Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-mlc7c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T21:24:26.518Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Green by Choice? Cross-National Variations in Firms' Responses to EMS-Based Environmental Regimes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Kelly Kollman
Affiliation:
The George Washington University.
Aseem Prakash
Affiliation:
School of Business and Public Management, The George Washington University
Get access

Abstract

Environmental Management Systems (EMSS) represent a new generation of voluntary “beyond compliance” environmental policies that neither set substantive goals nor specify final outcomes. As a result, many stakeholder groups are lukewarm toward them. Since 1993 two major supranational EMSs—ISO 14001 and the European Union's Environmental Management and Audit Scheme (EMAS)—have been introduced. Firms receive formal accreditation after their EMS has been certified by outside verifiers. This accreditation can potentially bestow monetary and nonmonetary benefits on these firms.

Firm-level EMS adoption patterns in the United Kingdom, Germany, and the United States vary, thereby suggesting that national contexts influence firms' responses to them. In Germany and the U.K. a significant number of sites have become either ISO 14001 or EMAS certified, while the take-up of ISO 14001 in the U.S. (EMAS is available only to European sites) has been less enthusiastic.

This article begins with the hypothesis that firms in countries with adversarial economies— where regulators and business are on less than friendly terms—are less likely to adopt EMS-based programs. This hypothesis explains why ISO 14001 take-up has been relatively high in the U.K. and relatively low in the U.S. However, it cannot explain (1) the high rate of take-up of both ISO 14001 and EMAS in Germany, where the stringency of environmental legislation has been a contentious issue between the government and industry and (2) why EMAS has been more popular in Germany than in the U.K. This article argues that the original hypothesis, while largely correct, is underspecified. To better explain the cross-national differences in EMS adoption, one must take into account the type of adversarial economy (adversarial legalism versus prescriptive interventionism) and the nature of the policy regime (procedural versus substantive).

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 2001

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 For recent contributions to the private regimes literature, see Claire Cutler, A., Haufler, Virginia, and Porter, Tony, eds., Private Authority and International Affairs (Albany, N.Y.: SUNY Press, 1999)Google Scholar; Braithwaite, John and Drahos, Peter, Global Business Regulation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000).Google Scholar For a review of the beyond-compliance literature, see Prakash, Aseem, “Why Do Firms Adopt Beyond-Compliance Environmental Policies?” Business Strategy and the Environment (forthcoming)Google Scholar; and idem, Greening the Firm: The Politics of Corporate Environmentalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2000).

2 Rosenau, James N. and Czempiel, Ernst-Otto, eds., Governance without Government: Order and Change in World Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Prakash, Aseem and Hart, J., eds., Globalization and Governance (London: Routledge, 1999)Google Scholar; Young, Oran R., Governance in World Affairs (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1999).Google Scholar

3 Haas, Peter M., “Social Constructivism and the Evolution of Multilateral Environmental Governance,” in Prakash and Hart (fn. 2); Young (fn. 2).Google Scholar

4 Keck, Margaret E. and Sikkink, Kathryn, Activists beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International Politics (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1998).Google Scholar

5 For an explanation of the difference between these two globabalizations, see Falk, Richard, Predatory Globalization: A Critique (Oxford: Blackwell, 2000).Google Scholar

6 Gilpin has recently argued that global governance mechanisms will have to be strengthened if they are to keep pace with economic globalization. See Gilpin, Robert, The Challenge of Global Capitalism: The World Economy in the Twenty-first Century (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2000).Google Scholar

7 Krasner, Stephen, ed., International Regimes (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1983)Google Scholar; Rittberger, Volker, ed., Regime Theory and International Relations (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Young, Oran R., International Governance: Protecting the Environment in a Stateless Society (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1994).Google Scholar

8 Berger, Suzanne and Dore, Ronald, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1996)Google Scholar; Rosenau, James N., Along the Domestic-Foreign Frontier (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Prakash, Aseem and Hart, Jeffrey A., eds., Coping with Globalization (London: Routledge, 2000).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Exceptions include Victor, David, Raustiala, Kal, and Skolnikoff, Eugene, eds., The Implementation and Effectiveness of International Environmental Commitments: Theory and Practice (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1998)Google Scholar; Braithwaite and Drahos (fn. 1).

