Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-7cvxr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T01:37:21.749Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Polygamy, the Commodification of Women, and Underdevelopment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 September 2021

Daniel Seligson*
Affiliation:
Independent Scholar
Anne E. C. McCants
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 77 Massachusetts Ave, Cambridge, MA 02139, USA
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Family systems shape social institutions, yet they are rarely considered in histories of economic development. In this article, we show that a suite of social conventions—such as age gaps at marriage, bride price, sequestration, and discrimination and violence against women—are overrepresented in polygamous societies as compared to monogamous societies. This dichotomy can be explained on the grounds that polygamy produces a chronic scarcity of marriageable females. We argue that this suite, which we call gamos and which we quantify by two different methods, has demonstrably significant consequences for social, institutional, and economic development.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of the Social Science History Association

Man is more powerful in body and mind than woman, and in the savage state he keeps her in a far more abject state of bondage than does the male of any other animal.

Charles Darwin, The Descent of Man

Introduction

Every human, indeed, every large primate, begins her or his integration into society at birth in the ecological niche defined by its mother, for it is there that we learn, by example, how to interact with others and whom to trust (Hrdy Reference Hrdy1999: 383ff). As such, family and household are elemental to any discipline concerned with the social world. Not surprisingly, the household is a critical unit of analysis in and across anthropology, demography, sociology, and family history. In contrast, economics and political science have given it considerably less attention, focusing instead on the individual actor/citizen and their interactions with the marketplace or the state. This scholarly divide is exacerbated by methodological differences. For instance, family history, with its concern for the particular experiences of households over the life course, leans toward case studies as is typical of the history discipline. Economic history, however, has moved increasingly into the orbit of economics, where it takes its primary task to be raising broad questions about long-term processes and the generalizable laws that govern them. These differences of both topic and approach limit the transfer of knowledge across the divide.

Where then is the family in economic history? Footnote 1 Douglass C. North, founder of the New Institutional Economics (NIE), argues that “institutions are the rules of the game,” and more specifically that institutions are humanly devised constraints that serve to reduce uncertainty and transaction costs, acting thereby to improve economic performance. Footnote 2 The NIE’s definition of institutions includes informal constraints, e.g., taboos, culture, and social norms, all of which are propagated from generation to generation through the family, though not exclusively so. Alongside these, the NIE also considers formal constraints, of which constitutions and codified property rights are prime examples. Thus, it might seem that the family is squarely in the analytical framework of the NIE, but that is not the case because the NIE has chosen to focus on formal constraints only. Footnote 3 According to Oliver Williamson, the NIE’s rules of the game are the formal constraints of polity, bureaucracy, and judiciary, for example (Williamson Reference Williamson2000: 597). He designated these L2, shorthand for Level 2. Informal constraints, designated L1, are synonymous with socially embedded conventions and are explicitly not the rules of the game. Footnote 4 The NIE has been unsuccessful in incorporating social convention, in which family values or structure might be implicated. North highlights the paradoxically pervasive influence of norms on the long-term performance of economies (North Reference North1991: 111), but neither he nor Williamson, who reiterates the point (Williamson Reference Williamson2000: 596), offers an explanation, nor to our knowledge does anyone else.

Another place the family appears in economic history is in the literature on the impact of gender inequality and the treatment of women in shaping economic outcomes. Yet, the focus of this literature is primarily one about equity rather than family systems per se. In particular the European Marriage Pattern (EMP) has been invoked as a harbinger of both gender equality and modern economic growth (Hajnal Reference Hajnal and Eversley1965; Hartman Reference Hartman2004). Scholars have disputed both the definition of the EMP and the mechanisms by which it might have affected various regions of Europe differently (Carmichael et al. Reference Carmichael, Alexandra, Jan Luiten and Tine De2016; De Moor & van Zanden Reference De Moor and Jan Luiten2010; Dennison & Ogilvie Reference Dennison and Sheilagh2014). However, we believe that the EMP debate, while important locally, has missed the most salient factor characterizing family systems in their global scope, that is, the dichotomy between polygamy and monogamy.

Formally, polygamy may mean either male plural marriage, polygyny, or female plural marriage, polyandry, or even some combination thereof, but in practice, there is very little ambiguity. Polyandry is practiced in societies whose members comprise less than 2 percent of the global population, and only in polygynous societies (Becker Reference Becker1981: 102; Trevithick Reference Trevithick1997). In the Muslim world, which comprises a fifth of the world’s population and more than a third of the population in societies where polygamy is practiced, there is no ambiguity. Muslim women have no right to marry more than one man, so polygamy is identical to polygyny. In China, where polygamy was legal until 1950, its Mandarin pictogram 夫多妻 translates to “man bigger than sky with lots of wives.” The term polygyny is rarely used outside some academic disciplines, whereas polygamy, conveying the same meaning, is standard usage for economists and political scientists writing for academic and popular journals, for example, Politico and The Economist. It is also the preferred usage of policy makers, for instance at the United Nations, and it is the term of art in the English language press of Kenya, Nigeria, Ghana, and South Africa, to name a few examples. In this article, we use polygamy, polygyny, and male plural marriage synonymously, as does Fenske explicitly (Reference Fenske2015: 58) and as do others implicitly.

Monogamy, the root of the EMP, is so overwhelmingly the norm in the West that the aforementioned studies do not even consider its alternative. To many Westerners that alternative is infidelity (Perel Reference Perel2006). However, infidelity is no more a marriage system than is divorce. The alternative marriage system is polygamy, and we will show that insofar as socioeconomic impact is concerned, male plural marriage, which is synonymous with the term polygamy as used here, bears an outsized influence. Globally, societies that tolerate or promote male plural marriage are more numerous than monogamous ones, and the social dynamics of polygamous households impinge more on their monogamous neighbors than the other way around. On that topic, Laura Betzig’s Reference Betzig1986 Despotism and Differential Reproduction was pioneering. Tacitly accepting that polygamy has conferred (over anthropological times scales) and does confer (contemporaneously) differential reproductive success, she argues that autocratic governance and polygamy are inextricably intertwined. More recently, Alean Al-Krenawi (Reference Al-Krenawi2014) describes an ensemble of adverse effects of polygamy that bear on all members of polygamous households, and Rose McDermott (Reference McDermott2018) documents the widespread harm inflicted beyond the polygamous family. Bare Branches, a study of high-sex-ratio societies—which are superficially similar to polygamous ones—illuminates how sex-selective infanticide and abortion, and unequal access to resources contribute to crime and social instability (Hudson and den Boer Reference Hudson and Andrea2005). Footnote 5 Finally, Michele Tertilt (Reference Tertilt2005) observes that bride price, a practice that is all but unique to polygamous societies and consists of a transfer of assets from the groom’s family to the bride’s father, creates market incentives that elevate fertility and contribute to poverty. Her work stands alone, since that of Becker (Reference Becker1973), for its theorizing on the subject of male plural marriage and economic outcomes.

Though polygamy is very widespread, as we will show in the first of the sections that follow, it is remarkable how little work has quantitatively evaluated polygamy as a factor in shaping social and political institutions or studied its impact on long-term economic development. Our goal in this article is to address this shortcoming. In particular we explore how polygamy gives rise to social conventions, a term we use interchangeably with norms, that are either absent altogether or much diminished in monogamous society; we develop new measures to quantify them; and we use a multivariate causal model to show that polygamy, through the action of its conventions, has profoundly influenced the social, institutional, and economic development of nations. As a measure of that development, we augment the UN Human Development Index (HDI) with an additional component of governance per Amartya Sen’s Development as Freedom (Reference Sen2000).

Where Is Polygamy in the World?

The most comprehensive global survey of contemporary polygamy is Rose McDermott’s (Reference McDermott2010). Combining assessments of laws, practices, and w, a measure of plural marriage prevalence, McDermott codes each of 176 nations on an integer scale between 0 and 4 (see figure 1A). Footnote 6 Though a distinction on the basis of customary or religious law would seem at first glance to have no more or less gravitas than one made on the basis of national law, the histogram in figure 1B suggests that the former is weightier. We observe that the distribution of states is bimodal, cleaving along the line of legality in customary or religious law. This separates 4.1 billion people in 93 ${\cal P}$ -states where polygamy is legal under such law from 3.3 billion people in 83 ${\cal nP}$ -states where it is not.

