Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-dfsvx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T12:48:39.337Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Willingness to Accept Incentives for a Shift to Climate-Smart Agriculture among Smallholder Farmers in Nigeria

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 October 2021

Adebayo M. Shittu
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics and Farm Management, Federal University of Agriculture, Abeokuta, P.M.B. 2240, Abeokuta, Ogun State, Nigeria
Mojisola O. Kehinde*
Affiliation:
Department of Agriculture, Landmark University, Omu Aran, Kwara State, Nigeria
Abigail G. Adeyonu
Affiliation:
Department of Agriculture, Landmark University, Omu Aran, Kwara State, Nigeria
Olutunji T. Ojo
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Federal University of Agriculture, Abeokuta, P.M.B. 2240, Abeokuta, Ogun State, Nigeria
*
*Corresponding author. Email: mojisolaolanike@gmail.com

Abstract

We used choice experiment data collected from 542 farmers in Nigeria to assess smallholders’ preferences for shifting to Climate-Smart Agriculture (CSA). Results suggest that the higher the size of the incentive, the more the likelihood of farmers’ willingness to invest in CSA schemes. Similarly, the farmers were in favor of community development associations and non-governmental organizations-managed schemes over other project managements and also prefer government-based institutions as opposed to the private sector. Willingness to accept results suggest that an average farmer is willing to accept $540/ha/year and $386/ha/year to embrace good agricultural practices (GAPs) with and without manure application.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Southern Agricultural Economics Association

1. Introduction

Climate change already has a negative impact on livestock, fisheries, and crop production and, if adequate mitigation and adaptation measures are not implemented, it will continue to have a negative impact in the future (Mccarl et al., Reference Mccarl, Thayer and Jones2016; Zougmore et al., Reference Zougmoré, Partey, Ouédraogo, Omitoyin, Thomas, Ayantunde, Ericksen, Said and Jalloh2016). Climate change is expected to adversely affect agricultural production in sub-Saharan Africa by reducing crop yields and livestock productivity because of variability in rainfall, increased temperatures and incidences of the disease and pest (Kurukulasuriya et al., Reference Kurukulasuriya, Mendelsohn, Hassan, Benhin, Deressa, Diop, Eid, Fosu, Gbetibouo, Jain, Mahamadou, Mano, Kabubo-Mariara, El-Marsafawy, Ouda, Ouedraogo, Séne, Maddison, Seo and Dinar2006), and variations in the frequency and severity of extreme climatic events such as floods and droughts (Brida et al., Reference Brida, Owiyo and Sokona2013). Recent results indicate that climate change would most likely result in significant crop yield losses, impacting the livelihoods of Africa’s smallholder farmers (Lobell et al., Reference Lobell, Schlenker and Costa-Roberts2011). As a result, food security and income opportunities for farm households most reliant on agriculture may be jeopardized.

Climate change is largely caused by an increase in the concentration of heat-trapping gases, also known as greenhouse gases, in the Earth’s atmosphere. The most abundant of these gases is carbon dioxide, but methane, nitrous oxide, and some hydrocarbons and fluorinated gases also play important roles (Smith et al., Reference Smith, Martino, Cai, Gwary, Janzen, Kumar and McCarl2008). Reducing greenhouse gas emissions and increasing carbon dioxide uptake by plants, soils, and oceans are two ways to reduce the amount of greenhouse gases entering the atmosphere. Agriculture makes a significant contribution to emissions of greenhouse gases, especially in developing countries such as Nigeria. It is estimated that agriculture accounts for 10–12% of total anthropogenic greenhouse gases (IPCC, 2014). The agriculture sector’s overall contribution rises to about 26–35% when indirect emissions from the fertilizer industry, rice cultivation, and emissions from deforestation and land conversion are included (Padfield et al., Reference Padfield, Papargyropoulou and Preece2012).

As a result, prioritizing the development of adaptive mechanisms to deal with the negative effects of climate change should be a top priority. The promotion of agricultural practices with Climate-Smart Agriculture potentials (AP-CSAPs) is one major opportunity to mitigate climate change while maintaining agricultural system productivity (World Bank, 2011; Kehinde et al., Reference Kehinde, Shittu and Osunsina2019). Agricultural practices with Climate-Smart Agriculture potentials will also help with the creation of adaptive capacity, enabling producers, service providers to farmers, and key organizations to respond to long-term climate change effectively, while also managing the risks associated with increased climate variability (FAO, 2013). This is accomplished through the three core pillars of CSA, which are to increase agricultural productivity and income sustainably; adapt to and build resilience to climate change; and reduce greenhouse gas emissions where possible (FAO, 2010).

In this study, the AP-CSAPs are contextualized as a set of good agricultural practices (GAPs) that include GAPs with and without manure application, as well as agroforestry. Good agricultural practices are a set of farming operations aimed at improving food safety and quality of agricultural products during the production and postproduction phases, as well as environmental and socioeconomic sustainability (FAO 2016; Lotz et al., Reference Lotz, van de Wiel and Smulders2018). The GAPs include but are not limited to the combined use of zero/minimum tillage, early maturing and drought-tolerant varieties, mulching, crop rotation, mixed cropping, retaining refuse on the soil rather than burning, cover cropping, manuring (green manuring, application of farmyard manure, and compost), microdosing of fertilizer where absolutely necessary, integrated weed and pest management, improve water use efficiency, water harvesting, among others.

The adoption of AP-CSAPs in sub-Saharan Africa is typically low (FAO, 2013; Byamugisha, Reference Byamugisha2013; Liniger et al., Reference Liniger, Rima, Hauert and Gurtner2011). This could be because implementing the AP-CSAPs usually requires upfront investments that take time to yield productivity gains. It is also worth noting that the present markets do not correctly reflect the value of the environmental benefits provided by AP-CSAPs. Various incentives, such as transition funds, payment of ecological services, carbon price under carbon dioxide, and others, have been proposed to address this challenge (FAO, 2013; Wollenberg et al., Reference Wollenberg, Higman, Seeberg-Elverfeldt, Neely, Tapio-Biström and Neufeldt2012; Shittu et al., Reference Shittu, Kehinde, Ogunaike and Oyawole2018), to encourage more farmers to adopt AP-CSAPs. However, little is known about how smallholder farmers in sub-Saharan Africa, especially in the Southwest and North central Geopolitical Zones (GPZs) in Nigeria, may respond to such incentives. This may, however, not be unconnected with insecure land tenure and property rights (LTPRs), which is often cited as a barrier to the adoption of improved technology and investment in land development in Africa (Byamugisha, Reference Byamugisha2013; Liniger et al., Reference Liniger, Rima, Hauert and Gurtner2011).