10 Young (fn. 2), 15.

11 Putnam, Robert D., “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games,” International Organization 42 (Summer 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Tsebelis, George, Nested Games: Rational Choice in Comparative Politics (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990)Google Scholar; Evans, Peter B., Jacobson, Harold K., and Putnam, Robert D., eds., Double-Edged Diplomacy (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1994).Google Scholar

12 Although political scientists have extensively studied the influence of business over government and policy outcomes, far less research has addressed the effects of government-industry relations on policy implementation. For an overview of this largely underdeveloped literature, see Wilks, Stephen and Wright, Maurice, eds., Comparative Government-Industry Relations: Western Europe, the United States, Japan (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1987)Google Scholar; Vogel, David, Kindred Strangers (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995)Google Scholar; Kagan, Robert and Axelrad, Lee, “Adversarial Legalism: An International Perspective,” in Nivola, Pietro S., ed., Comparative Disadvantages? Domestic Social Regulations and the Global Economy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1997)Google Scholar; Kagan, Robert, “Regulatory Enforcement,” in Rosenbloom, David H. and Schwartrz, Richard D., eds., Handbook of Regulation and Administrative Law (New York: Marcel Dekker, 1994)Google Scholar; Kagan, Robert, “Adversarial Legalism and American Government,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 10, no. 3 (1991).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Lehmbruch, Gerhard and Schmitter, Philippe C., eds., Patterns of Corporatist Policy-Making (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1982)Google Scholar; Katzenstein, Peter J., Policy and Politics in West Germany: The Growth of a Semi-Sovereign State (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1987)Google Scholar; idem, Industry and Politics in West Germany (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989).

14 Vogel, David, National Styles of Regulation: Environmental Policy in Great Britain and the United States (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; Kagan (fn. 12, 1991).

There is an extensive literature examining the nature and impact of adversarial relationships in other issue-areas: on labor unionization, see Flanagan, Robert J., Labor Relations and the Litigation Explosion (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1987)Google Scholar; on mine safety, see Braithwaite, John, To Punish or to Persuade: Enforcement of Coal Mine Safety (Albany, N.Y.: SUNY Press, 1985)Google Scholar; on corporate governance, see Charkham, Jonathan P., Keeping Good Company: A Study of Corporate Governance in Five Countries (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1994)Google Scholar; and on pharmaceuticals, see Teff, H., “Drug Approval in England and the United Sates,” American Journal of Comparative Law 33 (Fall 1985).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Bennett points out that convergence can occur at various levels: setting objectives, establishing systems, adopting technologies, and achieving outcomes. See Bennett, Colin J., “Review Article: What Is Policy Convergence and What Causes It?British Journal of Political Science 21 (April 1991).CrossRefGoogle Scholar EMS-based policies focus on convergence of management systems based on the assumption that if such systems are in place, firms will adopt technologies most suitable to them and improve their environmental performance over time.

For a critical examination of the convergence debate, see Berger and Dore (fn. 8); Boyer, Robert and Drache, Daniel, eds., State against Markets (London: Routledge, 1996)Google Scholar; Pauly, Louis W. and Reich, Simon, “National Structures and Multinational Corporate Behavior: Enduring Differences in the Age of Globalization,International Organization 51, no. 1 (1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Prakash, Aseem and Hart, Jeffrey A., eds., Responding to Globalization (London: Routledge, 2000).Google Scholar

16 World Commission on Environment and Development, Our Common Future (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987)Google Scholar; World Bank, World Development Report (NewYork: Oxford University Press, 1992)Google Scholar; Schmidhieny, Stephen, Changing Course (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1992).Google Scholar

17 Osborne, David E. and Gaebler, Ted, Reinventing Government: How the Entrepreneurial Spirit Is Transforming the Public Sector (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1992)Google Scholar; Kettl, Donald F. and Dilulio, John J. Jr, eds., Inside the Reinvention Machine: Appraising Governmental Reform (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 1995).Google Scholar

18 These tables measure take-up rates in absolute terms, as well as by the number of certified sites in relation to GDP. Because no comparable data exist on the total number of sites in these countries, we are unable to calculate the ideal comparative measure—the ratio of certified sites to total sites for each country. As such, we assume that GDP is a rough proxy for the total number of sites. We base this assumption on the fact that the U.S., U.K., and German economies have broadly similar structures. In comparing take-up rates of EMAS, which is only available to firms in manufacturing sectors, we also look at the share of manufacturing as percentage of GDP in the U.K. and Germany. In the U.K. manufacturing makes up 21 percent of GDP, while in Germany it makes up 24 percent, again showing that they are roughly similar. It should also be pointed out that we are not comparing the take-up rates of EMAS and ISO 14001 within countries but rather are comparing the take-up rate of each EMS separately across countries. As such we compare only like with like. Data are from World Bank, 1999/2000 World Development Report (New York: Oxford University Press, 2000), 252–53.Google Scholar