Figure 1. McDermott’s polygamy scale: (A) tabulation and (B) histogram. Notes: 1A: (a) Multiple cohabitations: <2 percent; (b) multiple cohabitations: >2 percent; (c) only applies to select minorities and/or within enclaves; (d) w is the fraction, specified in percent, of women in plural marriages; and (e) no US agency compiles statistics on covert polygamous marriages. One source has reported, without documentation, that 50,000 to 100,000 Muslims live in polygamous households (Hagerty Reference Hagerty2008). Another says, also without documentation, that 50,000 to 100,000 Black Muslims live in polygamous relationships (Al-Krenawi Reference Al-Krenawi2014). From these it seems fair to estimate that no more than 0.1 percent of American marriages are polygamous. In figure 1B, the vertical axis label (#) signifies the number of states in each classification category. The world according to McDermott’s coding scheme is evidently bimodal, cleaving along the line of customary and religious law’s view of polygamy.

We begin by focusing on polygamy’s molding of social convention. Following the lead of philosopher and social theorist David Lewis, we understand convention to be a normative behavior—that is one accompanied by could, would, or should—that is adhered to by almost all members of society (Reference Lewis1969). The requirement of near-universal adherence, in conjunction with the fact that human socialization begins in infancy and is well-established by adolescence, suggests that convention may change only on a timescale of generations. That being the case, whatever the convention is today, it is the consequence of events and practices that transpired long ago. While laws—customary, religious, or national—likely reflect convention, contemporary law cannot itself be the source of contemporary convention. The twentieth century’s roiling social upheavals were often accompanied by new or unfamiliar legal systems. We can expect, therefore, that contemporary law is out of step with convention in some states. As a predictor of contemporary convention, the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}\;$ classification based on contemporary customary and religious law is likely to be inferior to such a classification made on the basis of customary and religious law in 1900. This warrants some changes to the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ classification we have just made on the basis of contemporary law per McDermott’s Polygyny Scale. We describe these changes in the following five paragraphs.

Polygamy was legal under customary law as recently as 1999 in Azerbaijan, 1990 in Laos, 2015 in Myanmar, and 1956 in Tunisia. Though they are classified as ${\cal nP}$ in the McDermott coding, we designate them ${\cal P}$ . China is reportedly free of polygamy today though it was prevalent there from the ancient past until the time of Mao (Lee and Feng Reference Lee and Wang2001; Zurndorfer Reference Zurndorfer and Kam2016). Consequently, China is ${\cal P}$ , and so too is Mongolia, which only won its independence from China in 1921.

On the other hand, McDermott classifies Singapore as 2, and therefore ${\cal P}$ in our system. But it was a small British colony in 1900 whose nearly hundredfold population growth in the intervening years qualifies it, in our view, as a new country whose norms are not typical of other ${\cal P}$ -states. For this reason, we classify Singapore as ${\cal nP}$ .

We must classify the Muslim-majority Balkans (Albania and Kosovo) as ${\cal P}$ , and also Bosnia and Macedonia where Muslims comprise about 40 percent of the population. Footnote 7 Finally, Fiji is a McDermott 0, though its long tradition of Chiefly Polygamy, irrespective of contemporary law, makes it ${\cal P}$ (Luker Reference Luker2015).

In the Muslim-majority Russian Republic of Chechnya, civil law prohibiting polygamy gives way to customary law permitting it (Tetrault-Farber Reference Tetrault-Farber2015). Footnote 8 In McDermott’s system, Russia is a 2 and therefore ${\cal P}$ . But Russia is historically Orthodox, and Christendom has been monogamous since its earliest days under Roman rule where polygamy was at first not-normative and then later a crime (Witte Reference Witte2015: 104–14). The overwhelmingly dominant convention in Russia is thus monogamy. We classify it as ${\cal nP}$ .

In the Americas, Belize, Suriname, and Haiti are the only states that have laws, customary or civil, that permit or at least tolerate polygamy, and are thus ${\cal P}$ . By contrast, Guyana is a McDermott 0, but UNICEF reports that the plural marriage fraction there is 4 percent (2014). Footnote 9 Accordingly, Guyana belongs among the ${\cal P}$ -states. Footnote 10

By this revised coding, approximately 5.5 billion people live under the influence of ${\cal P}$ and 2.0 billion live without such influence in ${\cal nP}$ . The global distribution of our revised ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ is shown in map 1, and a complete list is provided in the appendix. Footnote 11

Map 1. World map of 102 ${\cal P}$ -states (in gray) and 75 ${\cal nP}$ -states (in white).

The Social Conventions of Polygamous Society

Polygamy is an asymmetric marriage contract—formal or informal, secular or religious, legal or illegal—that deprives the bride of the right of further marriage while preserving that right for the groom. Even in societies where it is permitted, generally fewer than one in three married men are polygamous, and more typically, fewer than one in ten. Footnote 12 Though seemingly rare, the mere possibility of such asymmetric two-party contracts requires the tacit approval of most members of the community and supporting institutions that extend far beyond the sphere of the parties. Social conventions consistent with those contracts and their institutions will affect almost everyone within the sphere of permission. The driving mechanisms of polygamous convention and their consequences are the subject of this section.

In the 1710 edition of Transactions of the Royal Society, the world’s first scientific journal, Dr. John Arbuthnot (Reference Arbuthnot1710: 186–90) reported on the relative birth rates of girls and boys, finding them approximately equal, a conclusion supported by contemporary data as shown in figure 2. He also noted that, “where Males and Females are in equal number, if one man takes twenty wives, nineteen must live in celibacy, which is repugnant to the design of Nature.” He would have had no firsthand experience of polygamy in European society, though he would have known polygamy was common in Africa, and he might also have known something about its prevalence in the Near East, as did his contemporary Montesquieu (2008 [1721]), or in the Far East, as had been reported by Marco Polo in the thirteenth century (Reference Polo1958: Book 1, Chapter 52). He may be forgiven, then, his inference about celibacy, which is strictly correct only if marriage is restricted to parties of the same age. But his demography is sound and it bears heavily on polygamy. So long as men may take more than one wife, and women may not do the same, and so long as the male-to-female sex ratio at the age of puberty is not much less than unity—a condition that is satisfied everywhere—then polygamy creates a chronic scarcity of marriageable females.

Figure 2. Male-to-female sex ratios for 177 nations. Notes: (A) Sex ratios in the first four years of life and (B) sex ratios in the first decade after puberty. Means and medians for both age groups are about 1.05. Population weighted means are larger by about 0.03 owing to sex ratios greater than 1.12 in China and India. Five states—Qatar, UAE, Bahrain, Maldives, and Kuwait—have sex ratios after puberty exceeding 1.2, a fact that may be attributed to a preference for males in their immigrant workforces.

Being that scarcity is at the root of economic behavior, the economist’s imagination is not tested by the proposition that women in polygamous society are traded like any other commodity. Nor is it tested by the proposition that the chronic scarcity influences economic outcomes in polygamous society relative to monogamous societies that do not face that particular scarcity. Whether that differential is large or small, or positive or negative remains to be determined. In this section we elucidate how a chronic scarcity of marriageable females molds social convention and promotes the commodification of all women.

When a community is struck by famine or drought, historical experience shows that those with access to scarce essentials often hoard them and those who don’t have access either maraud for them or suffer. To the extent possible or desirable, state and private institutions distribute the necessities from stockpiles to ameliorate the suffering and to protect the interests of the politically powerful. If scarcity and suffering mount, the afflicted grow more restive, flee, or even die. Where redistribution fails to quell civil disturbances, state and private militias may do so. But such scarcities often originate in the weather, and like the weather they pass, first coming and then going. As with recollections of a great blizzard, the transient scarcity fades, and it does so without engendering materially permanent behavioral change for almost all members of the group, which is requisite for our definition of convention.

Chronic scarcity is altogether different. It does not come and go like the weather. It comes and stays on a timescale of centuries, like climate. Within a few generations, no living person can recall the world before the scarcity took hold. Footnote 13 If the scarcity does not pose an existential threat, or if alternatives can be found to alleviate the most dire of its consequences, then conventions adjust to the new normal and the old cultural system passes into legend.

Marriageable women are not like food or water; a man in search of a wife will not die in weeks for lack of a mate. However, the reproductive instinct is intrinsic to all life, leading us to expect that the logic of the market will apply where marriageable women are scarce, as they are wherever polygamy is permitted. In the following, we identify 11 different conventions that we hypothesize will be overrepresented in polygamous society. Because other factors independent of polygamy may give rise to these same conventions in nonpolygamous society, we do not expect that these conventions are necessarily absent there. We do, however, expect that they will be less prevalent there.

