2. A counterexample to score and rank monotonicity for betweenness. There is a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $0$ , a star with $h$ leaves around vertex $1$ , and $j$ vertices labeled with $4$ with the same neighborhood. Before adding the edge $0-1$ , the score of vertex $0$ is larger than the score of vertex $2$ ; after the addition, it becomes smaller. Moreover, the score of vertex 0 does not change when the edge is added.

Denoting with $\textrm{pre}({-})$ and $\textrm{post}({-})$ the value of betweenness before and after adding the edge $0-1$ , we have

\begin{align*} \textrm{pre}(0)&=\frac{k(2h+2j+k+11)}2 & \textrm{post}(0)&=\frac{k(2h+2j+k+11)}2\\ \textrm{pre}(1)&=\frac{h^2+(2j+2k+11)h+3k+7}2 & \textrm{post}(1)&=\frac{h^2+(2j+2k+11)h+(k+1)(j+4)+4}2\\ \textrm{pre}(2)&=\frac{(2h+2)j+3h+k+5}2 & \textrm{post}(2)&=\frac{(2h+k+2)j+3h+2k+6}2 . \end{align*}

Observe that $\textrm{pre}(0)=\textrm{post}(0)$ , showing that score monotonicity is violated. To prove that also rank monotonicity does not hold, we are interested in finding solutions to the set of inequalities

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \lt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\gt \textrm {pre}(2), \textrm {post}(0)\lt \textrm {post}(2) \end{equation*}

and

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}(0) \gt \textrm {pre}(1), \textrm {pre}(0)\gt \textrm {pre}(2), \textrm {post}(0)\lt \textrm {post}(2). \end{equation*}

There are infinite solutions for both sets of inequalities, and in particular, $h=k$ , $j= \lfloor (k^2-4k-15)/2 \rfloor$ , $k\geq 13$ , and $k=2+h$ , $j=4h$ , $h\geq 12$ satisfy the first and second set, respectively.

Theorem 3. Betweenness is not rank monotone on the graph of Figure 2, for $k=2+h$ , $j=4h$ , $h\geq 12$ , (top violation) and for $h=k$ , $j= \lfloor (k^2-4k-15)/2 \rfloor$ , $k\geq 13$ (bottom violation).

Also in this case, we have just nine different betweenness scores, which makes it possible to show that in both cases vertex $0$ is demoted by at least one position.

6. Eigenvector centrality

Eigenvector centrality is probably the oldest attempt at deriving a centrality from matrix information: a first version was proposed by Landau (Reference Landau1895) for matrices representing the results of chess tournaments, and it was defined in full generality by Berge (Reference Berge1958); it was rediscovered many times since then. One considers the adjacency matrix of the graph and computes its left or right dominant eigenvector (in our case, the two eigenvectors coincide): the result is thus defined modulo a scaling factor; furthermore, if the graph is (strongly) connected, the result is unique (again, modulo the scaling factor) by the Perron–Frobenius theorem (Berman & Plemmons, Reference Berman and Plemmons1994).

It is not difficult to find anecdotal examples of violation of rank (and even score, fixing a normalization) monotonicity in simple examples. In Figure 3, we show a very simple graph that does not satisfy score monotonicity under the most obvious forms of normalization. In particular, the score of vertex $0$ decreases after adding the edge $0-1$ both in norm $\ell _1$ and norm $\ell _2$ , and even when projecting the constant vectorFootnote 4 $\textbf 1$ onto the dominant eigenspace, which is an alternative way of circumventing the scaling factor (Vigna, Reference Vigna2016). The intuition is that once we close the triangle we create a cycle that absorbs a large amount of rank, effectively decreasing the score of vertex $0$ .

Figure 3. A counterexample to score monotonicity for eigenvector centrality. After adding the edge $0-1$ , the score of vertex $0$ decreases: in norm $\ell _1$ , from $0.30656$ to $0.29914$ ; in norm $\ell _2$ , from $0.65328$ to $0.63586$ , and when projecting the constant vector $\textbf 1$ onto the dominant eigenspace, from $1.39213$ to $1.35159$ .

A similar counterexample, shown in Figure 4, proves that eigenvector centrality does not satisfy rank monotonicity. Before adding the edge $0-1$ , the score of vertex $1$ used to be larger than the score of vertex $3$ ; the converse is true after the addition of the edge. This counterexample, however, is not very satisfactory as vertex $1$ is not demoted—in fact, the opposite happens; on the other hand, the set of vertices that dominate it changes completely with the addition of the new edge, showing that eigenvector centrality can undergo turbulent modifications upon a simple perturbation: this example thus shows that the known sensitivity of eigenvectors to matrix perturbation (Stewart & Sun, Reference Stewart and Sun1990) remains true even in our very restricted setting (dominant eigenvectors of symmetric irreducible 0 $-$ 1 matrices perturbed by setting two symmetric entries to one).

Figure 4. A counterexample to rank monotonicity for eigenvector centrality. Before adding the edge $0-1$ , the score of vertex $1$ is larger than the score of vertex $3$ ; after, it is smaller.

We are now going to prove that eigenvector centrality does not satisfy rank monotonicity on a class of graphs of arbitrarily large size in which we will also experience demotion. Proving analytical results will require combining a few techniques from spectral graph theory and analysis, as we would otherwise not be able to perform exact computations, as in the previous cases.

7. Interlude: Graph fibrations

Proving analytical results about graphs of arbitrary size requires in principle manipulating matrices of arbitrary size, and obtaining closed-form expressions for eigenvalues and eigenvectors of such matrices would be difficult, if not impossible. We thus turn to ideas going back to the results obtained in the ’60s in the context of the theory of graph divisors (Sachs, Reference Sachs1966), restating them in the more recent language of graph fibrations (Boldi & Vigna, Reference Boldi and Vigna2002).

A (graph) morphism $\varphi \,:\,G\to H$ is given by a pair of functions $f_N\,:\,N_G\to N_H$ and $f_A\,:\,A_G\to A_H$ commuting with the source and target maps, that is, $s_H(f_A(a))=f_N(s_G(a))$ and $t_H(f_A(a))=f_N(t_G(a))$ for all $a \in A_G$ . In other words, a morphism maps nodes to nodes and arcs to arcs in such a way to preserve the incidence relation. The definition of morphism we give is the obvious extension to the case of multigraphs of the standard notion the reader may have met elsewhere.

Definition 4. A fibration (Boldi & Vigna, Reference Boldi and Vigna2002 ; Grothendieck, Reference Grothendieck1959 ) between the graphs $G$ and $B$ is a morphism $\varphi \,:\, G\to B$ such that for each arc $a\in A_B$ and each node $x\in N_G$ satisfying $\varphi _N(x)=t_B(a)$ there is a unique arc $\widetilde{a}^{x}\in A_G$ (called the lifting of $a$ at $x$ ) such that $\varphi _A(\widetilde{a}^{x})=a$ and $t_G(\widetilde{a}^{x})=x$ .

If $\varphi \,:\,G\to B$ is a fibration, $G$ is called the total graph and $B$ the base of $\varphi$ . We shall also say that $G$ is fibered (over $B$ ). The fiber over a node $x\in N_B$ is the set of nodes of $G$ that are mapped to $x$ .

A verbal restatement of the definition of fibration is that each arc of the base lifts uniquely to each node in the fiber of its target; moreover, we remark that Definition 4 is just an elementary restatement of Grothendieck’s notion of fibration between categories applied to the free categories generated by $G$ and $B$ .