Emerging literature evidence (Deininger, Reference Deininger2003; Tenaw et al., Reference Tenaw, Zahidul and Tuulikki2009; Roth and McCarthy, Reference Roth and McCarthy2013) suggests that LTPRs may be important in various ways for economic growth. First, secure LTPRs encourage increased land investment, thereby fostering capital accumulation that is important to economic growth. Second, secure LTPRs enable landowners to use their property as collateral for loans, allowing for greater access to credit, which would not only improve investments but also provide a safe haven in the event of a shock (Tenaw et al., Reference Tenaw, Zahidul and Tuulikki2009). Third, generally secure LTPRs in a society tend to facilitate the emergence of more efficient land and labor markets, as well as attract foreign direct investment, both of which are critical in boosting economic growth (Roth and McCarthy, Reference Roth and McCarthy2013). Land tenure and property rights give incentives to farmers to adopt technologies that increase their efficiencies in relation to productivity and ensure environmental sustainability (Roth and McCarthy, Reference Roth and McCarthy2013). Similarly, Deininger (Reference Deininger2003) noted that without secure property rights farmers often don’t have the emotional attachment to the land they cultivate, and would thus not invest in land improvement that can enhance their productivity in the long run and promote sustainable development.

It is against this background that this paperFootnote 1 presents the report of a choice experiment with the focus on best scaling techniques (BWS) to assess the readiness of smallholder farmers in Nigeria to accept incentives for a shift to the CSA. This technique became increasingly popular in the area of healthcare preferences (Marley & Louviere, Reference Marley and Louviere2005) and is very different from traditional discrete choices, as additional information is obtained about the least preferred choice (Flynn et al., Reference Flynn, Louviere, Peters and Coast2007). BWS consists of at least three-option choice tasks in which an individual is asked to classify the best and worst choices, with the ultimate aim of obtaining a complete ranking of items in a way that is easy for respondents to understand and can then be analyzed in different ways (Marley & Louviere, Reference Marley and Louviere2005). Despite the fact that traditional discrete choice experiment has been used in many environmental valuation applications, only a few studies (Greiner, Reference Greiner2016) use this approach for non-market valuation based on multi-attribute discrete choice data.

This study was deemed necessary for Nigeria and other developing countries experiencing declining agricultural productivity due to land degradation and other climate change-related issues, in order to empirically determine what incentives farmers will be willing to accept in order to shift to climate-smart practices (CSPs) capable of reversing land degradation, restoring ecosystem health, and enhancing livelihood outcomes. In a number of ways, the paper contributes to the ongoing debates on willingness to accept incentives and CSA in Africa’s smallholder agriculture.

First, it contributes to the methodological debate on choice experiments by comparing model results from the best–worst scaling data set with results from the best choice subset to determine which of the two models produced a better result. Second, it provides new empirical evidence on the types of LTPRs that exist for agricultural lands in both Southwest and North central regions of Nigeria. Third, it offers empirical evidence on how CSA schemes, payment vehicles, intervention management, tenure types, and tenure security (title registration) influence smallholder farmers’ choice of CSPs in Nigeria.

Several studies have used traditional discrete choice experiments to investigate how the willingness of the farmers in Nigeria to accept incentives for climate-smart cultivation is affected by LTPRs (Shittu et al., Reference Shittu, Kehinde, Ogunaike and Oyawole2018), to explore future responses of farmers to German greening of the common agricultural policy in Germany (Schulz et al., Reference Schulz, Breustedt and Latacz-Lohmann2014), and investigate farmers’ preferences for drought tolerance traits and explore heterogeneity in these preferences embodied in different rice backgrounds in rural Bihar, India (Ward et al., Reference Ward, Ortega, Spielman and Singh2013), investigate Ethiopian farmers’ preferences for crop variety traits (Asrat et al., Reference Asrat, Yesuf, Carlsson and Wale2010), and explore Ethiopian potato farmers’ preferences for specific contract design attributes (Abebe et al., Reference Abebe, Bijman, Kemp, Omta and Tsegaye2013). Arising from the foregoing, this paper seeks to fill the already identified gaps.

The theoretical and econometric framework underlying choice modeling in conjunction with CSPs is outlined in the following section. Section three describes the methods, which include the discrete choice experiment design, study area, key variable measurement, and data analysis method. Section four describes and discusses our findings. In the final section, we discuss the implications of our findings.

1.1 Climate-Smart Agriculture in Africa

Promoting CSA is critical for African countries. This is due to the fact that food production will need to increase by 70% by 2050 to meet the demands of a rapidly growing population and changing diets (Suleman Reference Suleman2017). As a result, sub-Saharan Africa’s agricultural sector requires major transformation to address the multiple challenges of climate change, food insecurity and malnutrition, poverty, and environmental degradation (Nyasimi et al., Reference Nyasimi, Amwata, Hove, Kinyangi and Wamukoya2014). A variety of agricultural management solutions are available to increase crop productivity, build resilience to climate shocks, and reduce carbon emissions. Obtaining this triple win is critical to addressing Africa’s food security agenda (FAO 2013; FMARD, 2014; Hou et al., Reference Hou, Morales, Obuya, Bobo and Braimoh2016).

Nwajiuba et al., (Reference Nwajiuba, Emmanuel and Solomon2015) used Nigeria, Cameroon, and the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC) as case studies to critically examine the current state of CSA knowledge in Africa. They found that CSA is yet to be an explicit government policy and there are no agricultural practices defined as CSA in the three African countries mentioned earlier. However, elements of CSA are employed by farmers in Nigeria, Cameroon, and DRC, who engage in quite a number of agricultural practices despite the fact that they do not deliberately regard them as CSA practices. This assertion is based on the premise that the smallholders aim at improving productivity, build resilience against climate change, and reduce/mitigate greenhouse gases. However, some of the identified gaps in policy across the three countries include key stakeholders’ engagement on national CSA dialogue, low awareness about CSA, mainstreaming CSA into national agricultural development policy to expedite holistic approach in facilitating stakeholders’ engagement in the agricultural sector, building capacity, and training of the extension workers (government and private) with respect to core proficiencies in CSA using training of the trainers approach; actively engaging the youth and schools in CSA extension program strategies to widen dissemination and achieve greater impact.

Conservation agriculture, integrated crop management, organic agriculture, agricultural water management, and indigenous knowledge (local knowledge) are some of the CSA practices identified in Nigeria. Similarly in Cameroon, the CSA practices used include organic fertilizer, agroforestry, intercropping, multiple cropping and crop rotation, water harvesting, sprinkler, and drip irrigation, late planting, blocking of drainage, wood ash application, shade trees, riverbank farming, changing of planting dates, and soil conservation strategy. Identified CSA practices in DRC include soil and water conservation structures, sustainable land management practice, tree planting, and agroforestry, early-maturing varieties, mulching, fertilizer and manure application, livelihood diversification and new crops, changing of planting date.

Hou et al., (Reference Hou, Morales, Obuya, Bobo and Braimoh2016) highlight successful CSA projects in Africa. The first case study is the establishment of Climate-Smart Villages (CSVs) in Kenya. Farmers in the CSVs discovered that crop diversification will make their farms more resilient to climate change, sequester carbon while simultaneously increasing productivity and income as well as improving the soil quality. CSVs approach is all-encompassing and it has improved food security and adaptation to climate change, and also provides several options to smallholder farmers for adapting their agriculture.

The second case study focuses on incentivizing agriculture in Zambia—conservation through sustainable agricultural practices. Community Markets for Conservation (COMACO) is a rural development model that uses inputs, technologies, and markets to assist smallholders in achieving food security and increasing incomes while conserving the natural resources on which they rely. Community Markets for Conservation’s premise is that if smallholders are given the right incentives and training, they will prefer sustainable agriculture practices over more destructive ones, especially if their basic food and income needs are met. COMACO sells goods at above-market prices that are produced in accordance with sustainable soil, farming, and conservation agriculture practices. Community Markets for Conservation has trained 87,000 farmers (52% of whom are women) in climate-smart and sustainable agriculture. The trained farmers now practice minimum tillage, mulching, and composting, in addition to beekeeping, dry season gardening, and poultry husbandry. The CSA practices have increased productivity and reduced conventional agriculture such as deforestation and bush fires, hence reducing greenhouse gas emissions.