First, where marriageable women are a scarce commodity, we expect that they will be more highly valued in the marriage market, and that families with daughters will approve their marriage only for a price. Unlike dowry, which is a transfer of assets from the bride’s family to the married couple, bride price is a transfer of assets from the groom or the groom’s family to the bride’s family. Typically, these accrue to her father. Valerie Hudson (Reference Hudson2016) has developed an 11-point grading system for the full range of at-marriage wealth transfers: 0 signifies that neither dowry nor bride price is common; 1 to 5 signifies a range of dowry conventions; and 6 to 10 signifies a range of bride price conventions. By her design, circumstances for women are less favorable as the index value increases. We divide her sample of 173 states into groups according to the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ classification. By visual inspection, the distributions of wealth transfer conventions within ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ , figures 3A and 3B, respectively, are so dissimilar as to be distinct. Furthermore, bride price, we observe, is a practice all but unique to polygamous society. Footnote 14

Figure 3. Hudson’s index of wealth transfers at marriage. Notes: (A) The distribution of wealth transfers at marriage per Hudson’s index in 73 ${\cal nP}$ states. (B) The distribution of wealth transfers at marriage per Hudson’s index in 100 ${\cal P}$ states. (C) The cumulative distribution functions of the ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions. The maximum difference, $\delta $ , of these is approximately 0.9, generating a vanishingly small p ks , from which we conclude that the distributions are distinct, as expected.

As a quantitative diagnostic of similarity between two distributions, economists have long employed the Kolmogorov–Smirnov or KS test (Dagum Reference Dagum1980). It hinges on the observation that two distributions are similar only if their cumulative distribution functions (CDF) differ by at most a small amount, $\delta $ . The KS test generates an estimate of the probability that two distributions are the same. That probability, ${p_{KS}}$ , is exponential in the term $ - {\cal N}{\delta ^2}$ , where ${\cal N}\;$ is of the order of the number of elements in the smaller of the two distributions. ${p_{KS}}$ is therefore nonnegligible only if $\delta \le 1/\surd {\cal N}$ . In the case at hand, ${\cal N} \cong 70$ , so ${p_{KS}}$ is nonnegligible only if $\delta \le 0.12$ . The CDFs of ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions of at-marriage wealth transfers are shown in figure 3C. The corresponding $\delta \cong 0.9$ , so ${p_{KS}}$ is vanishingly small. We conclude, therefore, that the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ dichotomy gives rise, in the case of wealth transfers at marriage, to distinctly different conventions, as we hypothesized.

We claim, if contentiously, that polygamy causes, or is one of the causes of the convention we call bride price, or ${\cal P} \rightarrow B$ in the notation of causal inference theory (Pearl and McKenzie Reference Pearl and Dana2018: 128ff). By this we mean that (1) there exists a mechanism by which ${\cal P}$ effects B ; (2) ${\cal P}$ is highly correlated with B ; (3) ${\cal P}$ precedes B ; and (4) there is no confounding factor Z that induces changes to both ${\cal P}$ and B . Having already demonstrated (1) and (2), we proceed to investigate (3) and (4).

In The Histories of Herodotus (fifth century BCE) polygamy was present throughout Eurasia and Africa, though it was absent in Athens and possibly other Greek city-states. This absence is consistent with Diane Hughes’s assessment of the absence of bride price in the same sources (Reference Hughes1978: 262–63). Polygamy was present, too, among the Greeks in The Iliad, as well as documented in eighth-century BCE China (Golden Reference Golden2002: 49). Thus, polygamy was present everywhere in the historical record at least 2,700 years before the present. Footnote 15 If a nonpolygamous society existed before that time, it left no record and its impact on marriage structure was transient. Society emerged in the presence of preexisting polygamy. Footnote 16 It follows that the polygamy-born scarcity of marriageable females was a fact on the ground for emergent society to manage, just as it had to manage scarcities of food, water, and shelter. The solutions to those management challenges are social conventions, bride price being one example. The temporal or chronological primacy of ${\cal P}$ relative to all convention rules out the existence of a conventional confounder Z that causes B . Regarding the existence of a natural confounder, that is, one born of climate or geography, the latter is ruled out because geography is a constant over the Holocene. We rule out climate as a confounder because polygamy was everywhere, irrespective of climate, by the earliest evidence.

The evidence of mechanism, correlation, and chronology, and the absence of evidence of confounders, all point to polygamy being the cause of bride price. Footnote 17 Variations on these arguments apply for the other 10 conventions described in the following text. Footnote 18 Table 1 summarizes the descriptive statistics of the 11 conventions we discuss in this article. We refer to these by name or by line item, for example #1 in lieu of bride price.

Table 1. Eleven social conventions and descriptive statistics of their distributions in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$

Note: Data tables and their sources are provided in the supplementary appendix.

Just as the market translates the scarcity of marriageable females into the custom of bride price, the same scarcity will, we expect, drive up birthrates and increase the age gap at first marriage as well. The former increases the supply of a valuable commodity and the latter is a form of product substitution, from same-age mates to ever younger girls. Footnote 19 Tertilt asks how it is possible that more than one in three marriages are polygynous given that the sex ratios in most countries do not deviate much from one, and then explains that the resolution lies in “extremely high spousal age gaps coupled with high population growth” (Tertilt Reference Tertilt2005: 1346). Both practices bear economic costs as well. Tertilt further argues that the practice of buying wives and selling daughters in sub-Saharan Africa is explicitly market driven. Though locally and immediately optimal, it has longer-term negative consequences for economic development. She estimates that banning polygamy could decrease fertility by 40 percent, increase savings by 70 percent, and increase output per capita by 170 percent (Tertilt Reference Tertilt2005: 1343). Footnote 20

The mechanism driving the age gap at marriage has three elements. First, when confronted by scarcity in the marriage market, some men will resort to marrying a prepubescent girl. This may be understood as a form of product substitution in a thin market. Second, as it is in the financial interest of the bride’s father to encourage such a marriage, he does. Third, because bride price is a financial barrier, a man must delay marriage until such time as he has amassed the necessary capital to overcome it. These factors work together to increase the age gap at first marriage.

Consistent with Tertilt’s work on sub-Saharan Africa, lines #2 and #3 in Table 1 bear out the predictions for both birthrates and marital age gaps. Birthrates are nearly twice as high in ${\cal P}$ as in ${\cal nP}$ -states, and age gaps at marriage are greater in ${\cal P}$ by 1.6 years, exceeding by more than 50 percent the age gap in ${\cal nP}$ . Footnote 21 We recognize that the relationship between social customs and economic behavior is complex, and that the mechanisms identified here are not the only ones at work. However, for our purposes, the mechanisms previously described correctly predict the observed sign of the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ differentials, and that is all that is necessary for our argument.

Polygamy’s bride price culture informs us that women are highly valued in ${\cal P}$ but that their value accrues to older males. Footnote 22 We can expect, therefore, that other social conventions will reinforce the male grip on power (a not unreasonable understanding of patriarchy) and that such conventions, like the three just identified, will be differentially represented in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ . First consider patrilocality, wherein the bride relocates to the home of her new husband’s family. Hrdy writes that “female autonomy depends on the availability of support from her kin” (Reference Hrdy1999: 102). The convention of patrilocality decouples a young bride from that support and subordinates her to the groom and his family. This is especially so given the notably early age at which women marry in ${\cal P}$ , and even more so in higher-order plural marriages where the age gap may amount to decades. Line item #4 in Table 1 makes evident that patrilocality predominates in ${\cal P}$ .

Second, property and landownership laws and practice in ${\cal P}$ -states discriminate against women to a demonstrably greater extent than in ${\cal nP}$ -states, as affirmed by #5 in Table 1. Property rights are recognized by most scholars as a critical component of economic development. Thus the two-tier system puts women at a further disadvantage in society. Polygamy-born scarcity increases the value of women, and discriminatory property rights enables men to retain for themselves the value of those women they possess, whether “possess” has figurative or literal meaning.

In a related but somewhat different vein, it is a well-observed fact that scarce commodities are hoarded and that they must be safeguarded against marauding and decay. In his classic work on the economics of shortage among socialist firms, Janos Kornai argues that chronic scarcity leads to hoarding and “an almost-insatiable demand” for the scarce commodity (Kornai Reference Kornai1980: 102). The demand for women in ${\cal P}$ is not merely almost insatiable, it is actually insatiable because women are both the scarce commodity and the means of its production through their fertility.