In Figure 5, we show two graph morphisms; the morphisms are implicitly described by the colors on the nodes and in the only possible way on the arcs. The morphism displayed on the left is not a fibration, because the loop on the base has no counterimage ending at the lower gray node, and moreover, the other arc has two counterimages with the same target. The morphism displayed on the right, on the contrary, is a fibration. Observe that loops are not necessarily lifted to loops.

Figure 5. On the left, an example of graph morphism that is not a fibration; on the right, a fibration. Colors on the nodes are used to implicitly specify the morphisms (arcs are mapped in the only possible way).

Definition 5. If $\varphi \,:\,G\to B$ is a fibration, given a vector $\boldsymbol{{u}}$ of size $n_B$ , define its lifting along $\varphi$ as the vector $\boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi$ of size $n_G$ given by

\begin{equation*} \left (\boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi \right )_i=u_{\varphi (i)}. \end{equation*}

Otherwise said, $\boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi$ is the vector obtained by copying $\boldsymbol{{u}}$ along the fibers of $\varphi$ .

Theorem 4. (Sachs, 1966) If $\varphi \,:\,G\to B$ is a fibration surjective on the nodes, given a vector $\boldsymbol{{u}}$ of size $n_B$ we have

\begin{equation*} \boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi G = (\boldsymbol{{u}} B)^\varphi . \end{equation*}

In other words, one can lift and multiply by $G$ , or equivalently multiply by $B$ and then lift: the base $B$ “summarizes” the graph $G$ well enough that the multiplication of fiberwise constant vectors by $G$ can be carried on (usually smaller) $B$ . The proof of Theorem 4 is in fact immediate once one realizes that Definition 4 implies that $\varphi$ induces a local isomorphism between the in-neighborhood of a node $x$ of $G$ and the in-neighborhood of $\varphi _N(x)$ (Boldi & Vigna, Reference Boldi and Vigna2002).

Theorem 4 has the important consequence that every left eigenvector $\boldsymbol{{e}}$ of $B$ can be lifted to a left eigenvector $\boldsymbol{{e}}^\varphi$ of $G$ , so every eigenvalue of $B$ is an eigenvalue of $G$ , and thus, the characteristic polynomial of $B$ divides that of $G$ (hence the name graph divisor). In our case, by the Perron–Frobenius theorem (Berman & Plemmons, Reference Berman and Plemmons1994), if $B$ is strongly connected the dominant eigenvector of $B$ is strictly positive, so its lifting is strictly positive, and thus (applying again the Perron–Frobenius theorem), it is the dominant eigenvector of $G$ ; moreover, $G$ and $B$ share the same dominant eigenvalue (and thus spectral radius).

8. Back to eigenvector centrality

We now get back to eigenvector centrality: Figure 6 shows a family of total graphs $G_k$ depending on an integer parameter $k$ , and an associated family of bases $B_k$ , with fibrations defined on the nodes following the node labels, and on the arcs in the only possible way. We will show that when the edge $0-1$ is added to the graphs (obtaining new graphs $G^{\prime}_k$ and $B^{\prime}_k$ ), all vertices labeled with $4$ , which used to have a smaller score than vertex $1$ in $G_k$ , will become more important than vertex $1$ in $G^{\prime}_k$ .

Figure 6. The parametric counterexample graph for eigenvector centrality: when adding the edge $0-1$ , vertex $1$ violates rank monotonicity (top). The $k$ vertices labeled with $4$ form a $(k+1)$ -clique with vertex $0$ , and the $k$ vertices labeled with $6$ form a $(k+1)$ -clique with vertices $2$ ; finally, there is a star with $(k-1)(k-2)$ leaves around vertex $1$ . Arc labels represent multiplicity. The matrix displayed is the adjacency matrix of $B_k$ , with the grayed entries to be set to $1$ when $0-1$ is added to the graph. Table 2 shows a set of values for the size of the cliques and the size of the star causing vertex $1$ to be less important than vertex $0$ .

The intuitive idea behind the graphs $G_k$ is that the new edge makes the vertices labeled with $4$ much closer to vertex $1$ , a high-degree vertex; at the same time, the new edge doubles the number of paths from the vertices labeled with $6$ to the vertices labeled with $4$ . The advantage for vertex $1$ is to get much closer to the vertices labeled with $4$ , but those have a much smaller degree. All in all, the new edge will turn out to be much more advantageous for the vertices labeled with $4$ than for vertex $1$ .

The fundamental property of our counterexample is that albeit $G_k$ is a simple undirected graph with $k^2-k-6$ vertices, $B_k$ is a general directed multigraph with seven nodes, independently of $k$ , so its adjacency matrix, shown in Figure 6, is a fixed-sized matrix containing a parameter $k$ due to the variable number of arcs. Thus, fibrations make it possible to move our proof from matrices of arbitrary size to a parametric matrix of fixed size.

8.1 Sturm polynomials

There is no way to compute exactly the eigenvalues and eigenvectors of $B_k$ . However, we will be able to control their behavior using Sturm polynomials (Rahman & Schmeisser, Reference Rahman and Schmeisser2002), a standard, powerful technique to analyze and locate real roots of polynomials.

Definition 6. If $p(x)$ is a polynomial with real coefficients and $p^{\prime}(x)$ its derivative, the Sturm sequence of polynomials associated with $p(x)$ is defined by

\begin{align*} S_0(x) &= p(x)\\ S_1(x) &= p^{\prime}(x)\\ S_{i+1}(x) &= - S_{i}(x) \bmod S_{i-1}(x)\qquad for\ i\geq 1, \end{align*}

where $S_{i}(x) \bmod S_{i-1}(x)$ is the remainder of the Euclidean division of $S_i(x)$ by $S_{i-1}(x)$ . The sequence stops when $S_{i+1}(x)$ becomes zero, and it is long at most as the degree of $p(x)$ .

Given a real number $a$ , the number of sign variations $V(a)$ of a Sturm sequence is the number of sign changes, ignoring zeros, of the sequence $S_0(a)$ , $S_1(a)$ , $S_2(a)$ , $\dots \,$ . Finally, if $p(x)$ is squarefree (i.e., it is not divisible by the square of a nonconstant polynomial), the number of distinct roots of $p(x)$ in the interval $(a\ldotp \ldotp b]$ is $V(a)-V(b)$ ; all polynomials we will study will be squarefree.

8.2 Bounding the dominant eigenvalue

We now discuss how to bound the dominant eigenvalue $\rho _k$ of $B_k$ (and thus $G_k$ ); the same results hold for the dominant eigenvalue $\rho^{\prime}_k\gt \rho _k$ of $B^{\prime}_k$ (and thus $G^{\prime}_k$ ). The approach we describe will be used throughout the rest of the paper.

Consider the characteristic polynomial of $B_k$

\begin{equation*} p_k(\lambda ) = \det\! (1- \lambda B_k). \end{equation*}

We can compute its Sturm polynomials and evaluate them at the points $k+\frac 1{k^2}$ and $k+\frac 3{4k}$ . This evaluation leaves us with a pair of rational functions in $k$ for each Sturm polynomial in the sequence, and such functions have a defined sign for $k\to \infty$ that depends on the sign of the ratio of the leading coefficients of their numerator and denominator: in other words, for large enough $k$ we can count the number of zeroes of $p_k(\lambda )$ in the interval $\big(k+\frac 1{k^2}\ldotp \ldotp k+\frac 3{4k}\big]$ , and indeed $p_k(\lambda )$ has exactly one zero in that interval for $k\geq 24$ .