The third case study is combating drought in Morocco—supporting smallholder farmers in a changing climate. Morocco is prone to drought, and climate change is already resulting in higher temperatures and lower and more unpredictable rainfall. This has implications for the agricultural sector, which is critical to the country’s demographic and socioeconomic situation. Water management is crucial under drought conditions and climate change. In irrigated areas, the Plan Maroc Vert (PMV) and the related National Irrigation Water-Saving Program promote improved water service and the adoption of more efficient irrigation technologies. As a result, water is provided when it is best for crop needs, and can be used by small farmers more effectively and efficiently. In rainfed areas, the PMV promotes—among others—the transition from cereals to tree crops: olive trees are well adapted to drought, provide a higher return to small farmers, and are less at risk of year-to-year fluctuations than annual crops especially when practices like rainwater harvesting are put in place.

Mutoko (Reference Mutoko2014) classified the broad factors influencing the adoption of CSA practices as socioeconomic and cultural barriers, as well as policy and institutional frameworks. They discovered that composting and biogas adoption is low in Kaptumo, which was attributed to the type of farming system and availability of resources such as small quantities of manure and high labor demand. The farmer trainers pointed out that the county’s open grazing system makes collecting scattered fresh cow dung labor intensive. Addressing this challenge would imply the need for farmers in that area to shift to a zero-grazing system which will be too costly to establish for most of the smallholder farmers. The main limitation of the use in agroforestry and fodder trees is the availability of seeds/seedlings, as described in the household survey and the focus group discussions. Men are generally the de facto landowner and the primary decision maker for allocating land to family members for various uses. Given that tree planting is viewed as defining one’s piece of land, the challenge is real for women, sons, and daughters who took part in the project to embrace agroforestry and fodder trees. This is due to a lack of authority to make such decisions for the household head, who may or may not have participated in project activities.

Emphasizing the policy and institutional frameworks that affect the adoption of CSPs, Mutoko (Reference Mutoko2014) stated the need for a policy framework that clearly specifies the terms and conditions of how smallholders who have adopted CSA practices such as agroforestry can benefit from carbon credit schemes. Similarly, existing agricultural extension services need to be strengthened and extension workers’ capacity built, in particular, on promising CSA practices. Many public institutions face resource constraints when it comes to service delivery; however, the innovative farmer trainers’ approach is capable of making the extension delivery systems more efficient and more effective. The farmer trainers’ approach would ensure the sustainability and scale-out of climate-smart activities in this and other areas if integrated into the mainstream of extension delivery systems properly (Kiptot et al., 2011). The adoption rate of CSA practices can be accelerated through effective partnership and collaboration with other interested organizations in the county.

2. Theoretical Framework and Modeling

The random utility theory is the basis for the discrete choice experiment and best–worst scaling; therefore, the models for the two methods are similar with the exception of additional information that is included in the BWS method. The central premise of random utility theory is that decision makers maximize their utility by selecting their preferred alternative from a set of alternatives (Luce, Reference Luce1959; McFadden, Reference McFadden1974; Shen, Reference Shen2006).

The real utility of an alternative for a farmer i cannot be observed; however, it could be seen as consisting of systematic component, V and an error (random) component, $\varepsilon $ which is independent of the systematic part and follows a predetermined distribution (McFadden, Reference McFadden1974; Hanemann et al., Reference Hanemann, Loomis and Kanninen1991).

(1) $${U_{ikn}} = {V_{ikn}} + {\varepsilon _{ikn}}$$

Thus, a farmer i will choose an alternative k from a specific choice set, n, given the utility of U, if the utility of farmer i making a choice of an alternative k from a specific choice set, n ( ${U_{ikn}})$ is greater than the utility of any other alternative j in choice set n:

The probability of farmer i choosing the alternative k is

(2) $${P_{ikn}} = Pr\left( {{U_{ikn}} \gt {U_{ijn}}} \right){\forall _j} \ne k\;$$
(3) $${U_{kn}} \gt {U_{jn}} \to {V_{kn}} + {\varepsilon _{kn}} \gt {V_{jn}} + {\varepsilon _{jn}}\;{\forall _j} \ne k;k,j \in J$$

V is, therefore, the explainable proportion of the variance in choice while $\varepsilon $ is the unobservable part. The random utility model assumes that an individual acts rationally and chooses the choice that provides the highest degree of satisfaction, implying that the person is maximizing his utility. In addition, the above-mentioned choice procedure is interpreted with error terms following Gumbel distribution by both discrete choice experiment and best–worst scaling technique.

3. Method

3.1. Survey Design

Analyzing discrete choice data entails the design of an experiment to investigate the influence of various attributes of the alternatives on the preferred choice. The choice experiment design process, according to Hensher et al., (Reference Hensher, Rose and Greene2005) and Louviere et al., (Reference Louviere, Hensher and Swait2000), begins with identifying the problem and defining the objectives of the experiment. Answers to the following questions will help you gain a better understanding of the problem:

  1. 1. What are the possible alternatives, that is, other options that could have been taken into account by the respondent instead of making the choice?

  2. 2. What characteristics do the existing alternatives have?

  3. 3. What are the most likely factors influencing the demand for such alternatives?

  4. 4. Who is the intended audience?

According to Louviere et al., (Reference Louviere, Hensher and Swait2000) and Hensher et al., (Reference Hensher, Rose and Greene2005), genericFootnote 2 AP-CSAPs were presented to respondents, who were asked to select the best and worst alternatives, which differed in terms of the levels at which the attributes were presented, with a status quo option to be exhaustive. The response format was a multi-profile best–worst scaling technique (Flynn and Marley Reference Flynn and Marley2012). The BWS is structured to provide a complete ranking of all alternatives present in an option range, whereas the conventional discrete choice experiment format only shows the first preference among the alternatives. BWS provides a way to augment data and is particularly useful in situations where the number of choice tasks needs to be minimized by providing choice data in addition to the first preference (Potoglou et al., Reference Potoglou, Burge, Flynn, Netten, Malley, Forder and Brazier2011; Lancsar et al., Reference Lancsar, Louviere, Donaldson, Currie and Burgess2013). It differs mainly from traditional DCEs because it receives additional information about the least preferred option (Flynn, Reference Flynn2010). BWS has also proven to be superior when dealing with qualitative data, such as various conservation criteria and monitoring arrangements (Flynn et al., Reference Flynn, Louviere, Peters and Coast2007).

There is no standard method for selecting attributes, as established in the literature (Bennett & Blamey, Reference Bennett and Blamey2001; Bateman et al., Reference Bateman, Carson, Hanemann, Hanley, Hett, Jones-Lee, Loomes, Mourato, Özdemiroðlu, Pearce, Sugden and Swanson2002), but the attributes should be relevant to policy makers and meaningful to respondents. As a result, the attributes and attribute levels for this study were determined through a multistage process that included literature reviews, direct questioning, and interviews with key stakeholders such as crop specialists and extension agents, among others. The carbon price was included as part of the attribute so that willingness to accept could be estimated.