19 Buchanan, James A. and Tullock, GordonA Calculus of Consent (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1962)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Arrow, Kenneth J., Social Choice and Individual Values (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1963)Google Scholar; Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965).Google Scholar

20 The literature on this subject is vast. Key works, both supportive and nonsupportive of new institutionalism, include Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J., eds., The New lnstitutionalism in Organizational Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983)Google Scholar; Granovetter, Mark, “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,” American Journal of Sociology 91, no. 3 (1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Evans, Peter B., Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, and Skocpol, Theda, Bringing the State Back in (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Eggertsson, Thrainn, Economic Behavior and Institutions (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Furubotn, Eirik G. and Richter, Rudolf, eds., The New Institutional Economics (College Station: Texas A and M University Press, 1991)Google Scholar; Steimo, Sven, Thelan, Kathleen, and Longstredi, Frank, Structuring Politics (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kent Weaver, R. and Rockman, Bert A., eds., Do Institutions Matter? (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1993)Google Scholar; Peters, Guy B., Institutional Theory in Political Science (London: Pinter, 1999).Google Scholar

21 Ostrom, Elinor, “An Agenda for the Study of Institutions,” Public Choice 48 (1986).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

22 North, Douglas C., Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Ostrom, Elinor, Governing the Commons (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

23 North (fn. 22); Knight, Jack, Institutions and Social Conflict (Cambridge University Press, 1992).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

24 See, for example, Commons, John R., Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1961).Google Scholar

25 Hall, Peter, Governing the Economy: The Politics of Intervention in Great Britain and France (New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), 29.Google Scholar

26 March, James and Olsen, Johan, Rediscovering Institutions (New York: Free Press, 1989), 56.Google Scholar

27 On this subject, see the debate between Lake, and Sandholtz, : Lake, David A., “Global Governance: A Relation Contracting Approach,” in Prakash and Hart (fn. 2)Google Scholar; and Sandholtz, Wayne, “Globalization and the Evolution of Rules,” also in Prakash and Hart (fn. 2).Google Scholar

28 Ostrom, Elinor, “Rational Choice and Institutional Analysis: Toward Complementarity,“American Political Science Review 85 (March 1991).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29 For example, North (fn. 22); and Ostrom (fn. 22).

30 Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979)Google Scholar; Greico, Joseph, “Anarchy and the Limits to Cooperation,International Organization 42 (August 1988).Google Scholar For an overview of the neorealist-institutionalist debate, see Baldwin, David A., ed., Neorealism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York: Columbia University Press, 1993).Google Scholar

31 Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S., Power and Interdependence (Boston: Little and Brown, 1977).Google Scholar

32 Krasner (fn. 7), 2.

33 Young (fn. 2).

34 For example, Moravcsik, Andrew, “Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovemmentalist Approach,” Journal of Common Market Studies 31 (1993).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 For other works that look at the effects of domestic institutions on foreign policy decision making, see Katzenstein, Peter J., ed., Between Power and Plenty: Foreign Economic Policies of Advanced Industrial States (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1978)Google Scholar; Putnam (fn. 11); Gourevitch, Peter A., “Squaring the Circle: The Domestic Sources of International Cooperation,” International Organization 50 (Spring 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Raustiala, Kal, “Domestic Institutions and International Regulatory Cooperation: Comparative Responses to the Convention on Biological Diversity,World Politics 49 (July 1997).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

36 Berger and Dore (fn. 8); Evans, Peter, “The Eclipse of the State? Reflections on Stateness in an Era of Globalization,World Politics 50 (October 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kitschelt, Herbert, Lange, Peter, Marks, G., and Stephens, John D., eds., Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

37 Falk (fn. 5).

38 Other examples of supranational “beyond compliance” codes include the chemical industry's Responsible Care Program, the Valdez Principles, and the International Chamber of Commerce's Business Charter for Sustainable Development. For a theoretical discussion, see Prakash, Aseem, “Responsible Care: An Assessment,” Business and Society 39, no. 2 (2000).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

39 Commission of the European Communities, Towards Sustainability: A European Community Programme of Policy and Action in Relation to the Environment and Sustainable Development (COM(92)23 final, 1992).Google Scholar

40 The Environmental Council of Ministers is the intergovernmental body that consists of the environmental ministers of the fifteen member states and that is responsible for adopting all environmental legislation proposed by the commission. For reference, the first EMAS draft was published before the 5th EAP in 1991, but it changed a great deal after the publication of BS 7750 and the pilot program that preceded this.