If we apply the same technique to the interval $\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\ldotp \ldotp 2k\right ]$ , we find no zeroes. Since $2k$ is an upper bound for the dominant eigenvalue of both matrices (as it is larger than the geometric mean of indegree and outdegree of all vertices (Kwapisz, Reference Kwapisz1996, Theorem 1.(ii)), we conclude that the spectral radius $\rho _k$ of $B_k$ lies in $\left (k+\frac 1{k^2}\ldotp \ldotp k+\frac 3{4k}\right ]$ .

8.3 Bounding the dominant eigenvector

Armed with this knowledge, we approach the study of the dominant eigenvectors of $B_k$ and $B^{\prime}_k$ . There is no way to compute them exactly: thus, we resort to the study of $\textbf 1(1 -\alpha B_k )^{-1}$ , because the dominant eigenvector $\boldsymbol{{e}}$ of $B_k$ and $\boldsymbol{{e}}^{\prime}$ of $B^{\prime}_k$ can be expressed as (Vigna, Reference Vigna2016)

(1) \begin{align} \boldsymbol{{e}} &= \lim _{\alpha \to 1/\rho _k}\bigl (1-\alpha \rho _k\bigr )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}. \end{align}
(2) \begin{align} \boldsymbol{{e}}^{\prime} &= \lim _{\alpha \to 1/\rho^{\prime}_k}\bigl (1-\alpha \rho^{\prime}_k\bigr )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B^{\prime}_k\bigr )^{-1}. \end{align}

In fact, $(1 -\alpha B_k )^{-1}$ is a slightly different way (up to a constant factor) to define the resolvent of $B_k$ (Dunford & Schwartz, Reference Dunford and Schwartz1988), but the formulation we use here will make it easier to apply the results we will develop in the sections on Katz’s index and PageRank.

While we have no way to compute exactly the eigenvectors of $B_k$ , we can compute symbolically $\textbf 1 (1 -\alpha B_k )^{-1}$ , thus obtaining for each node of $B_k$ a rational function in $\alpha$ whose coefficients are polynomials in $k$ , and do the same for $B^{\prime}_k$ .

We will be interested in comparing eigenvector centralities, that is, in proving statements (for nodes $x$ and $y$ of $B_k$ ) of the form

\begin{equation*} \frac {e_x}{e_y}=\lim _{\alpha \to 1/\rho _k}\frac {\left [\bigl (1-\alpha \rho _k\bigr )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_x}{\left [ \bigl (1-\alpha \rho _k\bigr )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_y}\gt 1. \end{equation*}

However,

\begin{equation*} \frac {e_x}{e_y}=\lim _{\alpha \to 1/\rho _k}\frac {\left [\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_x}{\left [ \textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_y} =\lim _{\alpha \to 1/\rho _k}\frac {\left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm {adj}({1-\alpha B_k})\right ]_x}{\left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm {adj}({1-\alpha B_k})\right ]_y} =\frac {\left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm {adj}({1- B_k/\rho _k})\right ]_x}{\left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm {adj}({1- B_k/\rho _k})\right ]_y}, \end{equation*}

where we used the fact that the inverse is the adjugate matrix (Gantmacher, Reference Gantmacher1980) divided by the determinant

\begin{equation*} \textrm {adj}({1-\alpha B_k})=\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\cdot \det\! (1 -\alpha B_k). \end{equation*}

The final substitution can be performed safely because the column-sums of the adjugate must be nonzero in a neighborhood of $\rho _k$ , or the limits (1) would not be finite and positive. The advantage is that the entries of $\textrm{adj}({1-\alpha B_k})$ are just polynomials. The same considerations hold for $B^{\prime}_k$ .

We thus define, for every node $x$ ,

\begin{align*} \textrm{pre}_\alpha (x)&= \left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm{adj}({1 -\alpha B_k})\right ]_x\\[4pt] \textrm{post}_\alpha (x)&= \left [\textbf 1\cdot \textrm{adj}({1 -\alpha B^{\prime}_k})\right ]_x. \end{align*}

For example,

\begin{align} \textrm{pre}_\alpha (0) &= ({-}2k^3 + 7k^2 - 7k + 2)\alpha ^6 + (2k^2 - 7k + 5)\alpha ^5 + (2k^3 - 6k^2 + 6k)\alpha ^4\\ &\qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad \qquad + (k^3 - 5k^2 + 9k - 7)\alpha ^3 + ({-}k^2 + k - 3)\alpha ^2 + ({-}k + 2)\alpha + 1. \end{align}

Note that in the adjacency matrix of $B_k$ just three rows contain $k$ : as a consequence, the degree in $k$ of the coefficients of the polynomials in $\alpha$ is at most three.

Since $k+\frac 3{4k}\gt \rho _k$ , we start by showing that

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(1)\gt \textrm {pre}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(4) \end{equation*}

and once again, since we are dealing with rational functions in $k$ , for enough large $k$ the difference

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(1)-\textrm {pre}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(4) \end{equation*}

has a constant sign: in particular, for $k\geq 53$ it is positive. The same analysis, however, shows that

\begin{equation*} \textrm {post}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(1) \lt \textrm {post}_{1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )}(4) \end{equation*}

when $k\geq 3$ .

We are now going to extend our inequalities to a range comprising $1/\rho _k$ . If we consider the Sturm polynomials (in $\alpha$ ) of

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}_\alpha (1)- \textrm {pre}_\alpha (4),\end{equation*}

we find no zero between $\alpha = 1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right ) \lt 1/ \rho _k$ and $\alpha = 1\big/\left (k+\frac 1{k^2}\right ) \gt 1/ \rho _k$ for $k\geq 53$ . Hence, for $1\big/\left (k+\frac 3{4k}\right )\lt \alpha \leq 1\big/\left (k+\frac 1{k^2}\right )$

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}_\alpha (1)\gt \textrm {pre}_\alpha (4), \end{equation*}

so, in particular,

\begin{equation*} \textrm {pre}_{1/\rho _k}(1)\gt \textrm {pre}_{1/\rho _k}(4), \end{equation*}

showing that the eigenvector centrality of node $1$ is larger than that of node $4$ for $k\geq 53$ . A similar analysis for $\textrm{post}$ shows that

\begin{equation*} \textrm {post}_{1/\rho^{\prime}_k}(1)\lt \textrm {post}_{1/\rho^{\prime}_k}(4) \end{equation*}

for $k\geq 1$ . Thus, in the graph $G_k$ the addition of the edge $0-1$ causes vertex $1$ to violate rank monotonicity. Further analysis of the same kind on the remaining nodes show that only the vertices labeled with $4$ change their importance relatively to vertex $1$ , which implies that vertex $1$ is demoted by $k$ positions. Finally, studying the polynomial $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (0)$ it is easy to see that in our example vertex $1$ is more important than vertex $0$ for $k\geq 54$ .

While all the previous discussions are valid for $k\geq 54$ , numerical computations show that the result indeed extends to all $k\geq 7$ . Hence:

Theorem 5. Eigenvector centrality is not rank monotone (top violation) on the graphs $G_k$ of Figure 6 for $k\geq 7$ .