The experiment was performed in conjunction with interviews to determine the farmers’ land-use preferences, trade-offs, and WTA incentives to move from their current farming system to one of a collection of context/crop-specific AP-CSAPs, based on the above discrete choice experimental design. In addition to the importance of restoring soil health, AP-CSAPs have the potential to sequester carbon, help farmers to build resilience to climate change, and increase productivity. The presented AP-CSAPs include agroforestry and the adoption of GPAs with or without manure application. The GAPs include the use of Zero/Minimum tillage, retaining/incorporating refuse on the soil rather than burning it, and Integrated Water, Pest, and Fertility Management—including microdosing of fertilizer when absolutely necessary.

Using the FAO Ex-Ante Carbon Balance Tool (Ex-Act), we estimated the carbon sequestration potentials of shifting to a CSA option versus not using any CSA with CSA potentials under various climate and soil conditions in Nigeria. To offer a project period of 30 years, we set the implementation phase at 10 years and the capitalization phase at 20 years. In determining the incentives offered to farmers, the estimated carbon sequestration potentials were valued at carbon prices ranging from US$10/tCO2 equivalent to US$50/tCO2 equivalent. This was based on the World Bank Carbon Pricing Watch (World Bank and ECOFYS 2016), which estimated global carbon prices as of April 1, 2016, to be between US$6/tCO2 equivalent and US$53/tCO2 equivalent.

Table 1 shows the choice attributes of concern and their levels. Using the orthogonal design procedures in the Statistical Package for Social Scientists (SPSS) version 17, these were combined into profiles (i.e., options presented in the choice sets). This method produces a compact collection of profiles that are small enough to fit into a survey but broad enough to determine the relative value of each attribute. The orthogonal main effects design framework enables statistical testing of multiple attributes without requiring testing of each grouping of attribute levels.

Table 1. Attributes and levels of Climate-Smart Practices for smallholder farmers

In the context of this study, two series of orthogonal main effect designs, each comprising 25 profiles, were generated in two sets per crop/context-specific scenario and the tasks presented to respondents were randomly combined with the status quo (e.g., Table 2). This procedure yielded 25 task sets, which were divided into five blocks of five tasks each, and was presented sequentially to all respondents. The blocks were assigned to respondents at random in a systematic manner: the first respondent to be interviewed receives tasks in Block A, the second B…, and the fifth E. The cycle was repeated for respondents 6–10, 11–15, and so on. In any given choice task, respondents were asked to select the most preferred options and then indicate which option was less preferred than the second preferred option. This BWS format allowed for the ranking of all AP-CSAPs alternatives and the status quo. It is worth noting that the incentive (Table 2) is calculated by multiplying the carbon price by the potential carbon that will be sequestered by each of the CSA schemes.

Table 2. Typical tasks presented to respondents

Note: Official exchange rates at the time of the study were an average of N305.44/US$1.

3.2. The Study Area

The research was conducted in selected farming communities in Nigeria’s two GPZs (Southwest and North central). Nigeria is located in West Africa, between the longitudes of 3° and 14° and the latitudes of 4° and 14°. It has a land area of 923,768 square kilometers. Nigeria is bordered on the west by the Republic of Benin, on the east by Chad and Cameroon, and on the north by Niger. Its coast faces the Gulf of Guinea in the south and Lake Chad in the northeast. The study area includes 12 of Nigeria’s 36 states as well as the Federal Capital Territory, which are divided into 4 agro-ecological zones: rain forest, mid-altitude, derived, and southern Guinea Savannah all of which are suitable for maize and rice, as well as other crops such as cassava, yams, and others. Nigeria comprises 36 Federal States and the territories of the Federal Capital. The states are usually divided into six (6) geographical zones: the northeast, the northwest, the north central, the southwest, and the south–south. The Hausa–Fulani’s, Nupe, Gwari Tiv, and Igalas are indigenous to the North central states, while the Yorubas are indigenous to the Southwest. In 2015, the estimated human population was 191.8 million, 29% of which were Hausa–Fulani’s and 21% Yoruba’s.

3.3. Study Design

The research was conducted as part of the FUNAAB-RAAF-PASANAO project, which was funded by the Economic Community of West African States and carried out by the Federal University of Agriculture, Abeokuta (FUNAAB) in collaboration with the National Cereals Research Institute, Baddegi. The focus was on encouraging the adoption of CSA practices in cereals production in Nigeria. The respondents were selected in a three-stage sampling process, described as follows:

Stage I: Purposive selection of seven states that have been the leading rice and maize producers in Southwest and North central Nigeria based on production statistics from (National Bureau of Statistics [NBS], 2016).

Stage II: Purposive selection of Three Agricultural Blocks per crop from the state’s main rice and maize production areas, as well as two Extension Cells per block, for a total of 12 Cells and 84 Cells.

Stage III: In each of the selected cells, a proportionate stratified random selection of 5–10 rice and maize farmers from members of the maize and rice farmers’ associations.

This process resulted in 542 maize and rice farmer households, from which a full data set was compiled through personal interviews with the farmer and other family members. Data on a wide range of topics were collected, including household socioeconomics, land-use choices, and ecosystem service valuation, as well as LTPRs on farmland cultivated during the 2016/2017 farming season.

3.4. Method of Data Analysis

The data were analyzed using a combination of descriptive and econometric techniques. Data from the household survey, land acquisition, and key rights held were analyzed using descriptive statistical methods to generate frequencies and percentages. Data on WTA incentives for shifting to CSA schemes, as well as the influence of land titling and tenure type on this, were analyzed using the rank-ordered regression method.

3.4.1. Measurement of Land Tenure and Property Rights

Two measures were used to determine farmers’ LTPRs in this study. They include:

  1. (i) Tenure Type: This was measured on a nominal scale using three dummy variables—Freehold, Leasehold, and Communal—with one indicating that the right to use the parcel of land was obtained by direct inheritance and/or outright purchase for freehold, leased or rented for leasehold, and joint ownership with extended family or other community members for communal. Otherwise, the dummy variables were given a value of zero.

  2. (ii) Tenure security (legal): A tenure was considered de jure secured if the parcel was surveyed and properly registered with the Land Registry; otherwise, it was considered unsecured. This variable was designed to evaluate the significance of title registration.

3.4.2. Econometric Model

In marketing research, the rank-ordered logit (ROL) model is also known as the exploded logit model (Punj and Staelin Reference Punj and Staelin1978) and the choice-based conjoint analysis model (Hair et al., Reference Hair, Black, Babin and Anderson2010). The ROL analytical framework is one of the extensions of the multinomial logit model and was chosen because respondents rank the alternatives rather than simply selecting the best option from a set of alternatives presented to them. The maximum likelihood approach is used to estimate the model coefficients and the ROL model is specified in equation 4 as follows:

(4) $${\rm Let}\, U_{ikn} = \beta _i' {{\rm{X}}_{{\rm{ikn}}}}{\rm{ + }}{\varepsilon _{{\rm{ikn}}}}$$

for $j = A,\;.\;.\;.\;,\;C$ with ${\varepsilon _{ikn}}$ independently identically distributed, iid with an extreme value distribution.