41 Commission of the European Communities, Draft Proposal for a Council Regulation Establishing a Community Scheme for the Evaluation and Improvement of Environmental Performance in Certain Activities and the Provision of Relevant Information to the Public (Eco-Audit) (COM(91)XI/83, 1991).Google Scholar

42 Clapp, Jennifer, “The Privatization of Global Environmental Governance: ISO 14000 and the Developing World,” Global Governance 4, no. 3 (1998).Google Scholar

43 Hortensius, D. and Barthel, , “Beyond 14001,” in Sheldon, C., ed., ISO 14001 and Beyond (Sheffield, U.K.: Greenleaf Publishing, 1997).Google Scholar

44 Commission of the European Communities, Regulation on EMAS (EEC/1836/93, 1993). The European Union is in the process of adopting a revised EMAS II scheme that would use ISO 14001 as the management system part of the scheme. The European Parliament has also tried to add amendments to this proposal to introduce concrete performance standards such as more stringent BAT measures. No final draft has yet been decided upon. Thus the struggle both to harmonize EMAS with ISO 14001 and to strengthen the scheme goes on. For the latest version of EMAS II draft proposal, see Commission of the European Communities, Community Preparatory Acts, Document 599PC0313 (2000).Google Scholar

45 NSF International, International Environmental Management System Demonstration Project: Final Report (Ann Arbor, Mich.: NSF International, 1996).Google Scholar Procter and Gamble, however, estimates a higher figure: $100,000 per site. With 150 facilities worldwide, it would amount to $15 million for Procter and Gamble's worldwide operations. See Kolk, Ans, The Economics of Environmental Management (Essex: Prentice Hall/Financial Times, 2000).Google Scholar

46 For an overview of the stakeholder theory, see Clarkson, Max B. E., ed., The Corporation and Its Stakeholders (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1998).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47 For a review, see Bhagwati, Jagdish and Hudec, Robert E., eds., Fair Trade and Harmonization (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1996), vols. 1, 2.Google Scholar

48 “Responsible Care Earns Discount on EIL Premium,” Chemical Week (July 23, 1997), 11.

49 Walley, Noah and Whitehead, Bradley, “It's Not Easy Being Green,” Harvard Business Review (May-June 1994).Google Scholar For an opposing view, see Porter, Michael E. and van der Linde, C., “Towards a New Conception of Environment-Competitiveness Relationships,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9, no. 4 (1995).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

50 MNEs have facilities across countries. Pauly and Reich (fn. 15) Research suggests that the nationality of the parent firm continues to matter in many aspects of corporate governance. However, most MNEs try to implement nonmarket strategies, especially in terms of their relationship with regulators, that respond to the characteristics of the host country. In other words, MNEs' nonmarket strategies are multidomestic and not global; Baron, David P., Business and Its Environment (Upper Saddle River, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1999).Google Scholar This, of course, may prove problematic if the opposition to MNEs assumes a global rather than a local character—Seattle being a case in point. For a detailed discussion, see Prakash, Aseem, “Beyond Seattle: Globalization, the Non-Market Environment, and Business Strategy,” Working Paper no. 2000–03 (Department of Strategic Management and Public Policy, The George Washington University, Washington, D.C., 2000).Google Scholar

51 Lundqvist, Lennart, The Hare and the Tortoise: Clean Air Policies in the United States and Sweden (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1980).Google Scholar

52 Chandler, Alfred D., “Government versus Business: An American Phenomenon,” in Dunlop, John, ed., Business and Public Policy (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1980)Google Scholar; Marcus, Alfred A., The Adversary Economy (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books, 1984).Google Scholar

53 The adversarial economy coexists with numerous instances of “capture,” especially in relation to nonenvironmental issues; on “capture,” see Stigler, George, “The Economic Theory of Regulation,Bell Journal of Economics 2 (Spring 1971).Google Scholar Historically, regulatory agencies have also functioned as cartelenforcing bodies in industries such as trucking, railways, and airlines. Thus, as we argue subsequendy, the notion of adversarial economy needs better specification.

54 See Vogel (fn. 12); and Kagan (fn. 12, 1994, 1991).

55 Environmental Protection Agency/EPA, Oral History Interview 1, William K. Reilly, http://www.epa.gov/cgi-bin/claritgw, 1995 (retrieved November 17, 2000).