By gaging accurately the size of the star around $1$ , it is possible to find also bottom violations of rank monotonicity. We have tabulated the first few values of $k$ for which there is a suitable star, and we show them in Table 2: we conjecture that there is a function of $k$ of order $\Theta (k^2)$ which gives a correct real value for $s$ , and examples emerge when such value is very close to an integer.

Table 2. Pairs of values providing bottom violations of rank monotonicity for eigenvector centrality: $k$ is the same as in Figure 6, and $s$ is the size of the star around $1$ (in Figure 6, $s=(k-1)(k-2)$ )

9. Seeley’s index

A natural variant of eigenvector centrality is Seeley’s index (Seeley, Reference Seeley1949), the steady state of the (uniform) random walk on the graph; for more details, see Boldi & Vigna (Reference Boldi and Vigna2014). The situation here is quite different: it is a well-known fact that if the graph is connected the only possible steady-state probability of vertex $x$ is simply $d(x)/2m$ , where $d(x)$ is the degree of $x$ —essentially, the centrality of a vertex is just its $\ell _1$ -normalized degree. We will use this definition on all graphs, albeit in the general case it does not give the only possible steady state. As a consequence:

Theorem 6. Seeley’s index (defined as $\ell _1$ -normalized degree) is strictly rank monotone on undirected graphs.

The situation is almost the same for score monotonicity:

Theorem 7. Seeley’s index (defined as $\ell _1$ -normalized degree) is score monotone on undirected graphs, except in the case of a graph formed by a star graph and one or more additional isolated vertices.

Proof. When we add an edge between $x$ and $y$ in a graph with $m$ edges, the score of $x$ changes from $d(x)/2m$ to $(d(x)+1)/(2m+2)$ . If we require

\begin{equation*} \frac {d(x)+1}{2m+2}\gt \frac {d(x)}{2m} \end{equation*}

we obtain $d(x)\lt m$ . Since obviously $d(x)\leq m$ , the condition is always true except when $d(x)=m$ , which corresponds to the case of a disconnected graph formed by a star graph and by additional isolated vertices. Indeed, in that case adding an edge between an isolated vertex and the center of the star will not change the score of the center.

Theorem 7 is a general characterization of score monotonicity of Seeley’s index, under the assumption that its values are given by $\ell _1$ -normalized degree. Since we aim at providing connected counterexamples only, in Table 1 we do not use the negative part of Theorem 7, marking Seeley’s index as score monotone. Furthermore, note that while in general Seeley’s index on unconnected graphs may have several definitions, $\ell _1$ -normalized degree yields the only possible steady state even in the case of a graph formed by a nontrivial connected component plus isolated vertices.

10. Interlude: Graph fibrations and damped spectral rankings

The key observation used to build the counterexample for eigenvector centrality was Theorem 4, stating that lifting of vectors commutes with matrix multiplication.

The theorem is true also for weighted graphs, as long as the fibration preserves weights and adjacency matrices are defined by adding the weights of all arcs between two nodes. An interesting consequence of this fact is the following:

Theorem 8. [Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Lonati, Santini and Vigna2006 ] Let $G$ and $B$ be weighted graphs, and $\varphi \,:\,G\to B$ be a surjective weight-preserving fibration; then, given a (row) vector $\boldsymbol{{v}}$ of size $n_B$ we have

\begin{equation*} \boldsymbol{{v}}^\varphi (1-\alpha G)^{-1} = \bigl (\boldsymbol{{v}} (1-\alpha B)^{-1}\bigr )^\varphi . \end{equation*}

The proof is simple:

\begin{align*} \boldsymbol{{v}}^\varphi (1-\alpha G)^{-1} & = \boldsymbol{{v}}^\varphi \sum _{i=0}^\infty (\alpha G)^i = \sum _{i=0}^\infty \boldsymbol{{v}}^\varphi (\alpha G)^i \\& = \sum _{i=0}^\infty \bigl (\boldsymbol{{v}} (\alpha B)^i\bigr )^\varphi = \left(\boldsymbol{{v}}\sum _{i=0}^\infty (\alpha B)^i\right)^\varphi = \bigl (\boldsymbol{{v}} (1-\alpha B)^{-1}\bigr )^\varphi . \end{align*}

Theorem 8 makes it possible to apply the techniques we used for eigenvector centrality to general damped spectral rankings, as defined in Vigna (Reference Vigna2016), of which both Katz’s index and PageRank are special instances. Both centralities can be defined, up to a constant multiplying factor, as

\begin{equation*} \boldsymbol{{v}} (1-\alpha M)^{-1} \end{equation*}

for suitable preference vector $\boldsymbol{{v}}$ and for a matrix $M$ derived from the adjacency matrix of the graph.

11. Katz’s index

Recall that Katz’s index (Katz, Reference Katz1953) is defined as

\begin{equation*} \textbf 1\sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^i G^i = \textbf 1(1-\alpha G)^{-1}, \end{equation*}

where $0\leq \alpha \lt 1/\rho (G)$ (here, $\rho (G)$ is the spectral radius of $G$ ). It is trivially score monotone, but we will prove that it is not rank monotone.

First of all, we note that if $\alpha$ is small enough Katz’s index will be strictly rank monotone:

Theorem 9. Let $G$ be a graph and $\rho$ its spectral radius. Then, there is an $\bar \alpha \lt 1/\rho$ such that for $\alpha \leq \bar \alpha$ Katz’s index is strictly rank monotone on $G$ .

Proof. We remark that

\begin{equation*} \textbf 1\sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^i G^i = \textbf 1 + \alpha \textbf 1G + \alpha ^2 \textbf 1 G^2\sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^i G^i. \end{equation*}

The relative node importance in $\textbf 1 + \alpha \textbf 1G$ is exactly that defined by degree, and score differences are $O(\alpha )$ for $\alpha \to 0$ . However,

\begin{equation*} \Biggl \|\alpha ^2\textbf 1 G^2 \sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^iG^i\Biggr \|_\infty \leq \alpha ^2\bigl \|G^2\bigr \|_\infty \Biggl \|\sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^i G^i\Biggr \|_\infty, \end{equation*}

and given any $0\lt \alpha^{\prime}\lt 1/\rho _k$ for $\alpha \leq \alpha^{\prime}$ the last expression is $O (\alpha ^2 )$ for $\alpha \to 0$ . Thus, there is an $\alpha _G$ such that, for $\alpha \leq \alpha _G$ , the relative importance of a node of $G$ is that defined by its degree. If we minimize over all such $\alpha$ ’s for all graphs obtained by adding an edge to $G$ , we obtain the value $\bar \alpha$ of the statement.

On the other hand, we are now going to provide an example on which rank monotonicity is not satisfied when we go sufficiently close to $1/\rho$ . We can use the same counterexample as for eigenvector centrality (Figure 6): in view of Theorem 8, the analysis performed in Section 8 already shows that Katz’s index is not rank monotone on $G_k$ for sufficiently large $k$ and for all

\begin{equation*} \alpha \in \biggl [\frac 1{k+\frac 3{4k}}\ldotp \ldotp \frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}\biggr ). \end{equation*}

In other words,

Theorem 10. Let $\rho^{\prime}_k$ be the spectral radius of the graph $G^{\prime}_k$ in Figure 6. For $k\geq 54$ , there exists some $\nu _k\lt \frac 1{k+\frac 3{4k}}$ such that Katz’s index is not rank monotone (top violation) on $G_k$ for all $\alpha \in \left (\nu _k\ldotp \ldotp \frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}\right )$ .