Where

${U_{ikn}}$ = utility that farmer i would obtain from choosing alternative k.

${X_{ikn}}$ = observable attributes of alternative k to farmer i for each choice scenario n.

${\beta _i}$ = is a vector of coefficients of these variables for farmer i, which represents the farmer’s taste.

${\varepsilon _{ikn}}$ = unobservable component of utility accruing to farmer i from alternative k.

The trade-off (marginal rate of substitution) of one attribute in terms of another was calculated using the estimated parameters in the empirical model. One important trade-off is that of the bid and one of the other attributes. The WTA for attribute z is obtained by dividing the parameter’s value ${\delta _z}$ with the bid parameter (i.e., ${\delta _z}/{\delta _{incentive}})$ ; where the parameter ${\delta _z}$ are marginal utilities of the attributes. Table 3 shows the outcome variables of interest as well as the sets of regressors used in the study.

Table 3. Definitions of study variables and their descriptive statistics

4. Results and Discussion

4.1. Socioeconomic Characteristics of the Smallholder Farmers

Table 4 summarized the socioeconomic background of 542 farmers who provided the entire data set used in this study as a background for subsequent analyses. According to Table 4, the average cereal crop farmer in the study area is around 46 years old, has 9 years of schooling, is 7% likely to be a female, and is 81% likely to be married. The average household had seven (7) members. During the 2016/2017 farming season, the 542 farmers whose data were used in this study provided plot-level information on a total of 1,810 parcels of land that were cultivated by members of their farm households. The characteristics of the farmland in terms of size, mode of acquisition, property rights enjoyed by households on those lands, and registration status on those parcels are summarized in Table 5.

Table 4. Socioeconomic characteristics and percentage in the sample (n = 542)

Source: Field survey; 2017.

Table 5. Distribution of cultivated parcels by title registration and tenure types

Source: Field Survey; 2017.

Table 5 depicts the distribution of 1,810 cultivated parcels in the Suthwest and North central geopolitical areas in Nigeria by title registration, tenure, and property rights characteristics among smallholder farmers. The plot size was 1.49ha on average. The proportion of land acquired through inheritance was extremely lower for the southwest (26.78%) as opposed to that of north central (56.07%). On the contrary, the smallholder farmers in the southwest (50.54%) tend to cultivate more leased land when compared to their north central counterparts (28.45%). In addition, about 9.71% and 7.64% of the sampled farmers cultivated farmland acquired through outright purchase and communal means.

In terms of key rights, the majority of respondents across the study area have the ability to exclude others from their farm (74.62%), grow tree crops (65.52%), and develop their plots further (61.54%) by investing in an irrigation scheme, while approximately half of them may either sell or transfer their land to the next generation. Also, 23.47% of the farmers’ farmlands were duly surveyed with about 4.63% of the cultivated parcels registered with the state government, as well as only 3.33% and 6.23% of the parcels registered in both north central and southwest, respectively. This implies that only a few out of the sampled smallholder farmers had de jure tenure security while the majority had insecure tenure which can lead to eviction from their farmland and regular harassment by the land grabbers. The result is closely in line with the findings of Ghebru et al., (Reference Ghebru, Edeh, Ali, Deininger, Okumo and Woldeyohannes2014) and Birner and Okumo (Reference Birner and Okumo2012) who found that only 3% of the land in Nigeria is formally registered. It is worth noting that the right-held variables are not mutually exclusive, hence the reason for the values not summing to 100%.

4.2. Best–Worst Scores of the Smallholder Farmers

The best–worst scenarios of CSA attributes in combination with the intervention management and mode of payment are shown in Tables 6 and 7, respectively. The results show that agroforestry, GAPs with manure, and GAPs without manure are of most concern to about 52%, 45%, and 26% of the sampled smallholders, respectively. It is important to note that less than 20% of the respondents see agroforestry and GAPs with manure as the issue of least concern in the study area with 60% of the smallholder farmers ranking the status quo (conventional practice) as their worst choice. This implies that the farmers are willing to embrace AP-CSAPs. Agroforestry with government as the intervention management is chosen as the best choice in 59% of the cases followed by when it is managed by private organizations. Good agricultural practices with (53%) and without manure (41%) application tend to be of most concern to the farmers when managed by the NGOs. Similarly, Table 7 shows that agroforestry with incentive received in kind (57%), GAPs with manure when the incentive is given in both cash and kind (55%) as well as GAPs without manure when the incentive is received as a cash payment (32%) are of great concern to the farmers.

Table 6. Best–worst scores of the CSA attributes by intervention management

Source: Field survey; 2017.

Table 7. Best–worst scores of the CSA attributes by mode of payment

Source: Field survey; 2017.

4.3. Hausman Specification Test

Given the study data, the Hausman test (Table 8) was used to see whether the unrestricted model (full ranking data) is superior to the restricted model (most preferred alternatives) or not. All studies and experiments were carried out in Stata 16 using the appropriate procedures.

Table 8. Estimated best–worst models results and Hausman Specification Test Results

As noted in Stata 16 documentations, the Hausman is a general implementation of Hausman’s (Reference Hausman1978) specification test, which compares an estimator ${\hat \theta _1}$ that is known to be consistent with an estimator ${\hat \theta _2}$ that is efficient under the assumption being tested. The null hypothesis states that the estimator ${\hat \theta _2}$ is an efficient (and consistent) estimator of the true parameters. There should be no systematic difference between the two estimators if this is the case. If the estimates differ in a systematic way, the assumptions on which the efficient estimator is based should be questioned. Table 8 shows that the null hypothesis of no systematic difference between the two estimators is rejected at the 1% level, implying that the unrestricted model outperforms the restricted model. As a result, we believe that an evidence-based full-ranking model is efficient and reliable, making it suitable for policy analysis.

4.4. Willingness to Accept Incentive to Shift to Climate-Smart Schemes

Table 8 shows the results for both the best–worst and first choice models. The estimation included eight thousand one hundred thirty selected observations (542 respondents, 15 choice sets each). At the 1% level, the coefficients associated with the size of the incentive were positive and significant. This implies that the higher the incentive provided to farmers, the more likely the farmer will be willing to abandon the status quo and invest in CSA schemes. This is consistent with the findings of Schulz et al., (Reference Schulz, Breustedt and Latacz-Lohmann2014), who discovered that higher payment increased the likelihood of preferring greening to the “do nothing” alternative.

4.5. Influence of CSA Scheme, Mode of Incentive Payment, and Management

The coefficients of GAPs with and without manure application were significantly positive at a 1% level. This result shows that stronger preference was given to GAPs with manure followed by GAPs without manure in the best–worst model. This finding suggests that the smallholder farmers were willing to shift to GAPs with and without manure as against the status quo indicating their favorable disposition to CSA schemes. This shows that the farmers assign a higher value to both GAPs with and without manure application as opposed to the status quo. Despite the scarcity and higher cost of manure application relative to investing in other measures to combat land degradation, GAPs with manure were still given stronger preference and highest priority by the farmers in the study area.