To illustrate further, in the recently decided Browner v. American Trucking and American Trucking v. Browner cases by the U.S. Supreme Court, the trucking industry challenged the EPA's authority to make rules under the Clean Air Act. In 1997 the EPA promulgated regulations on stricter ozone and particulate emission standards. A large number of business groups also filed friends-of-the-courts briefs arguing that such regulatory powers are not inconsonant with the nondelegation doctrine that requires that laws be made by the elective representatives only (the EPA being a nonelected body). Further, firms were outraged that the EPA promulgates regulations predominantly to achieve public health objectives, without doing adequate cost-benefit analysis. At a broader level, this case suggests that businesses are challenging the authority of all federal regulatory agencies and reinforcing the continuation of an adversary economy.

56 Müller, Edda, Innenwelt der Umweltpolitik: Sozial-liberal Umweltpolitik (Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 1986).Google Scholar

58 Weidner, Helmut, “Twenty-five Years of Modern Environmental Policy in Germany: Treading a Well-Worn Path to the Top of the International Field,” WZB Working Paper, FS II 95–301 (1995).Google Scholar

59 Urbach, M., “Konsens aus Koalitionsraeson,” Tageszeitung (June 6, 2000).Google Scholar

60 Vogel (fn. 14).

61 Boehmer-Christiansen, Sonja and Skea, Jim, Acid Politics: Environmental and Energy Policies in Britain and Germany (London: Belhaven Press, 1991)Google Scholar; Lowe, Philip and Goyder, Jane, Environmental Groups in Politics (London: Allen and Unwin, 1983).Google Scholar

62 Prakash, Aseem, “A New Institutionalist Perspective on ISO 14000 and Responsible Care,” Business Strategy and the Environment 8, no. 6 (1999).3.0.CO;2-H>CrossRefGoogle Scholar

63 Author interview with Martin Cheesborough, Environment Agency, July 14, 1998.

64 Author interview with Bernard Walsh, Department of Environment, Transport and the Regions, July 13, 1998.

65 For a more in-depth discussion of the effects of procedural versus substantive supranational policy regimes, see Kollman, Kelly, “The Globalization of German Environmental Policy” (Paper presented at the annual meeting of the German Studies Association, Atlanta, Ga., October 7–9, 1999).Google Scholar

66 For a detailed account of the negotiations that took place in the Council over EMAS, see Waskow, Siegfried, Betriebliches Umweltmangement (Heidelberg: C. F. Müller, 1997).Google Scholar

67 Author interview with Geoff Smith, Department of Trade and Industry, July 13, 1998, and Ruth Hillary, March 9, 1999.

68 Another interview with Bernard Walsh, July 13, 1998.

69 See Department of Environment, Transport and the Regions, Environmental Reporting: Getting Started (London: HMSO, 1999)Google Scholar; idem, Sustainable Development: Opportunities for Change and Sustainable Business (London: HMSO, 1998).

70 Waskow(fn. 66).

71 Kagan (fn. 12, 1994, 1991).

72 For an account of how American adversarial legalism negatively affected the U.S. government's desire/ability to ratify the Convention on Biological Diversity, see Raustiala (fn. 35).

73 Rose-Ackerman, Susan, Controlling Environmental Policy: The Limits of Public Law in Germany and the United States (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1995)Google Scholar; Weidner, Helmut, Basiselemente einer erfolgreichen Umweltpolitik (Berlin: WZB, 1995).Google Scholar

74 Katzenstein (fn. 13).

75 Müller (fn. 56); Weidner (fn. 58).

76 Prakash (fn. 1, 2000).

77 Levy, Keohane, and Haas, as well as Braithwaite and Drahos, conclude that environmental regimes that are strategically vague (similar to procedural regimes in this paper) provide governments with flexibility in implementing them and are therefore less likely to be opposed in the domestic political economy. See Levy, Marc A., Keohane, Robert O., and Haas, Peter M., “Improving the Effectiveness of International Environmental Institutions,” in Haas, , Keohane, , and Levy, , eds., Institutions for the Earth (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993), 14Google Scholar; and Braithwaite and Drahos (fn. 1), 295.

78 Soskice, David, “Divergent Production Patterns: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1980s and 1990s,” in Kitschelt, Lange, Marks, and Stephens (fn. 36).Google Scholar

79 Roht-Arriaza, Naomi, “Environmental Management Systems and Environmental Protection: Can ISO 14001 Be Useful within the Context of APEC?Journal of Environment and Development 6, no. 3 (1997).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

80 Putnam (fn. 11).