Note that the theorem above claims that the violation happens in a left neighborhood of the upper bound of $\alpha$ ; moreover, on the left we can get as close as desired to $0$ given a suitable $k$ . This is the best possible scenario, in view of Theorem 9. Also our considerations about demotion in Section 8 transfer immediately to the present setting.

Further analysis by Sturm polynomials in the interval $\left (\frac 1{k+\frac 1k}\ldotp \ldotp \frac 1{k+\frac 3{4k}}\right ]$ shows the following:

  • the relative importance of node $1$ and node $4$ in $\textrm{pre}_\alpha ({-})$ flips (node $4$ is more important than node $1$ at the beginning of the interval and then becomes less important, after some value of $\alpha$ , say $\alpha^{\prime}$ );

  • the relative importance of node $0$ and node $1$ in $\textrm{pre}_\alpha ({-})$ flips (node $0$ is more important than node $1$ at the beginning of the interval and then becomes less important, after some value of $\alpha$ , say $\alpha^{\prime\prime}$ );

  • $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (4)$ always dominates $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (0)$ .

The latter observation implies $\alpha^{\prime}\lt \alpha^{\prime\prime}=\nu _k$ , in the notation of Theorem 10; since the relative importance of node $1$ and node $4$ remains the same in $\textrm{post}_\alpha ({-})$ (node $4$ is always more important than node $1$ in the interval after the addition of the edge), in the interval $ (\alpha^{\prime}\ldotp \ldotp \nu _k )$ , we can observe a bottom violation of rank monotonicity.

Moreover, the interval $(\alpha^{\prime}\ldotp \ldotp \nu _k)$ gets closer to the upper bound $\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}\gt \nu _k$ as $k$ gets larger:

\begin{equation*} \frac {\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k} - \alpha^{\prime}}{\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}}\leq \frac {\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k} - \frac 1{k+\frac 1k}}{\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}} = 1-\frac {\rho^{\prime}_k}{k+\frac 1k}\leq 1-\frac {k+\frac 1{k^2}}{k+\frac 1k}\to 0 \quad \text {for $k\to \infty $}. \end{equation*}

Theorem 11. For every $k$ , there is an interval of values of $\alpha$ contained in $\left (\frac 1{k+\frac 1k}\ldotp \ldotp \frac 1{k+\frac 3{4k}}\right ]$ in which Katz’s index is not rank monotone (bottom violation). The interval gets arbitrarily close to $\frac 1{\rho^{\prime}_k}$ as $k\to \infty$ .

As a final consideration, there is another range of validity of Theorem 10: if we further analyze with Sturm polynomials the relative importance of node $1$ and node $4$ in the interval $\left (\frac 1{k+\frac 2k}\ldotp \ldotp \frac 1{k+\frac 3{4k}}\right ]$ , we find two sign changes in $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)- \textrm{pre}_\alpha (4)$ , two sign changes in $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)- \textrm{pre}_\alpha (0)$ , and zero sign changes in $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)- \textrm{post}_\alpha (4)$ : thus, there is an interval comprising $\frac 1{k+\frac 2k}$ in which the violation of rank monotonicity happens again. Also in this interval, $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (4)$ always dominates $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (0)$ ; hence, we have both top violations and bottom violations; it is also immediate to show demotion. Figure 7 summarizes graphically the results proved in this section.

Figure 7. A graphical summarization of the results about Katz’s index proved in Section 11. Dashed lines (dotted lines, resp.) represent intervals of values of $\alpha$ , in which we proved top (bottom, resp.) violations of rank monotonicity (Theorems 10 and 11). The thick interval represents a region where rank monotonicity is guaranteed (Theorem 9).

12. PageRank

PageRank (Page et al., Reference Page, Brin, Motwani and Winograd1998) can be defined as

\begin{equation*} (1-\alpha )\boldsymbol{{v}}\sum _{i=0}^\infty \alpha ^i\bar G^i = (1-\alpha ) \boldsymbol{{v}}(1-\alpha \bar G)^{-1}, \end{equation*}

where $\alpha \in [0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ is the damping factor, $\boldsymbol{{v}}$ is a non-negative preference vector with unit $\ell _1$ -norm, and $\bar G$ is the row-normalized versionFootnote 5 of $G$ ; that is, $\bar G$ is just the (adjacency matrix of the) weighted version of $G$ defined by letting $w(a)=1/\sum _{x\in N_G}G_{s_G(a)\, x}$ . Hence, if you have a weighted graph $B$ , a weight-preserving fibration $\varphi \,:\, \bar G \to B$ that is surjective on the nodes, and a vector $\boldsymbol{{u}}$ of size $n_B$ such that $\boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi$ has unit $\ell _1$ -norm, you can deduce from Theorem 8 that

(3) \begin{equation} (1-\alpha ) \boldsymbol{{u}}^\varphi (1-\alpha \bar G)^{-1}=\left ( (1-\alpha ) \boldsymbol{{u}} (1-\alpha B)^{-1}\right )^\varphi . \end{equation}

On the left-hand side you have the actual PageRank of $G$ for a preference vector that is fiberwise constant; on the right-hand side you have a damped spectral ranking of $B$ . Note that $B$ is not necessarily row-stochastic, and $\boldsymbol{{u}}$ has not unit $\ell _1$ -norm, so technically the right-hand side of the equation in Theorem 8 is not PageRank anymore.

We first observe that

Theorem 12. Given an undirected connected graph $G$ , there is a value of $\alpha$ for which PageRank is score monotone and strictly rank monotone on $G$ .

Proof. We know that for $\alpha \to 1$ , PageRank tends to Seeley’s index (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Santini and Vigna2005), which under our connectedness hypothesis is just $\ell _1$ -normalized degree. Since Seeley’s index is strictly rank monotone (Theorem 6), for each non-adjacent pair of vertices $x$ and $y$ there is a value $\alpha _{xy}$ such that for $\alpha \geq \alpha _{xy}$ adding the edge $x-y$ is strictly rank monotone. The proof is completed by taking $\alpha$ larger than all $\alpha _{xy}$ ’s. The result for score monotonicity is similar, using Theorem 7.

It is interesting to remark that this result is dual to Theorem 9: Katz’s index is approximated by degree for values of the damping factor close to the lower bound (zero), whereas PageRank is approximated by degree for values of the damping factor close to the upper bound (one). Note that the part about score monotonicity of Theorem 12 has a flavor similar to statement (2) of Theorem 4.1 in Avrachenkov & Litvak (Reference Avrachenkov and Litvak2006).

On the other hand, we will now show that for every possible value of the damping factor $\alpha$ there is a graph on which PageRank is neither rank nor score monotone. Our proof strategy will be identical to the one we used for Katz’s index, except that now we expect our example to satisfy rank monotonicity when $\alpha$ is close to its upper bound, instead of its lower bound, because of Theorem 12.

In Figure 8, we show a family of total graphs $G_k$ depending on an integer parameter $k$ , and an associated family of bases $B_k$ , with fibrations defined on the nodes following the node labels, and on the arcs in the only possible way.Footnote 6 Weights are defined by normalizing the adjacency matrix of $G_k$ and then using the fibration to transfer the weights on the arcs $B_k$ (it is easy to see that no conflict arises when multiple arcs of $G_k$ are mapped to the same arc of $B_k$ ). As usual, $G^{\prime}_k$ and $B^{\prime}_k$ are the same graphs with the additional edge $0-1$ .