The coefficient of community-based association and non-governmental organizations managed schemes were significant and positive at 1% level, respectively, while the coefficient of private-managed schemes was negative and significant at 5% level. The results indicate that farmers preferred CDA and NGOs-managed schemes over other project management, and they would also prefer government-based institutions (status quo) over the private sector, possibly because they did not trust them enough to provide effective services. As a result, project management by either the CDA or NGOs will increase the likelihood of farming households investing in CSA schemes. This finding supports the findings of Shittu et al., (Reference Shittu, Kehinde, Ogunaike and Oyawole2018) that there was clear discord with the PES schemes managed by the private sector in relation to the schemes managed by the public sector.

Focusing on preferences for mode of incentive payments in Table 8, the coefficient of cash and kind payment was positively significant at a 1% level while the result was not significantly different from zero for payment made in kind. The possibility of farmers receiving an incentive in cash and in-kind increased significantly the likelihood of shifting to CSA schemes among the smallholder farmers as against the reference category of cash payment.

4.6. Main Effects Interacting with Tenure Type and Land Titling

To examine the influence of tenure type and land titling on farmers’ preferences for CSA schemes, the level of these factors were interacted with CSA schemes. The result (Table 8) shows that farming households with GAPs with and without manure when interacted with the land acquisition by freehold and leasehold, were not significantly different from zero. However, GAPs with and without manure application on communal land significantly and positively influence the preference for CSA scheme at 1% level, respectively. This implies that tenure type is important for a shift to the CSA scheme and that having a secure tenure to make a medium to long-term investment on the land will enable the smallholder farmers to recover their returns from the land. This result is in agreement with the findings of Roth and McCarthy (Reference Roth and McCarthy2013) who opined that secure land tenure provides incentives for farmers to invest and make improvements to their land to ensure full utilization of land

Similarly, agroforestry when interacted with land acquired by freehold and leasehold positively and significantly influence the preference for CSA schemes at 1% and 5% levels, respectively. Thus, farming households attribute a stronger preference to cultivating agroforestry on land acquisition by freehold followed by a strong preference for cultivating agroforestry on communal with the establishment of agroforestry on leased lands having the lowest preference. This implies that smallholder farmers will only agree to embrace agroforestry provided the farmland is acquired through freehold and/or leasehold means. Similarly, land titling was only important to promote a shift to GAPs without manure at a 5% level, while it was not significantly different from zero for other CSA schemes—most likely because the majority of those who registered land are elites (possibly, land grabbers) whose main mission is to sell it at a premium later. This finding is in line with the finding of Besley (Reference Besley1995) and Nigussie et al., (Reference Nigussie, Tsunekawa, Haregeweyn, Adgo, Nohmi, Tsubo, Aklog, Meshesha and Abele2017) who found that secure tenure enhanced agricultural investments in Ghana and Ethiopia, respectively.

4.7. Willingness to Accept Incentives for a Shift to CSA Schemes

Table 9 shows the willingness to accept (pay) based on parameter estimates from the unrestricted model in Table 8. The results reveal that an average farmer is willing to accept $88, $540, and $386 per hectare per annum to embrace agroforestry, GAPs with and without manure, respectively, in the study area. In a case where any of the CSA schemes is managed by CDA and NGO, the farmers are willing to accept $201 and $198 per hectare each year, respectively. On the contrary, the farmers are willing to pay (give up) $61/ha/annum if the CSA scheme will be managed by the private organization, implying they will prefer the CSA scheme to be managed by the government. Estimated willingness to accept values per hectare/year for an average farmer that integrated agroforestry on freehold, leasehold, and communal land are $474, $236, and $977, respectively. Similarly, smallholder farmers that cultivate agroforestry, GAPs with and without manure on titled land are willing to accept $191, $119, and $181 per hectare per year, respectively, as incentives to shift to CSA schemes. Evidence from Shittu (Reference Shittu2017) shows that the annual revenue per ha for an average maize and rice farmer in Nigeria is US$1,508 and US$1,861, respectively. Situating the WTA result in the context of annual revenue per hectare for an average farmer in the study area, we wish to state the WTA values for CSA schemes are realistic as the incentive is meant to support the farmers knowing full well that implementing agricultural practices with CSA potentials, in most cases, involves upfront investments that take time to bring about gains in productivity.

Table 9. Willingness to accept (pay) 1 incentives for a shift to CSA options

Note: Figures in parentheses are WTAs, i.e., (WTA = WTP).

1 The WTA is at 95% confidence interval.

5. Conclusion and Policy Implications

Using the best–worst scaling technique, this study added to the literature on smallholder farmers’ preferences for shifting to CSA in Nigeria. Land tenure and property rights were examined on a plot-by-plot basis and are summarized as farmland characteristics in terms of size, mode of acquisition, property rights enjoyed by households on those lands, and the status of registration (de jure) on those parcels. The average parcel size was 1.49ha, with approximately 48.46% and 9.71% parcels held by inheritance and purchase, respectively, 34.19% held by leasehold, and 7.64% held by communal land. However, LTPRs results show that only 23.47% of the plots were surveyed while only 4.63% had their title registered with the State Land Registry.

The policy implications from this study are stated as follows:

  1. i. Government, private institutions, and relevant international agencies should make the incentives available to the farmers in form of payment for ecosystem services and/or conditional cash transfer so as to increase their willingness to shift from their current practice to CSA schemes.

  2. ii. The smallholder farmers were willing to shift to the CSA scheme as against the status quo. Hence, the need for both Federal and State governments to pay proper attention to the moribund extension services in Nigeria such that there will be a reawakening of the extension services through adequate funding of the agricultural development program, as well as capacity building of the agricultural extension officers to demonstrate the CSA practices and principles to the farmers using experimental management plots.

  3. iii. Secure tenure enhances medium to long-term investment on the land and also increases farmers’ willingness to embrace CSA schemes. Therefore, policy measures that will focus on a more effective and efficient land title registration system should be established by the government. The policy should also aim at removing the bottlenecks in the land market and enhancing individual tenure security.

  4. iv. An average farmer is willing to accept $88, $540, and $386/ha each year to embrace agroforestry, GAPs with and without manure, respectively. The farmers are willing to accept smaller payments for agroforestry and GAPs without manure, hence, policy directed toward the adoption of CSA schemes in Nigeria should focus mainly on agroforestry and GAPs without manure application.

  5. v. Project management by CDA or NGOs would increase the probability of farming households investing in CSA schemes, thus, all the relevant stakeholders needed to implement the CSA scheme in Nigeria should be brought on board.

It is pertinent to note that one of the limitations of this study is that currently, there is no PES in Nigeria and most parts of sub-Saharan Africa, we have to rely on existing literature in Europe and North America to arrive at our carbon prices. Given that the carbon price was between US$1 and US$153, we removed the extreme values and we believed that this limitation would not affect our results. Despite this limitation, we believe that our research has made significant contributions to the body of knowledge on the subject.

Acknowledgements

We thank the Cambridge University Press for granting us the discretionary waiver towards the publishing of this paper.

Authors’ contribution

Adebayo M. Shittu: Conceptualization, methodology, project administration, supervision, formal analysis, and writing (review and editing).

Mojisola O. Kehinde: Conceptualization, data curation, formal analysis, investigation, methodology, writing (original draft), and writing (review and editing).

Abigail G. Adeyonu: Writing (review and editing) of the manuscript.

Olutunji T. Ojo: Writing (review and editing) of the manuscript.