Given that polygamous societies have too few women, and given the logistical challenges of raiding at a distance, we hypothesize that polygamous societies raid near-neighbors to acquire females. Tribalism is a source of otherization that justifies warring behavior. Raiding has two other ends: (1) fungible material booty serves to improve a man’s position in his community and consequently his marriage prospects; and (2) for every man who dies raiding, the odds of reproductive success increase for the survivors. Work by evolutionary biologists Luke Glowacki and Richard Wrangham (Reference Glowacki and Richard2015) supports this expectation. Similarly, Robert Tignor’s Reference Tignor1972 study of violence among the Maasai in Kenya and Tanzania emphasizes the centrality of raiding to wealth-building, noting that it is a prerequisite to marriage and admission to the circle of elders. Also, the surge in raiding that is associated with the start of the Viking Age was one consequence of polygyny and concubinage in the Late Iron Age (Raffield et al. Reference Raffield, Price and Collard2017: 316). Wealth is inseparable from marriage, and both are a means to enfranchisement because it is only the elders who hold authority in community decision making. Anthropologists and ethnographers know these patterns well. Footnote 23

No less so than any other scarce commodity, a man’s wives, daughters, sisters, and mothers are safe from predation only when isolated from marauders. Men cannot be trusted, at least insofar as women are concerned. Footnote 24 It is predictably prudent, therefore, that men will isolate their assets behind walls, and that when necessity dictates that these assets mingle in public, men will act to ensure their safety by shielding them from view beneath formless dress or behind veils, and will demand that they be accompanied by trusted guardians. Line item #6 in Table 1 confirms that a woman’s right to intermingle in public is substantially different in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ , being relatively abridged in the former, as predicted.

Stratification of males and the accompanying rites-of-passage rituals are well documented in polygamous tribal society, for example, the Maasai (Osborn Reference Osborn1996: 114). Footnote 25 When tribal society is subsumed into larger civil society where intertribal raiding is prohibited by formal law, the scarcity of marriageable females that motivated raiding remains in place so long as polygamy is practiced. The disenfranchised male may seek his enfranchisement by contravening civil society’s strictures against violence when he perceives that violence is the sole available means to that end. That such males are largely in the 19 to 34 age group that is infamously responsible for the vast majority of violent crime only makes such rebellion more likely (Farrington Reference Farrington1986). Footnote 26 Chronic scarcity is thus suggestive of chronic violence. The latter could be countered in two ways. One, the sequestration of women, overrepresented in ${\cal P}$ , addresses the specific threat of kidnap, rape, or murder. The second is, we predict, harsh justice. Footnote 27

Consider the death penalty as an indicator of a harsh judicial system. There are, per Amnesty International (2012), 75 states that impose harsh justice in this sense, and 98 that do not. Amnesty catalogs formal issuances of the state, but not informally issued death sentences such as honor killing and femicide carried out by the dishonored family. Footnote 28 Of Amnesty’s 98 abolitionist states, honor killings and femicides are “either ignored or generally accepted” in 26 of them (Womanstats 2020). Employing a definition of capital punishment that includes both formal and informal channels, we find that 80 of 101 ${\cal P}$ -states and 21 of 72 ${\cal nP}$ -states practice harsh justice. In this binary accounting, capital punishment is dominant in ${\cal P}$ as we hypothesized (see #7 in Table 1).

Honor killing and femicide are the terminal point on a gray scale of violence against women. Checks on such violence in general are, we expect, few in ${\cal P}$ , where the male’s sense of ownership of the women in his household is reinforced by patrilocality, discriminatory property rights, and the other factors discussed thus far. This is borne out in #8, which employs a 5-point scale to characterize the physical security of women (Womanstats 2020). On the low end, in states graded 0, an ideal achieved nowhere on Earth, there are laws against domestic violence, rape, and marital rape, these laws are enforced, and there are no taboos against reporting them. On the high end, in states graded 4, there are weak, rarely enforced laws against rape, and all other sex is presumed to be consensual. An example of a weak law is one that confines the definition of rape to sex with a girl under the age of 12.

We now turn to female genital mutilation or cutting, fgm/c, arguing that this practice restricts a woman’s freedom of movement by virtue of intimidation, thereby reinforcing male power. As such, it is yet another sequestration convention, and we expect to find it overexpressed in ${\cal P}$ . Footnote 29 Convergent evolution might well yield identical conventions from independent sources, and indeed the United Nations, the World Health Organization, the World Bank, the International Center for Research on Women, Human Rights Watch, and others are at pains to find what unifies the practice of fgm/c across Islamic, Christian, and animist communities; in Jewish communities in Ethiopia (Belmaker Reference Belmaker2012); in areas as geographically separated as West Africa and the Philippines; in countries both in and out of the tropics; and in countries above and below global means of income. We identify confirmed fgm/c states (N = 38) as those meeting either of the following two criteria: UNICEF reports greater than 1 percent prevalence of fgm/c among women of ages 15 to 49, or McDermott reports a prevalence of greater than 25 percent (McDermott Reference McDermott2007; UNICEF 2016). One hundred percent of so-confirmed fgm/c states are ${\cal P}$ . We identify a second or provisional category (N = 11) based on reporting by the Orchid Project or credible news sources (Orchid Project 2020). Of these 11 states, 100 percent are also in ${\cal P}$ . See #9 in Table 1. By reason of parsimony, the 100 percent congruence of ${\cal P}$ and fgm/c favors polygamy (over convergent evolution) as its single dominant cause.

As noted, fgm/c is in decline, and some states that practiced it in the twentieth century have eliminated it in the twenty-first century. If a multitude of those former fgm/c states are ${\cal nP}$ , then that would at least dent, and possibly invalidate, the argument we have made. Though there is no comprehensive study of this matter, we know of no evidence that would suggest that there was even one such case. By contrast, the aforementioned data suggests that some ${\cal P}$ states have cut back on their fgm/c practices between 2007 and today, with the Democratic Republic of Congo, Jordan, Kazakhstan, and Sri Lanka, having materially eradicated it. The fact that Israel, an ${\cal nP}$ -state, was an fgm/c-state as recently as 1995 confirms rather than disproves the rule, as the subpopulation within Israel that practiced fgm/c was a Bedouin one in which the plural fraction of all marriages is between 20 percent and 36 percent (Abu Rabia Reference Abu Rabia2011).

Consider now the educational opportunities for girls and young women in ${\cal P}$ . Fathers in ${\cal P}$ will (by convention) collect a bride price for their daughters upon marriage, leading us to expect that the investments in daughters are calculated to maximize financial return. Given that (by convention) girls in ${\cal P}$ marry relatively early and bear relatively many children, we hypothesize that they receive relatively little education. To test this, we assess the difference in male and female education measured in years, normalize that difference to male education in years, and compare the distributions in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ . Footnote 30 Line item #10 of Table 1 informs us that the distributions are well separated, confirming this hypothesis.

The 11th and final convention we examine is antidemocratic or authoritarian governance. The relationship between marriage law and democracy has a history as long as that of democracy. Classicists Susan Lape (Reference Lape2002) and Walter Scheidel (Reference Scheidel2009) emphasize that aspects of marriage and inheritance law in Solon’s sixth-century BCE reforms were decisive in the establishment of Athenian democracy. Specifically, the reforms denied inheritance to children of all but the first wife in plural marriages. Noble families that had used plural marriage to concentrate wealth and power were thus denied that mechanism of accumulation. Furthermore, the reforms expanded enfranchisement by linking it to income rather than wealth, thereby favoring the commercial classes at the expense of the nobility. Footnote 31 By the time of the Persian War a century later, the evidence suggests that the city-states had left polygamy behind. Herodotus makes no mention of it among either Athenians or Spartans. Footnote 32 Emphasizing the importance of this transition, Scheidel writes, “Greco-Roman emphasis on ‘Socially Imposed Universal Monogamy’ deserves pride of place in a world history of monogamy that has yet to be written” (Scheidel Reference Scheidel2009: 289).

Despotism is the ultimate in disenfranchisement because it is a system of governance in which only the voice of the autocrat matters. The linkage between disenfranchisement and polygamy is well documented by Betzig (Reference Betzig1986). It is therefore reasonable to expect that democratic impulses toward greater enfranchisement will be suppressed in a polygamous society. Compounding this is the tendency in ${\cal P}$ toward violence as a response to scarcity, a tendency that we also expect is more readily countered by autocratic than democratic regimes. Footnote 33

Through the lens of our ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ binary, we look at two independently gathered though highly correlated (r = 0.94) measures of democratic institutions: one an annual ranking from The Economist and the other from Freedom House (both 2016). In both cases, the ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions are well separated, supporting the hypothesis that authoritarian governance is overrepresented in ${\cal P}$ . We report the results from Freedom House, because of its greater global coverage, in #11. These 11 indicators of convention form the basis of the analysis that follows.