Figure 8. A parametric counterexample graph for PageRank: when adding the edge $0-1$ , vertex $1$ violates score and rank monotonicity (bottom violation). The $k$ vertices labeled with $4$ form a $(k+1)$ -clique with vertex $3$ , and the $k-1$ vertices labeled with $8$ form a $(k+1)$ -clique with vertices $0$ and $7$ . Arc labels represent multiplicity; weights are induced by the uniform distribution on the upper graph. The matrices displayed are the adjacency matrix of $B_k$ and $B^{\prime}_k$ ; differently from Figure 6, we show them both explicitly to highlight how the addition of the new edge influences row normalization.

The basic intuition behind the graphs $G_k$ is that when you connect a high-degree vertex $x$ with a low-degree vertex $y$ , $y$ will pass to $x$ a much larger fraction of its score than in the opposite direction. This phenomenon is caused by the stochastic normalization of the adjacency matrix: the arc from $x$ to $y$ will have a low coefficient, due to the high degree of $x$ , whereas the arc from $y$ to $x$ will have a high coefficient, due to the low degree of $y$ .

While $G_k$ has $2k+6$ vertices, $B_k$ has $9$ vertices, independently of $k$ , and thus, its PageRank can be computed analytically as rational functions of $\alpha$ whose coefficients are rational functions in $k$ (since the number of arcs of each $B_k$ is different).

We thus define, for every node $x$ ,

\begin{align*} \textrm{pre}_\alpha (x)&= \left [(1-\alpha )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_x\\[4pt] \textrm{post}_\alpha (x)&= \left [(1-\alpha )\textbf 1\bigl (1 -\alpha B^{\prime}_k\bigr )^{-1}\right ]_x. \end{align*}

Note when discussing score monotonicity, we cannot use the adjugate matrix to simplify our computations, as we did in Section 8, but we can use without loss of generality an arbitrary constant vector as preference vector. When discussing rank monotonicity, however, we will switch silently to the adjugate (because the denominator cannot change its sign anywhere in $[0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ ).

For example,

\begin{equation*} \textrm {post}_\alpha (1)= \frac {\frac {2 k^{2} - 6 k + 4}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4} \alpha ^{5} + \frac {-14 k^{2} + 12 k + 4}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4} \alpha ^{4} +\cdots + \frac {6 k^{4} + 6 k^{3} - 24 k^{2} - 24 k}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4} \alpha + \frac {-4 k^{4} - 12 k^{3} - 8 k^{2}}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4}} {\alpha ^{5} + \frac {-2 k^{3} - 10 k^{2} + 12 k + 4}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4} \alpha ^{4} + \cdots + \frac {4 k^{4} + 4 k^{3} - 20 k^{2} - 24 k}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4} \alpha + \frac {-4 k^{4} - 12 k^{3} - 8 k^{2}}{k^{2} - 6 k + 4}}, \end{equation*}

where we omitted part of the terms for lack of space. Once again, in the adjacency matrix of $B_k$ just four rows contain $k$ : as a consequence, the degree in $k$ of numerators and denominators of coefficients of the rational functions in $\alpha$ is at most four.

12.1 Score monotonicity

We start by considering node $1$ : evaluating $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)$ in $\alpha =2/3$ , we obtain a negative value for $k\geq 11$ , showing there is a value of $\alpha$ for which node $1$ violates score monotonicity. Then, we use again Sturm polynomials to show that for $k\geq 13$ the numerator of $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)$ never changes its sign in $ (a_k\ldotp \ldotp b_k ]$ , where

\begin{equation*} a_k = \frac 23 - \frac {2k}{3k+ 100} \lt \frac 23 \lt \frac 23+\frac {k}{3k+100} = b_k, \end{equation*}

while the denominator of $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)$ cannot have zeros in $[0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ . The interval $ (a_k\ldotp \ldotp b_k ]$ approaches $(0\ldotp \ldotp 1]$ as $k$ grows, so we conclude that the interval of values of $\alpha$ for which the score of node $1$ decreases reaches the whole unit interval as $k$ grows.

Finally, by studying (as in the case of Katz’s index) the polynomial $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (0)$ it is easy to see that in our example node $0$ is always more important than node $1$ as long as $k\geq 1$ .

Theorem 13. For every value of $\alpha \in (0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ , for sufficiently large $k$ PageRank with damping factor $\alpha$ is not score monotone (bottom violation) on the graphs $G_k$ of Figure 8.

It is also interesting to count the sign changes of $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)$ in $ (0\ldotp \ldotp a_k ]$ (one) and $ (b_k\ldotp \ldotp 1 )$ (one), as they describe the behavior of the score change for limiting values: initially, the score increases; then, it starts to decrease somewhere before $a_k$ and stops decreasing somewhere after $b_k$ , as expected from Theorem 12.

12.2 Rank monotonicity

We now use the same example to prove the lack of rank monotonicity. In this case, we study in a similar way $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (5)$ , which is positive in $\alpha =2/3$ if $k\geq 13$ . To extend our results about rank monotonicity to every $\alpha$ , we use again Sturm polynomials to show that the numerator of $\textrm{pre}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{pre}_\alpha (5)$ never changes its sign in $ (a_k\ldotp \ldotp b_k ]$ for $k\geq 14$ .

Again, it is interesting to count the sign changes of $p(\alpha )$ in $(0\ldotp \ldotp a_k]$ (one) and $(b_k\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ (one): initially, node $1$ has a smaller PageRank than node $5$ ; then, somewhere before $a_k$ , node $1$ starts having a larger PageRank than $5$ ; somewhere after $b_k$ , we return to the initial condition, as expected from Theorem 12.

Finally, we study $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{post}_\alpha (5)$ which is negative in $\alpha =2/3$ and again has no sign changes in $ (a_k\ldotp \ldotp b_k ]$ for $k\geq 5$ . More precisely, we study $p(\alpha )$ , where $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{post}_\alpha (5) = (1-\alpha )^2p(\alpha )$ , as $\textrm{post}_\alpha (1)-\textrm{post}_\alpha (5)$ is not squarefree, but $p(\alpha )$ is.

In this case, there are two sign changes in $(0\ldotp \ldotp a_k]$ and no sign change in $(b_k\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ , so initially, node $1$ is less important than node $5$ ; then, in an interval of values before $a_k$ it is more important; then, it starts to be again less important before $a_k$ ; and it becomes as important as node $5$ only in the limit for $\alpha \to 1$ .

Theorem 14. For every value of $\alpha \in (0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ , for sufficiently large $k$ PageRank with damping factor $\alpha$ is not rank monotone (bottom violation) on the graphs $G_k$ of Figure 8.

Recall that in Boldi et al. (Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017), PageRank was proven to be both score and (strictly) rank monotone for all directed graphs and all $\alpha \in [0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ , given that the preference vector is positive: comparing those results with Theorems 13 and 14, we see once more that in the undirected case the behavior is radically different.

For sufficiently large $k$ , almost all nodes are more important (i.e., have larger PageRank score) than node $1$ both before and after edge addition, with the only exception of nodes $5$ and $6$ : as we said, node $5$ is less important than node $1$ before but more important after the edge addition, whereas node $6$ is also less important than node $1$ before and becomes as important as node $1$ after the edge addition (as node $6$ and node $1$ become equivalent modulo an automorphism). As a result, node $1$ is demoted.