Funding statement

This project was implemented with a grant from the Economic Community of West African States with funding support of the French Development Agency (AFD) (Grant number: No.18_AP3_TH3/2016/ECOWAS/AEWR/RAAF/PASANAO).

Conflict of interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Data availability statement

The data will be made available on request.

Ethical standards

We agree upon standards of expected ethical behaviour for all parties involved in the act of publishing. Our paper presents an accurate account of the work performed and an objective discussion of its significance. Underlying data is represented accurately in the article. Each respondent was informed that his/her answers would be used as a part of a research project and agreed to that by filling in the questionnaire.

Footnotes

1 An earlier version of this paper, titled “Willingness to Accept Incentives for a Shift to Climate-smart Agriculture among Smallholders Farmers in Southwest and Northcentral Nigeria”, was presented at the 30th International Conference of Agricultural Economists of International Association of Agricultural Economists, held in Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada from July 28 to August 2, 2018.

2 That is, that no additional branding was given to the alternatives.

References

Abebe, G.K., Bijman, J., Kemp, R., Omta, O., and Tsegaye, A.. “Contract farming configuration: Smallholders’ preferences for contract design attributes.” Food Policy 40(2013):1424. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.foodpol.2013.01.002 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asrat, S., Yesuf, M., Carlsson, F., and Wale, E.. “Farmers’ Preferences for Crop Variety Traits: Lessons for On-Farm Conservation and Technology Adoption.” Ecological Economics 69(2010):23942401. doi: 10.1016/j.ecolecon.2010.07.006 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bateman, I.J., Carson, R.T., Hanemann, M., Hanley, N., Hett, T., Jones-Lee, M., Loomes, G., Mourato, S., Özdemiroðlu, E., Pearce, D.W., Sugden, R., and Swanson, J.. Economic Valuation with Stated Preference Techniques: A Manual. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennett, J. and Blamey, R.K.. The Choice Modelling approach to Environmental Valuation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2001.Google Scholar
Besley, T.Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana.” Journal of Political Economics 103,5(1995):903937 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brida, A.B., Owiyo, T., and Sokona, Y.. “Loss and damage from the double blow of flood and drought in Mozambique.International Journal of Global Warming 5,4(2013):514531. https://doi.org/10.1504/IJGW.2013.057291 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Byamugisha, F.F. Securing Africa’s Land for Shared Prosperity: A Program to Scale up Reforms and Investments. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birner, R., and Okumo, A.. “Challenges of Land Governance in Nigeria: Insights from a Case Study in Ondo State.” NSSP Working Paper No. 22. Abuja and Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. 2012.Google Scholar
Deininger, K. Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. A World Bank Policy Research Report. Washington, DC: The World Bank; 2003.Google Scholar
FAO. Climate-Smart Agriculture: Policies, Practices and Financing for Food Security, Adaptation and Mitigation. Rome: FAO, 2010.Google Scholar
FAO. Climate-Smart Agriculture Sourcebook. Rome, Italy. 2013. Internet site: http://www.fao.org/docrep/018/i3325e/i3325e00.html Google Scholar
FAO. Nigeria Food Security and Vulnerability Survey 2016 Report. FAO Representation in Nigeria. 2016.Google Scholar
Federal Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development. National Agricultural Resilience Framework. A Report by the Advisory Committee on Agricultural Resilience in Nigeria Edited by Jimmy Adegoke, ChidiIbe, and Adebisi Araba. Abuja, Nigeria; 2014.Google Scholar
Flynn, T.N., Louviere, J.J., Peters, T.J., and Coast, J.. “Best–worst scaling: What it can do for Health Care Research and How to do it.” Journal of Health Economics 26,1(2007):171189. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2006.04.002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Flynn, T.N.Valuing citizen and patient preferences in health: recent developments in three types of best–worst scaling.” Expert Review of Pharmacoeconomics & Outcomes Research 10,3(2010):259–67.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Flynn, TN, Marley, AA. “Best-worst scaling: theory and methods.” Handbook of Choice Modelling. S. Hess and A. Daly, eds. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 2012.Google Scholar
Greiner, R.Factors influencing farmers’ participation in contractual biodiversity conservation: a choice experiment with northern Australian pastoralists.” Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 60,1(2016):121. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-8489.12098 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghebru, H, Edeh, H., Ali, D., Deininger, K., Okumo, A., and Woldeyohannes, S.. “Tenure Security and Demand for Land Tenure Regularization in Nigeria.” NSSP Working Paper No. 25. Abuja and Washington, DC: IFPRI, 2014.Google Scholar
Hair, J. F. Jr, Black, W.C., Babin, B.J., and Anderson, R.E.. Multivariate Data Analysis. 7th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson, 2010.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W.M., Loomis, J.B., and Kanninen, B.. “Statistical Efficiency of Double bounded Dichotomous Choice Contingent Valuation.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73,4(1991):12551263. https://doi.org/10.2307/1242453 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, J. A. 1978. “Specification tests in econometrics.” Econometrica 46:12511271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hensher, D.A., Rose, J.M., and Greene, W.H.. Applied Choice Analysis: A Primer. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2005.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hou, X., Morales, X.Z., Obuya, G.A., Bobo, D., and Braimoh, A.. Climate smart agriculture: successes in Africa. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group, 2016 Nov 1. Internet site: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/622181504179504144/Climate-smart-agriculture-successes-in-Africa (Accessed January 30, 2021).Google Scholar
IPCC. Summary for Policymakers. Climate Change (2014). Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014, pp. 1–32.Google Scholar
Kehinde, M.O., Shittu, A.M., and Osunsina, I.O.O.. “Willingness to Accept Incentives for a Shift to Climate-smart Agriculture among Lowland Rice Farmers in Nigeria.” Nigerian Journal of Agricultural Economics 9,1(2019):2944.Google Scholar
Kiptot, E., Lukuyu, B.A., Franzel, S., and Place, F.. “The farmer trainers approach in technology dissemination in Uganda: Farmer trainers’ and trainees’ perspectives.” East Africa Dairy Development Project. Working Paper, Nairobi, Kenya.Google Scholar
Kurukulasuriya, P., Mendelsohn, R., Hassan, R., Benhin, J., Deressa, T., Diop, M., Eid, H.M., Fosu, K.Y., Gbetibouo, G., Jain, S., Mahamadou, A., Mano, R., Kabubo-Mariara, J., El-Marsafawy, E.M., Ouda, S., Ouedraogo, M., Séne, I., Maddison, D., Seo, S.N., and Dinar, A.. “Will African Agriculture Survive Climate Change?The World Bank Economic Review 20,3(2006):367388. https://doi.org/10.1093/wber/lhl004.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lancsar, E., Louviere, J., Donaldson, C., Currie, G., and Burgess, L.. 2013. “Best worst discrete choice experiments in health: Methods and an application.” Social Science & Medicine 76(2013):7482.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Liniger, H., Rima, M.S., Hauert, C., and Gurtner, M.. “Sustainable Land Management in Practice: Guidelines and Best Practices for Sub-Saharan Africa.” TerrAfrica, World Overview of Conservation Approaches and Technologies (WOCAT) and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO), 2011. Internet site: http://www.wocat.net/fileadmin/user_upload/documents/Books/SLM_in_Practice_E_Final_low.pdf Google Scholar