Gamos: A Unified Measure of Polygamous Conventions

It is a fact that polygamy generates a scarcity of marriageable females, and it is our hypothesis that this scarcity gives rise to normative behaviors or conventions that contribute in turn to social and economic outcomes. The 11 distinct indicators we review in the preceding text are indicative of those dichotomous social outcomes. The descriptions of the 11 behavioral conventions serve to illuminate their scope, but for the purposes of modeling we seek a more compact representation of the collective effect.

Each of the conventions follows the same pattern of separation into distinct ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions, and they are highly correlated as well. Footnote 34 Yet, across different societies the individual conventions are manifest to different extents, so no single one of them stands out as the natural or obvious representative for them all. Together they constitute a suite, a set that is incomplete without all its elements. Principal components analysis (PCA) affords us a means to achieve the compact representation of 11 conventions as a single variable.

Returning to the 11 conventions in Table 1, PCA tells us that the first principal component explains 55 percent of the variance of the full suite. This one component is a good, compact representation for quantitative analysis. We will call it gamos owing to its origin in behaviors linked to marriage patterns, and we denote it g S , where the subscript signifies that we obtained this measure from the suite. In figure 4, we show that the CDFs of the ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions of g S are well separated, as we expect. The vanishingly small ${p_{KS}} = 3 \times {10^{ - 29}}$ confirms that they are distinct.

Figure 4. The cumulative distribution functions of ${\cal P}$ (to the right) and ${\cal nP}$ (to the left) distributions of gS . Notes: Within the ${\cal nP}$ distribution, we identify members of the EMP (black) and non-EMP (gray) subgroups. Though those two subgroups are themselves distinct, the distinction is modest compared to that between ${\cal P}$ and $\;{\cal nP}$ as a whole.

The behaviors assayed by g S originate in polygamy, though no measure of polygamy is in the data sets that comprise it. Footnote 35 It is, therefore, an indirect measure of the phenomenon that we seek to evaluate. As such, polygamy may not be the only source of those conventions. Were we to deploy g S in the modeling of the final section, we would risk conflating the influence of polygamy with the influence of other, unknown factors. To address this risk, we seek an additional, direct measure of polygamy to serve as a micro-level confirmatory indicator of gamos. The ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ binary is one candidate, as evidenced by the very high correlation (r = 0.85) of ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ and g S , but we seek a gray scale rather than a binary measure. We will devote the remainder of this section to the construction of such a scale, one we will denote g.

Consider the prevalence of polygamy—defined as the male plural marriage fraction—as a candidate for this micro-level measure. It seems plausible that as the prevalence grows, the depth of the scarcity will grow, and the behaviors that follow from that scarcity will be more, rather than less distinct when compared to monogamous society. In the preceding section, we made the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ binary classification on the basis of customary or religious law in 1900 because contemporary convention may be out of step with contemporary law. Here, by the same logic, we select the opening of the twentieth century as the time frame for our estimate of prevalence. We know that g S is a good measure of gamos, contemporary convention. If g and g S are highly correlated, as we have every reason to expect based on the high degree of correlation between ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ and g S , then nineteenth-century prevalence is also a good measure of gamos.

Polygamy and culture are intimately intertwined, and so are culture and geography. The geospatial correlations of polygamy are evident in map 1. Having examined global, regional, and local assays of prevalence, we assert that seven cultural and/or regional traditions provide a sound basis for estimating g almost everywhere. These are African (within which there are three subcategories), Chinese, Near Eastern, Islamic, Asian (exclusive of China, the Near East, and Islam), Pacific Islander, and Western. Footnote 36 For each of these we posit a prevalence, g, whose standard error is g/6. Our assignments, separated by g/2, are thus separated by about three standard errors. We justify this method in the following paragraphs and summarize the assignments in Table 2.

Table 2. Regional and or cultural traditions, nominal prevalences of plural marriage fraction c. 1900, and exemplary states

The distribution of female plural marriage prevalences in twentieth-century Africa cluster in three groups. According to Fenske (Reference Fenske2015), their nominal values are 30 percent, 45 percent, and 60 percent at mid-century, falling to about half that by its close. In another study of mid-century tropical Africa, predominantly Africa (high) in our system, William Brass et al. report a male plural fraction of 23.7 percent (σ = 8.0 percent, N = 12) (Brass et al. Reference Brass, Coale, Demeny, Heisel, Lorimer, Romaniuk and van de Walle1968: 214). These findings, which may appear contradictory, are in fact consistent because female plural fraction is always somewhat greater than twice male plural fraction. From these data we posit that polygamy in early-twentieth-century Africa was typified by low, mid, and high prevalences of 10 percent, 15 percent, and 22.5 percent.

Islam is a world religion whose sectarian and regional differences are vast. Though the prevalence of polygamy among Muslims is highly variable, it does not defy categorization. Tertilt’s (Reference Tertilt2005) estimate of prevalence in Bangladesh is 11 percent. Among Bedouins in the Negev, contemporary prevalence is about 30–35 percent, having increased by 10 percent over the past decade (Al-Krenawi Reference Al-Krenawi2014). Chamie’s (Reference Chamie1986) study of latter twentieth-century polygamy in 13 Arab countries yields a value of 4.6 percent (σ = 2.4 percent, N = 22). If the long-term decline seen by Fenske is mirrored in these Arab countries, then the prevalence in 1900 was, on average, 9 percent. Being the case that polygamous marriages are often not civil marriages and thus not recorded, it is fair to assume that actual polygamy is more prevalent than the civil data shows. In our model, we assign 10 percent to the prevalence of polygamy across Islam, a value that does not stretch credulity.

Islam emerged among the Bedouins in the Hejaz on the western edge of the Arabian Peninsula. Polygamy was the custom among Bedouins, and had been so for millennia among others in the region (Quran 4:3; Genesis 29). It is not unreasonable to suppose that the prevalence of polygamy throughout the Near East was typified by the prevalence among Muslims who codified it. Thus, we assign 10 percent to the Near East tradition.

The traditions we call Asian derive from Buddhist, Hindu, and other cultures across Central and South Asia and, from there, east to Indonesia. Footnote 37 Wendy Doniger’s important work on the Hindus notes that polygyny “was the rule, and men could have several spouses throughout most of Hindu history” (Doniger Reference Doniger2009: 296). Indeed, the absence of polygamy in India’s labor-intensive agricultural communities would be anomalous, per Becker’s theory of the family (Reference Becker1973). Census data from the 1960s and 1970s shows that the bigamy rate among upper-class Hindus was 5.8 percent (Unisa and Mundu Reference Unisa and Grace Bahalen2011) and somewhat higher among Buddhists and other smaller ethnic groups (Dayal Reference Dayal2001). Allowing for the likely possibility that polygamy among upper classes is higher than among the lower ones, we assign g = 6.7 percent to Asia, exclusive of China, the Near East, Islam, and Russia.

Polygamy in China before communism was a mix of formal marriages and concubinage, both of which would have contributed to a scarcity of marriageable females. Mark Elvin suggests that the daughter of a thirteenth- or fourteenth-century tenant-serf could become a servant-girl, a wife, or a concubine, and we presume he means a concubine to the landlord (Elvin Reference Elvin1973: 71). In eighteenth- and nineteenth-century Liaoning Province in the north and Taiwan in the south, polygamy rates exclusive of concubinage were less than 2 percent, whereas in the uppermost reaches of the social hierarchy, prevalences exceeded 33 percent, also exclusive of concubinage (Lee and Feng Reference Lee and Wang2001: 76). We have argued, in harmony with Tertilt, that elevated birth rates go hand in hand with prevalence, in order that the scarcity of marriageable females be slaked (Reference Tertilt2005). Max Roser’s study of fertility in 1950 places China squarely among nations whose prevalence was 6.7 percent by our accounting (Roser Reference Roser2020). Though the data are sparse, we infer from them a value of 6.7 percent for the male plural fraction in China at the turn of the twentieth century, putting it at the low end of our system, and too low in the opinion of some sinologists.

Migrations, isolation, and small tribal chiefdoms in the Solomon Islands, Papua New Guinea, Samoa, and Fiji are consonant with polygamy on a high-African scale (Luker Reference Luker2015). We assign g = 22.5 percent for the Pacific Island tradition. Owing to early missionization of Fiji and Samoa, we judge that polygamy was lower in those two systems by 1900, and accordingly, we assign them values of g = 15 percent.