Figure 9. A parametric counterexample graph for PageRank: when adding the edge $0-1$ , vertex $0$ violates score and rank monotonicity (top violation). There is a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $0$ , a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $4$ , and the $k$ vertices labeled with $6$ form a $(k+2)$ -clique with vertices $1$ and $2$ . Arc labels represent multiplicity; weights are induced by the uniform distribution on the upper graph.

Finally, we provide in Figure 9 a counterexample in which the more important node violates rank monotonicity. In this case, the intuition is that we connect two nodes with the same degree but different scores. As in the previous case, the counterexample works for any chosen $\alpha$ , up to an appropriate choice of the parameter $k$ . The proof follows the same line of attack, and detailed computations can be found in the Sage worksheets. The main difference is that the relevant interval $ (a_k\ldotp \ldotp b_k ]$ is now

\begin{equation*} a_k = \frac 23-\frac {2\sqrt k}{3\sqrt k+10}\lt \alpha \leq \frac 23 + \frac k{3k+1} = b_k. \end{equation*}

Theorem 15. For every value of $\alpha \in (0\ldotp \ldotp 1)$ , for sufficiently large $k$ PageRank with damping factor $\alpha$ is neither score nor rank monotone (top violation) on the graphs $G_k$ of Figure 9.

12.3 Anecdotal evidence: PageRank on the IMDB

To show that our results are not only theoretical, we provide a few interesting anecdotal examples from the PageRank scores ( $\alpha =0.85$ ) of the Hollywood co-starship graph, whose vertices are actors/actresses in the Internet Movie Database, with an edge connecting them if played in the same movie. In particular, we used the hollywood-2011 dataset from the Laboratory for Web Algorithmics,Footnote 7 which contains approximately two million vertices and $230$ million edges.

To generate our examples, we picked two actors either at random, or considering the top 1/10,000 of the actors of the graph in PageRank order and the bottom quartile, looking for a collaboration that would hurt either actor (or both).Footnote 8 About $4$ % of our samples yielded a violation of monotonicity, and in Table 3 we report a few funny examples.

Table 3. A few examples of violations of score monotonicity and rank monotonicity in the Hollywood co-starship graph hollywood-2011. If we add an edge between the actors in the first and second column, the first actor has a score increase, the second actor has a score decrease, and the actors in the third column, which were less important than the second actor, become more important after the edge addition. The first three examples are bottom violations, whereas the last one is a top violation

The first three cases are bottom violations: it is the less-known actor that loses score (and rank) by the collaboration with the star, and not the other way round, as it happens also in the counterexample of Figure 8. In the last case, instead, we have a top violation: a collaboration would damage the more important vertex, like in the counterexample of Figure 9. We found no case in which both actors would be hurt by the collaboration, and it is in fact an open problem whether this situation can happen.

13. Conclusions

We have studied score and rank monotonicity on undirected graphs for some popular notions of centrality. Our results show that except for Seeley’s index (on connected graphs), there are always cases in which rank monotonicity does not hold, and in the case of Katz’s index and PageRank, we can find range of values of the parameters where the violation occurs; moreover, some centralities are also not score monotone. We provide examples of both top and bottom violations to highlight that even the knowledge of whether one is the more important or less important node is insufficient to decide whether the new edge will be beneficial. A possible direction for future research is to show that top and bottom violations cannot happen at the same time; that is, that the new edge is beneficial for at least one endpoint.

This lack of monotonicity is opposite to that we observed in the directed case, and it can also be seen in real-world graphs (at least for PageRank). It is interesting to note that even centrality indices that were designed for undirected graphs (e.g., closeness) are not rank monotone in the undirected case (even under a connectedness assumption). Our results show that common knowledge and intuitions about the behavior of centrality measures in the directed case cannot be applied to the undirected case.

Competing interests

None.

Footnotes

Action Editor: Ulrik Brandes

The authors have been supported by the FASTEN EU Project, H2020-ICT-2018-2020 (GA 825328).

A preliminary version of this paper appeared as Boldi, P., Furia, F., Vigna, S. (2022) as Spectral Rank Monotonicity on Undirected Networks in International Conference Complex Networks & Their Applications (pp. 234–246). Cham: Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-93409-5_20

2 Note that our negative results are a fortiori true if we consider undirected graphs with loops. Our positive results are still valid in the same case using the standard convention that each loop increases the degree by two.

3 We remark that in Boldi et al. (Reference Boldi, Furia, Vigna, Benito, Cherifi, Cherifi, Moro, Rocha and Sales-Pardo2022), rank monotonicity was defined incorrectly, using an apparently (but not effectively) equivalent condition to stated in Boldi et al. (Reference Boldi, Luongo and Vigna2017) and Chien et al. (Reference Chien, Dwork, Kumar, Simon and Sivakumar2004).

4 Note that in this paper, all vectors will be row vectors.

5 Here we are assuming that $G$ has no dangling nodes (i.e., nodes with outdegree $0$ ). If dangling nodes are present, you can still use this definition (null rows are left untouched in $\bar G$ ), but then to obtain PageRank you need to normalize the resulting vector (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Santini and Vigna2009; Del Corso et al. Reference Del Corso, Gullì and Romani2006). So all our discussion can also be applied to graphs with dangling nodes, up to $\ell _1$ -normalization.

6 Note that in the conference version of this paper (Boldi et al., Reference Boldi, Furia, Vigna, Benito, Cherifi, Cherifi, Moro, Rocha and Sales-Pardo2022), nodes are numbered differently, and the denominators of the second row of the adjacency matrix displayed therein are $k-1$ , mistakenly, instead of $k+1$ .

8 Note that for this to happen, the collaboration should be a two-person production. A production with more people would add more edges.