Lobell, D.B., Schlenker, W., and Costa-Roberts, J.. “Climate trends and global crop production since 1980.” Science 333,6042(2011):616620. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1204531 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lotz, L.A., van de Wiel, C., and Smulders, M.J.. “How to assure that farmers apply new technology according to good agricultural practice: lessons from Dutch initiatives.” Frontiers in Environmental Science 6(2018):89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Louviere, J., Hensher, D.A., and Swait, J.. Stated Choice Methods: Analysis and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luce, R.D. Individual Choice Behavior: A Theoretical Analysis. New York: Wiley, 1959.Google Scholar
Marley, A.A. and Louviere, J.J.. “Some probabilistic models of best, worst, and best-worst choices.” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 49,6(2005):464480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mccarl, B.A., Thayer, A.W., and Jones, J.P.. “The challenge of climate change adaptation for agriculture: An economically oriented review.” Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 48,4(2016):321344.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, D.Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior.” Frontiers in Econometrics. P. Zarembka, ed. New York: Academic Press, 1974, pp. 105–42.Google Scholar
Mutoko, MC. Adoption of climate-smart agricultural practices: Barriers, incentives, benefits and lessons learnt from the MICCA pilot site in Kenya. Rome: FAO, 2014.Google Scholar
NBS. Annual Abstract of Statistics. Nigerian Bureau of Statistics. Federal Republic of Nigeria, 2016.Google Scholar
Nigussie, Z, Tsunekawa, A, Haregeweyn, N, Adgo, E, Nohmi, M, Tsubo, M, Aklog, D, Meshesha, DT, and Abele, S.Factors influencing small-scale farmers’ adoption of sustainable land management technologies in north-western Ethiopia.” Land Use Policy 67(2017):5764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nwajiuba, C., Emmanuel, T.N. and Solomon, B.. State of Knowledge on CSA in Africa: Case Studies from Nigeria, Cameroun and the Democratic Republic of Congo. Forum for Agricultural Research in Africa, Accra, Ghana, 2015.Google Scholar
Nyasimi, M., Amwata, D., Hove, L., Kinyangi, J., and Wamukoya, G.. “Evidence of impact: Climate-smart agriculture in Africa.” CCAFS Working Paper no. 86. Copenhagen, Denmark: CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS), 2014. Internet site: http://ccafs.cgiar.org/publications/evidence-impact-climate-smart-agricultureafrica Google Scholar
Padfield, R., Papargyropoulou, E., and Preece, C.. “A preliminary assessment of greenhouse gas emission trends in the production and consumption of food in Malaysia.International Journal of Technology 3,(2012):5566. https://doi.org/10.14716/ijtech.v3i1.81 Google Scholar
Potoglou, D., Burge, P., Flynn, T., Netten, A., Malley, J., Forder, J., and Brazier, J.E.. “Best-worst scaling vs. discrete choice experiments: an empirical comparison using social care data.” Social Science and Medicine 72,(2011):17171727. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.socscimed.2011.03.027 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Punj, G.N., and Staelin, R.. “The choice process for graduate business schools.” Journal of Marketing Research 15(1978):588598.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roth, M., and McCarthy, N.. USAID Issue Brief: Land Tenure, Property Rights, and Economic Growth in Rural Areas, 2013.Google Scholar
Schulz, N., Breustedt, G., and Latacz-Lohmann, U.. “Assessing Farmers’ Willingness to Accept ‘Greening’: Insights from a Discrete Choice Experiment in Germany.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 65,1(2014):2648. https://doi.org/10.1111/1477-9552.12044 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shen, J.A review of stated choice method.” International Public Policy Studies 10,2(2006):97121.Google Scholar
Shittu, A.M., Kehinde, M.O., Ogunaike, M.G., and Oyawole, F.P.. “Effects of Land Tenure and Property Rights on Farm Households’ Willingness to Accept Incentives to Invest in Measures to Combat Land Degradation in Nigeria.Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 47,2(2018):357387. https://doi.org/10.1017/age.2018.14 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shittu, A.M. Final Report of the Project. Incentivising Adoption of Climate-smart Practices in Cereals Production in Nigeria: Socio-cultural and Economic Diagnosis, 2017.Google Scholar
Smith, P., Martino, D., Cai, Z., Gwary, D., Janzen, H., Kumar, P., and McCarl, B.. “Greenhouse Gas Mitigation in Agriculture.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 363,1492(2008):789813. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2007.2184 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Suleman, KK. “Upscaling Climate-Smart Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Southern African Institute of International Affairs Policy Insights 48, 2017.Google Scholar
Tenaw, S.K.M., Zahidul, I., and Tuulikki, P.. “Effects of Land tenure and Property rights on Agricultural Productivity in Ethiopia, Namibia and Bangladesh.” University of Helsinki Department of Economics and Management Discussion Papers no 33, Helsinki, 2009.Google Scholar
Ward, P.S., Ortega, D.L., Spielman, D.J., and Singh, V.. “Farmer Preferences for Drought Tolerance in Hybrid versus Inbred Rice Evidence from Bihar, India.” Environment and Production Technology Division. CGIAR Research Program on Policies, Institutions and Markets. International Food Policy Research Institute, 2013. IFPRI Discussion Paper 01307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wollenberg, E., Higman, S., Seeberg-Elverfeldt, C., Neely, C., Tapio-Biström, M.L., and Neufeldt, H.. Helping Smallholder Farmers Mitigate Climate Change. CCAFS Policy Brief no. 5. CGIAR Research Program on Climate Change, Agriculture and Food Security (CCAFS). Copenhagen, Denmark, 2012. Internet site: http://ccafs.cgiar.org/resources/reports-and-policy-briefs.Google Scholar
World Bank. Climate Smart Agriculture: A Call to Action. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2011. Internet site: http://www.worldbank.org/content/dam/Worldbank/document/CSA_Brochure_web_WB.pdf Google Scholar
World Bank Group and ECOFYS. Carbon Pricing Watch 2016. Washington, DC: World Bank, 2016. Internet site: https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/24288 Google Scholar
Zougmoré, R., Partey, S., Ouédraogo, M., Omitoyin, B., Thomas, T., Ayantunde, A., Ericksen, P., Said, M., and Jalloh, A.. “Toward Climate-smart Agriculture in West Africa: A Review of Climate Change Impacts, Adaptation Strategies and Policy Developments for the Livestock, Fishery and Crop Production Sectors.” Agriculture & Food Security 5,(2016):26. https://doi.org/10.1186/s40066-016-00753 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Attributes and levels of Climate-Smart Practices for smallholder farmers

Figure 1

Table 2. Typical tasks presented to respondents

Figure 2

Table 3. Definitions of study variables and their descriptive statistics

Figure 3

Table 4. Socioeconomic characteristics and percentage in the sample (n = 542)

Figure 4

Table 5. Distribution of cultivated parcels by title registration and tenure types

Figure 5

Table 6. Best–worst scores of the CSA attributes by intervention management

Figure 6

Table 7. Best–worst scores of the CSA attributes by mode of payment

Figure 7

Table 8. Estimated best–worst models results and Hausman Specification Test Results

Figure 8

Table 9. Willingness to accept (pay)1 incentives for a shift to CSA options