The Western marriage model is ${\cal nP}$ , so we assign g = 0 for the Western tradition. However, Haiti is in the West, yet a McDermott 3 and thus ${\cal P}$ . In the appendix we account for this with a refinement of the coarse characterization just described. Therein we apply the refinement to other states as necessary. We illustrate the refined g in map 2. Just as it is with g S , the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ distinction is manifest as a bimodality in g (see figure 5). We note further that the correlation between the two measures g S and g is 0.83, though they draw on different data and are developed using very different methodologies. This reaffirms our conviction that contemporary convention (g S ) is a result of longstanding polygamous practice as proxied by g, male plural marriage fraction in 1900.

Figure 5. Distribution of prevalence of polygamous marriage in 1900.

Map 2. A micromeasure of gamos, g, mapped for 177 states. Note: The scale is such that deepest grays correspond to 22.5 percent prevalence in 1900.

Where in this picture are the Mormons, whose late-nineteenth-century polygamy is a subject of interest? Nowhere, for three reasons. First, our unit polity is a sovereign nation, and united as Mormons may seem to some, they are not now nor have ever been a sovereign nation. Second, as to their impact on the sovereign United States, Mormons reached peak polygamy in 1890 when they formally abandoned it. The population of Utah was about 0.3 percent of the US total. If one-third of all Mormon marriages were polygamous, then it’s fair to say that the prevalence in the United States was about 0.1 percent, far below the level that divides ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ . Finally, the development of convention takes centuries, so the conventions we describe would not have had time to bud, much less reach full flower in the 50-year course of Mormon polygamous history. Nevertheless, the scarcity of marriageable females is evident in contemporary polygamous Mormon compounds, as is the stratification of males by elder and junior rank, the familial social disruption that follows de facto disenfranchisement, the aggravation of age difference at marriage, and the harsh authoritarianism that is necessary to hold the fractious factions together.

A Model of Development That Incorporates Polygamous Convention

The question at the heart of this article is “where is the family in economic history?” We have developed a theory of how polygamy shapes social convention, and we have quantified polygamous convention at the national level in a measure we call gamos. We aim, ultimately, to quantify polygamy’s contribution to macroscopic outcomes such as those broadly encompassed by the term development. In the service of that aim, we will deploy gamos in a causal, multivariate, cross-sectional, global model of development in which the nation is the unit polity, but first we must define our measure of development.

Development, like beauty, is in the eye of the beholder. To an economist, development is the expansion of goods and services. To the King of Bhutan, development is happiness. To an actuary, life expectancy. To Socrates, education. To Amartya Sen, not to mention Franklin Roosevelt, Max Weber, Thomas Jefferson, Adam Smith, Alexis de Tocqueville, and many others, some degree of good governance is an essential feature of prosperity and therefore of development.

The United Nations’ definition of development is embodied in their Human Development Index, HDI, a synthesis of highly correlated measures of income, life expectancy, and education, and it has two cardinal virtues that distinguish it from the economist’s choice, GDP. First, GDP is unsuited for cross-sectional analysis. This is made plain by the fact that the average of 2006 to 2015 per capita GDPs of the Czech Republic, Equatorial Guinea, Estonia, and Slovakia are approximately equal (World Bank 2020b), a result that is, in our view, at odds with experience. As seen through the lens of HDI, however, the Czech Republic, Estonia, and Slovakia remain peers, while Equatorial Guinea is the peer of Ghana. This does square with experience, though the per capita GDPs of the latter two countries differ by a factor of 12. HDI thus obviates GDPs failings, or many of them.

The second virtue of HDI is that, with few exceptions, a nation’s place in the global distribution of HDI, by which we mean its z-score in that distribution, is stable or persistent on a timescale measured in centuries. In work published elsewhere, we find that the correlation of the distribution of HDI at the present moment, to itself at an earlier moment, decays exponentially with a time constant of $626$ years (Seligson and McCants Reference Seligson and McCants2021). Footnote 38 Alternatively, we may say that the distribution decorrelates at a rate of about 15 percent per century. Either way, this is evidence of a remarkable persistence. In consequence of this persistence, one may be confident that models of the z-scored distribution are not sensitive to multidecadal changes of social or economic conditions, and one may rule out, as explanans, those putative sources of development that change on a timescale of decades. Very specifically, the observed persistence rules out the formal institutions favored by the NIE, Williamson’s L2, the very institutions that are said to be the rules of the game.

Though HDI incorporates the actuarial and Socratic interests of life expectancy and education, and is superior to GDP as a measure of development, it does not incorporate the interests of political science, that is, governance. To that end, we augment HDI with the World Bank’s six Worldwide Governance Indicators (World Bank, WGI, 2018). These indicators are measures of formal institutions, for example judiciaries and administrative bureaucracies, and thus this formulation puts formal institutions where they belong, on the output side and not on the input side of causation. Footnote 39 We denote the new measure $\mu $ and we call it development. Footnote 40 Map 3 illustrates the global distribution of $\mu $ and its large geospatial correlations. Figure 6 illustrates (A) the high correlation of HDI and $\mu $ (r = 0.93), and (B) the well-separated distributions of $\mu $ in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ .

Figure 6. Two views of development, $\mu $ . Notes: (A) The correspondence between HDI and $\mu $ (r = 0.93). (B) The well-separated CDFs of \mu in ${\cal P}$ (left/gray) and $\;{\cal nP}$ (right/black).

Map 3. The map of $\mu $ by nation. Note: The deepest grays correspond to the lowest states of development and white to the highest, or $\mu = \mp \;2$ respectively.

Like the distribution of HDI, the distribution of $\mu $ is persistent on long timescales, permitting us to model $\mu $ as a superposition of (mostly) very slowly changing sources of development. We write this as Eq. (1), where $x_i^j$ denotes the value of the $i^{th}$ source in the ${j^{th}}$ nation, ${c_i}$ is the coefficient expressing the ${i^{th}}$ source’s contribution to development, and ${e^j}$ is the residual, whose origin may lie in measurement error, stochasticity, or a flaw of model design. The ${c_i}$ are estimated by the ordinary method of least squares on a data set comprised of 177 nations.

(Eq. (1)) $${\mu ^j} = \mathop \sum \limits_{i \,= \,0}^n {c_i}x\,_ i^j + {e\,^j}$$

If the NIE’s favored L2 institutions are not, by reason of persistence, suitable for inclusion among the list of development’s candidate sources ${x_i}$ , what sources may we include? As already noted, $\mu $ is manifestly geospatially correlated. The likelihood that this arises from a superposition of geospatially uncorrelated sources seems to us low, so $\mu $ ’s geospatial correlations convey the message that its sources also have strong geospatial correlations. We may read, then, a list of candidate sources directly from the gross features of map 3, as Dell, Jones, and Olken did when they observed that apart from communist and formerly communist states, cold states are highly developed, and apart from oil rich states, hot states are less developed (Dell et al. Reference Dell, Jones and Olken2012: 70). In addition, we note that states at high elevations have lower $\mu $ than similar ones at lower elevations, as exemplified by Lesotho, Bolivia, and Nepal. These observations suggest that some proxies for climate, geography, natural resources, and communist history are likely candidates for the ${x_i}$ . Footnote 41 The same may be said, too, for gamos. From map 2, we see that its geospatial correlations are large, and if we compare maps 2 and 3, we see that those correlations are coincident; where gamos is high, $\mu $ is low. Each of these candidate sources is plausibly causative of development, Footnote 42 and each conforms to the boundary condition imposed by persistence. Footnote 43 For the purposes of this article, we restrict ourselves to ${x_i}$ drawn from these five categories. These are sufficient to achieve the article’s mission, which is to assess the role of family in economic history. Other categories, whose impact is not obvious from the map and therefore are likely to be of secondary importance, for instance religion, civil and international conflict, imperial conquest, ethnic fractionalization, good and bad neighbor effects, and genetics, deserve consideration, too, though giving them their due is beyond the scope of this article.