References

Anthonisse, J. M. (1971). The rush in a directed graph. Technical Report BN 9/71, Mathematical Centre, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Avrachenkov, K., & Litvak, N. (2006). The effect of new links on Google PageRank. Stochastic Models, 22(2), 319331.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bavelas, A. (1948). A mathematical model for group structures. Human Organization, 7(3), 1630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beauchamp, M. A. (1965). An improved index of centrality. Behavioral Science, 10(2), 161163.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Berge, C. (1958). Théorie des graphes et ses applications. Paris, France: Dunod.Google Scholar
Berman, A., & Plemmons, R. J. (1994). Nonnegative matrices in the mathematical sciences, Classics in Applied Mathematics. Philadelphia, PA: SIAM.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldi, P., Furia, F., & Vigna, S. (2022). Spectral rank monotonicity on undirected networks. In: Benito, R. M., Cherifi, C., Cherifi, H., Moro, E., Rocha, L. M., & Sales-Pardo, M., ed. Complex networks & their applications X, Studies in Computational Intelligence , vol. 1014 (pp. 234246). Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldi, P., Lonati, V., Santini, M., & Vigna, S. (2006). Graph fibrations, graph isomorphism, and PageRank. RAIRO Informatique Théorique, 40(2), 227253.Google Scholar
Boldi, P., Luongo, A., & Vigna, S. (2017). Rank monotonicity in centrality measures. Network Science, 5(4), 529550.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldi, P., Santini, M., & Vigna, S. (2005). Rank as a function of the damping factor. In Proceedings of the fourteenth international world wide web conference (WWW 2005) , Chiba, Japan. ACM Press (pp. 557566).Google Scholar
Boldi, P., Santini, M., & Vigna, S. (2009). PageRank: Functional dependencies. ACM Transactions on Information Systems, 27(4), 123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldi, P., & Vigna, S. (2002). Fibrations of graphs. Discrete Mathematics, 243(1-3), 2166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldi, P., & Vigna, S. (2014). Axioms for centrality. Internet Mathematics, 10(3-4), 222262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chien, S., Dwork, C., Kumar, R., Simon, D. R., & Sivakumar, D. (2004). Link evolution: Analysis and algorithms. Internet Mathematics, 1(3), 277304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Del Corso, G., Gullì, A., & Romani, F. (2006). Fast PageRank computation via a sparse linear system. Internet Mathematics, 2(3), 251273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dunford, N. J., & Schwartz, J. T. (1988). Linear operators, part 1: General theory. Wiley Classics Library. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.Google Scholar
Freeman, L. C. (1977). A set of measures of centrality based on betweenness. Sociometry, 40(1), 3541.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gantmacher, F. R. (1980). The theory of matrices. New York, NY: Chelsea Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Grothendieck, A. (1959-1960). Technique de descente et théorémes d’existence en géométrie algébrique, I. Généralités. Descente par morphismes fidélement plats. In Seminaire Bourbaki , vol. 190.Google Scholar
Katz, L. (1953). A new status index derived from sociometric analysis. Psychometrika, 18(1), 3943.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kwapisz, J. (1996). On the spectral radius of a directed graph. Journal of Graph Theory, 23(4), 405411.3.0.CO;2-V>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landau, E. (1895). Zur relativen Wertbemessung der Turnierresultate. Deutsches Wochenschach, 11, 366369.Google Scholar
Page, L., Brin, S., Motwani, R., & Winograd, T. (1998). The PageRank citation ranking: Bringing order to the web, Stanford Digital Library Technologies Project, Stanford University, Technical Report SIDL-WP-1999-0120.Google Scholar
Rahman, Q. I., & Schmeisser, G. (2002). Analytic theory of polynomials, London Mathematical Society New Series, vol. 26. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sabidussi, G. (1966). The centrality index of a graph. Psychometrika, 31(4), 581603.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, H. (1966). Über teiler, faktoren und charakteristische polynome von graphen. teil I. Wiss. Z. TH Ilmenau, 12, 712.Google Scholar
Seeley, J. R. (1949). The net of reciprocal influence: A problem in treating sociometric data. Canadian Journal of Psychology, 3(4), 234240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, G., & Sun, J. (1990). Matrix Perturbation Theory, Computer Science and Scientific Computing. Elsevier Science.Google Scholar
The Sage Developers (2018). SageMath, the Sage Mathematics Software System (Version 8.0).Google Scholar
Vigna, S. (2016). Spectral ranking. Network Science, 4(4), 433445.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Summary of the results of this paper for the case of connected undirected graphs. For comparison, recall that (Boldi et al., 2017) all the centrality measures listed are both score and rank monotone on strongly connected directed graphs, with the only exception of betweenness that is neither. We include degree (which is trivially score monotone and strictly rank monotone on all graphs) for completeness

Figure 1

Figure 1. A counterexample to rank monotonicity for closeness and harmonic centrality. There is a star with $j$ leaves around vertex $0$, a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $3$, a star with $r$ leaves around vertex $1$, and a star with $r$ leaves around vertex $2$. Before adding the edge $0-1$, the score of vertex $0$ is larger than the score of the vertices labeled with $4$; after, it is smaller.

Figure 2

Figure 2. A counterexample to score and rank monotonicity for betweenness. There is a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $0$, a star with $h$ leaves around vertex $1$, and $j$ vertices labeled with $4$ with the same neighborhood. Before adding the edge $0-1$, the score of vertex $0$ is larger than the score of vertex $2$; after the addition, it becomes smaller. Moreover, the score of vertex 0 does not change when the edge is added.

Figure 3

Figure 3. A counterexample to score monotonicity for eigenvector centrality. After adding the edge $0-1$, the score of vertex $0$ decreases: in norm $\ell _1$, from $0.30656$ to $0.29914$; in norm $\ell _2$, from $0.65328$ to $0.63586$, and when projecting the constant vector $\textbf 1$ onto the dominant eigenspace, from $1.39213$ to $1.35159$.

Figure 4

Figure 4. A counterexample to rank monotonicity for eigenvector centrality. Before adding the edge $0-1$, the score of vertex $1$ is larger than the score of vertex $3$; after, it is smaller.

Figure 5

Figure 5. On the left, an example of graph morphism that is not a fibration; on the right, a fibration. Colors on the nodes are used to implicitly specify the morphisms (arcs are mapped in the only possible way).

Figure 6

Figure 6. The parametric counterexample graph for eigenvector centrality: when adding the edge $0-1$, vertex $1$ violates rank monotonicity (top). The $k$ vertices labeled with $4$ form a $(k+1)$-clique with vertex $0$, and the $k$ vertices labeled with $6$ form a $(k+1)$-clique with vertices $2$; finally, there is a star with $(k-1)(k-2)$ leaves around vertex $1$. Arc labels represent multiplicity. The matrix displayed is the adjacency matrix of $B_k$, with the grayed entries to be set to $1$ when $0-1$ is added to the graph. Table 2 shows a set of values for the size of the cliques and the size of the star causing vertex $1$ to be less important than vertex $0$.

Figure 7

Table 2. Pairs of values providing bottom violations of rank monotonicity for eigenvector centrality: $k$ is the same as in Figure 6, and $s$ is the size of the star around $1$ (in Figure 6, $s=(k-1)(k-2)$)

Figure 8

Figure 7. A graphical summarization of the results about Katz’s index proved in Section 11. Dashed lines (dotted lines, resp.) represent intervals of values of $\alpha$, in which we proved top (bottom, resp.) violations of rank monotonicity (Theorems 10 and 11). The thick interval represents a region where rank monotonicity is guaranteed (Theorem 9).

Figure 9

Figure 8. A parametric counterexample graph for PageRank: when adding the edge $0-1$, vertex $1$ violates score and rank monotonicity (bottom violation). The $k$ vertices labeled with $4$ form a $(k+1)$-clique with vertex $3$, and the $k-1$ vertices labeled with $8$ form a $(k+1)$-clique with vertices $0$ and $7$. Arc labels represent multiplicity; weights are induced by the uniform distribution on the upper graph. The matrices displayed are the adjacency matrix of $B_k$ and $B^{\prime}_k$; differently from Figure 6, we show them both explicitly to highlight how the addition of the new edge influences row normalization.

Figure 10

Figure 9. A parametric counterexample graph for PageRank: when adding the edge $0-1$, vertex $0$ violates score and rank monotonicity (top violation). There is a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $0$, a star with $k$ leaves around vertex $4$, and the $k$ vertices labeled with $6$ form a $(k+2)$-clique with vertices $1$ and $2$. Arc labels represent multiplicity; weights are induced by the uniform distribution on the upper graph.

Figure 11

Table 3. A few examples of violations of score monotonicity and rank monotonicity in the Hollywood co-starship graph hollywood-2011. If we add an edge between the actors in the first and second column, the first actor has a score increase, the second actor has a score decrease, and the actors in the third column, which were less important than the second actor, become more important after the edge addition. The first three examples are bottom violations, whereas the last one is a top violation