For each of the five categories, we now describe the relevant proxies or candidate ${x_i}$ . In the second century CE, Ptolemy deduced that global climate variation is driven by insolation that is modulated by the sun’s varying inclination to Earth’s spherical surface (Edwards Reference Edwards2011: 128). By his analysis, climate variation is nearly independent of latitude within a zone $16.5^\circ $ north and south of the equator, and nearly linear in latitude in zones lying between $30^\circ $ and $50^\circ $ on either side of the equator. Edmond Halley, in 1686, and George Hadley, in 1735, theorized that convection would also bear heavily on near-equatorial climate, extending the range of latitude independence all the way to the lower subtropics, or roughly $ \pm 30^\circ $ (Hartmann Reference Hartmann1994: 142). Climate’s impact on the economy was noted by Aristotle, and has been elaborated on much since, but in a landmark paper, the Nobelist William Nordhaus remarks that by the mid-twentieth century, climate had all but disappeared from the economic development literature. A figure in that same paper suggests a weak linear dependence of log per capita GDP on distance from the equator, $\varphi $ , for higher latitudes, and an independence of the two for lower latitudes. This, and his investigation of the role of temperature on income led him to conclude, “We should surely look to factors other than climate to explain most differences in the wealth and poverty of nations” (Nordhaus Reference Nordhaus1994: 356–64). Soon thereafter, in a paper on the deep roots of national productivity, Hall and Jones (Reference Hall and Jones1999) proxied climate as $\varphi $ . For the more than four billion people who live within $30^\circ $ of the equator, $\varphi $ explains less than 5 percent of the variance of physical measures of climate, for instance temperature, aridity, and potential evapo-transpiration (PET). Overall, $\varphi $ is a poor proxy of climate, and one that no scientist since Ptolemy would endorse, but it is the economists’ choice, Footnote 44 so we include it here for completeness (see Table 3). Insolation is highly correlated with annual, national temperature where $\varphi \gt 30^\circ $ (r = 0.82), and moderately so where $\varphi \lt 30^\circ $ (r = 0.30), so it promises to be a moderately better proxy than $\varphi $ . Footnote 45 Of the aforementioned physical measures of climate, PET is probably the least well known. It is highly correlated with temperature (r = 0.93), and it exhibits systematically negative deviations where the humidity is very high, and positive deviations where the humidity is very low.

Table 3. Candidate proxies for sources of development across five categories

As proxies for geography we use mean elevation and terrain ruggedness. We justify the former on the grounds that higher elevation goes hand in hand with more difficult living conditions by virtue of agriculture, weather, access, and the partial pressure of oxygen. Terrain ruggedness was introduced by Nunn and Puga (Reference Nunn and Diego2012). We deploy that measure with its elevation component removed.

For climate and geography proxies, we use averages without weighting. Population-weighting is something to consider for future work, though our initial explorations hint at little merit in it. For natural resources, we rely on the World Bank’s compilation of annual natural resources rents as a fraction of GDP, averaged over the years 2006 to 2015. We use this in two forms; as reported and as the log of per capita rents in US dollars. For communism, our proxies focus on whether a nation did or did not have a Marxist–Leninist government. We employ a binary variant and one that is linear in its duration. For family structure, we use gamos, There are two choices for gamos, g S and g. As explained, g S is a measure of social convention that risks confounding by sources other than polygamy, and g is a direct measure of polygamy. As additional proxies for family structure, we use the ${\cal P}/{\cal nP}$ binary and sex ratio at puberty. We have no evidence that sex ratios exhibit the long-term persistence demanded of a candidate source. Nevertheless, we include it here because the social conventions that arise from polygamy are occasionally present in high sex ratio societies.

From these 14 proxies, we construct 648 models of the form given in Eq. (1), where $n \le 5$ and no model includes more than one candidate from each category. To select the best of them, we use the Bayes Information Criterion (BIC), a log likelihood estimate conjoined with a penalty for model complexity. BIC assesses the extent to which the data, usually called the evidence, favors the model, usually referred to as a scientific theory. We follow Kass and Raftery (Reference Kass and Raftery1995) who teach that, when comparing two models, a BIC difference exceeding 6, $\Delta {\rm{BIC}} \gt 6,$ is a strong indication that the evidence favors the model with the lower BIC. Being that BIC is logarithmic, the strength of that indication increases exponentially with $\Delta {\rm{BIC}}$ . Accordingly, Kass and Raftery teach that $\Delta {\rm{BIC}} \gt 10$ is a very strong indication that the evidence favors the model with the lower BIC. Though most researchers use the term model selection as a label for Kass and Raftery’s protocol, that protocol is more easily understood as quantitative alternative hypothesis testing.

In addition to BIC, we examine the geospatial correlations of the model residuals. The geospatial correlations of development, evident in map 3, must arise, in large part if not in toto, from the geographic extent of its sources. Large, geospatially correlated residuals signal the omission of a variable of geospatial scope. We assay these with I’, a logarithmic measure of geospatial correlations in the model residuals (Seligson and McCants Reference Seligson and McCants2021). Only if $I' \lt I'_{50}= - 2.88$ is the model more likely than not to be free of omitted geospatially significant variable bias.

In figure 7 we represent each of the 648 models by its BIC and I’, and we label many of them with their explained variance. Strung out like stars in the Milky Way, they form a band that runs from the upper right, where models have low explanatory power, high BIC, and considerable likelihood of suffering from omitted variable bias, to the lower left where they are better in every respect. The best model—the one with lowest BIC—is indicated by the large black pentagon which we call ${{\cal M}_5}$ . It selects PET, mean elevation (h), log per capita natural resources rents (nrr), the duration of communist rule ( $\tau $ ), and gamos (g). The maximum p-value of ${{\cal M}_5}$ ’s parameters is $1 \times {10^{ - 6}}$ , indicating that the model is well defined. Its BIC is 15 points lower than the closest competitor. By Kass and Raftery then, the data very, very strongly favor ${{\cal M}_5}$ over all others as a theory of development. Furthermore, its $I' = - 3.07 \lt {I'_{50}} = - 2.88$ , so we can have better than 50 percent confidence that, if we have omitted some variables, which we no doubt have, they do not produce large geospatial correlations among nations. Finally, the explained variance, an output of model selection rather than its criterion, is ${{R^2} = {0.77}}$ .

Figure 7. Five-parameter model selection. Notes: Each dot or polygon represents one of 648 different combinations of the 14 proxies. Black coloring signifies that g, the prevalence of male plural marriage, is one of the model variables. ${{\cal M}_5}$ , the optimal five-parameter model, is represented by the five-sided polygon in the lower left corner. ${{\cal M}_4}$ , the optimal four-parameter model (from which all measures of family structure are excluded), is represented by the four-sided polygon.

Let us now compare ${{\cal M}_5}$ to models without a family structure variable. The best of these, ${{\cal M}_4}$ , is denoted in figure 7 by the white four-sided polygon at ${\rm{BIC}} \cong 580$ . If $\Delta {\rm{BIC}} \gt 6$ implies strong and $\Delta {\rm{BIC}} \gt 10$ implies very strong, what adjective is appropriate for $\Delta {\rm{BIC}} = 77$ , the value pertinent to this comparison? Decisive. Apart from gamos, $\;{{\cal M}_4}$ deploys the same variables as ${{\cal M}_5}$ . Simply put, ${{\cal M}_5}$ is incomparably superior to ${{\cal M}_4}$ , and the superiority is due entirely to the inclusion of gamos. Thus we may fairly conclude, as we hypothesized, that the suite of social conventions born of polygamy, as proxied by its prevalence in 1900, is a powerful determinant of contemporary social and economic development.

Table 4 is a summary of key features of ${{\cal M}_5}$ . An index ( $i$ ), the variable name ( ${x_i})$ , its corresponding unit of measure, its standard deviation across the data set ( ${\sigma _i}$ ), and the OLS estimate of its corresponding parameter ( ${c_i})$ are in the first four columns. In the next column, following McCloskey’s (Reference McCloskey2002) suggestive nomenclature, we use the term oomph for $2{\sigma _i}{c_i}$ , an expression of the overall contribution of an input, ${x_i}$ , on the output $\mu $ (which, roughly speaking, spans the range $ \pm 2).\;$ The two variables with the greatest oomph are climate and polygamy, and communist governance is a near third. This overturns the astounding claims by Nordhaus (Reference Nordhaus1994), Hall and Jones (Reference Hall and Jones1999), Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2002), and Rodrik et al. (Reference Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi2004) that climate and culture are insignificant contributors to long-term economic development. We must note, though, that ${{\cal M}_5}$ is by no means the last word. More complex models, and models incorporating variables we did not consider here may change the rank ordering of oomph, but, surely, we must expect that climate and family structure will be on the shortlist of major contributors to the wealth and poverty of nations.

Table 4. ${{\cal M}_5}$ parameter summary table

Note: Column labels are described in the text.

In this penultimate paragraph, we make a few comparisons of our model with others, and we note a few of its unique features. From the fact noted in a footnote Footnote 40 , $\Delta \cal{E}=\Delta {\rm{log(GNI)}} \cong {\rm 1.142} \ \Delta \mu$ , we may infer the sensitivity of income to any one of the input variables. For climate, we get $ - 6.5\;{\rm{percent}}\;$ per $^\circ C$ . The value obtained by Dell et al. (Reference Dell, Jones and Olken2009) for GDP is $ - 8.5\;{\rm{percent}}\;$ per $\;^\circ C$ . We attribute the difference to unaccounted-for omitted variable bias in their univariate model, differences between dollar-denominated GDP and GNI denominated by purchasing power parity, and some other methodological differences. Next, the inferred sensitivity of GNI to polygamy is $ - 6.9\;{\rm{percent\;}}$ per 1 percent change in prevalence. In practice, the prevalence in the ${\cal P}$ -states is rarely less than 6.7 percent, and the mean prevalence for all ${\cal P}$ -states is $13.3{\rm{\;percent}}.$ These prevalences correspond to a GNI suppression (relative to ${\cal nP}$ -states where the prevalence is zero) of 38 percent and 61 percent, respectively. These values are consistent with Tertilt’s estimates, though our methods are rather different (Tertilt Reference Tertilt2005: 1343). Lastly, map 3 tells us that communism has a large (negative) bearing on $\mu $ . This led us to include proxies for communist governance in the model selection process. We did not, however, specify the sign of communism’s effect, and model selection might well have rejected communism altogether. But it did not; the best model without a communist governance proxy is 54 BIC points greater than that of ${{\cal M}_5}$ . This multivariate model of materially all nations on the planet tells us that the inferred cost or burden of communist governance on income is $15\;{\rm{percent}}$ per decade.

Clearly, as natural philosophers have been arguing for at least two millennia, climate matters for development; and clearly, as historians have been arguing for at least three, history matters too. Our framework permits us to assess their relative importance, but we can only weigh what we have included. In the hands of others, this same framework may reveal that beyond family and beyond communist ideology, there are other aspects of history that matter, too.

Conclusion

We began this article by asking the question “where is the family in economic history?” We conclude it by arguing that it should be squarely at the center. Work in economic sociology as well as in economic history has demonstrated time and again that social convention matters to economic outcomes. This insight is often shorthanded (imprecisely as we argue elsewhere) as “institutions matter.” We agree that they do, but which ones in particular, and in what ways? We show here that family law and practice, specifically the dichotomy between monogamy and polygamy, generates a bimodal set of linked conventions governing interactions between individuals, households, the state and marketplace, and of course, between the sexes. We identify a set of polygamy-born conventions that typically occur together, a suite we call gamos. It is associated with the commodification of women at the expense of their health, wealth, education, and personal agency. It is also associated with high birth rates, harsh justice, and authoritarian rule. If family law or practice shapes the conventions in which all economic activity is embedded, then we must expect gamos to matter for economic outcomes. That marriage law has not been invoked in standard models of economic development or inequality strikes us as a hobbling omission. Our work develops two independent measures of gamos for 177 nations—g S , based on the suite of 11 salient social conventions that we attribute in part to polygamy, and g, based on estimates of the prevalence of polygamy in 1900—and finds them highly correlated (r = 0.83). In a causal, multivariate, and compact model of long-term social and economic development, we deploy g—alongside variables describing climate, geography, communism, and natural resources—to find that its contribution is second only to climate’s, a factor long recognized as important, even if it has fallen out of favor with economists. The family, however, has been conspicuously absent from cross-sectional economic development modeling that, to paraphrase North, has not produced satisfactory explanations despite 70 years of immense effort (Reference North1990: 11). When ubiquity stares us in the face, we often fail to notice. The findings reported on here remind us that we ignore the family at our peril.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ssh.2021.23

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful for the opportunity to discuss aspects our research with Robert Paul, Francis Fukuyama, John Donohue, Rose McDermott, Mathieu Arnoux, Thomas Martin, Walter Scheidel, Jane Humphries, Deborah Oxley, Judy Stephenson, Harriett Zurndorfer, and Lauren Gage Segal. We also thank Fabian Drixler for his extensive comments on an early version of the paper. Finally, we thank the organizers of economic history workshops at Northwestern, Oxford, the Paris School of Economics, and Yale, for the opportunity to present aspects of the work in progress, as well as the thoughtful comments received after an SSHA presentation in Phoenix (2019).

Footnotes

1 In neoclassical economics, while the role of family is not altogether absent, it is nonetheless easy to miss, showing up more often at the edges of the discipline than as a key explanans. Gary Becker’s A Treatise on the Family (1981) is considered authoritative on this subject by many economists, but historians find in it little that is recognizable. His “family economics” method applies neoclassical concepts to the decision processes that shape family life, such as marriage, fertility, education, or the sexual division of labor. It does not concern itself foremost with how family processes shape the economic behavior of individuals once in the marketplace, nor more importantly how differing family systems contribute to the long-run processes of development that constitute the object of so much work in economic history.

2 The NIE is not alone in making the claim that factors beyond rational choice are essential to understanding economic behavior. In a landmark paper, sociologist Mark Granovetter wrote of “the extent to which economic action is embedded in structures of social relations” (Granovetter Reference Granovetter1985: 481). In the same year, economist Robert Solow wrote that “all narrowly economic activity is embedded in a web of social institutions, customs, beliefs, and attitudes” (Solow Reference Solow1985: 328). These papers have institutionalized “embeddedness” as a conceptual if not analytic framework for thinking about what underlies neoclassical economics.

3 Deirdre McCloskey mocks this narrow focus of the NIE, calling it a prescription to “add institutions and stir” (McCloskey Reference McCloskey2016: 10).

4 Williamson eschews the formal/informal distinction in favor of one based on the timescale of their evolution. The rules of the game change over the course of decades or less and socially embedded convention changes over the course of centuries if not longer (Williamson Reference Williamson2000: 597).

5 Bare Branches is a univariate study. In as much as high sex ratio societies are both similar to and different from polygamous ones, conclusions drawn from statistical or econometric analysis must include both high sex ratio and polygamy, or risk the consequences of omitted variable bias.

6 Measured as a fraction, w, the number of women in male plural marriages is typically somewhat more than twice the number of men in such marriages.

7 Recently in Albania, 6 percent of married men were in plural marriages (Gruber Reference Gruber2002).

8 Given the fact that polygamy is a virtue in Islam (Elbedour et al. Reference Elbedour, Onwuegbuzie, Caridine and Abu-Saad2002), it is probable that what holds in Chechnya also holds in the Russian republics of Ingushetia, Dagestan, Karachay-Cherkessia, Kabardino-Balkaria, Tatarstan, and Bashkortostan, in each of which the Muslim population exceeds 38 percent.

9 Plural marriage fraction, which we will denote p, is distinct from and less than w, the fraction of women in plural marriages. Generally speaking, one needs an additional piece of information, the number of wives per plural marriage, to compute p from w or vice versa.

10 Supporting this, the linguist Walter Edwards has reported on the adoption in Guyana of West African marriage traditions, specifically bride price, which are otherwise unique to polygamous society (1982).

11 In addition to the states in McDermott’s classification, we add Samoa as ${\cal P}$ and Antigua and Barbuda, Grenada, and Seychelles as ${\cal nP}$ .

12 This is consistent with McDermott’s findings, wherein the female plural marriage fraction—which is typically somewhat more than twice the male plural marriage fraction— ${\cal P}$ was less than 25 percent in 76 of 93 ${\cal P}$ -states.

13 From the requirement that almost all members of a group adhere to a convention, and from the fact that such behavioral norms are generally learned in the first few years of life, we may infer that conventions change on a timescale of multiple generations, a timescale far longer than one we associate with a temporary shortage.

14 That bride price is all but unique to polygamy is evidence that the scarcity mechanism, absent in ${\cal nP}$ , is responsible for it. We do not assert, nor do we find, that other forms of wealth transfer at marriage are impossible in ${\cal P}$ . We note further that Botticini and Siow show that, contrary to the theorizing of Gary Becker, bride price does not emerge in response to the disappearance of dowry. Rather it exists independently, and is strongly associated, they say, with the practice of polygyny, especially in Africa (Botticini and Siow 2003: 1385, 1390).

15 Ancient history tells us little about polygamy in the Americas in that time, but supporting our claim is the fact that many of its indigenous societies were polygamous at the time of conquest and some remain so today (Chagnon et al. Reference Chagnon, Lynch, Shenk, Raymond and Flinn2017; Pearsall Reference Pearsall2019).

16 Sexual size dimorphism in Homo sapiens confirms the fact that we inherited polygamy from our Miocene ancestors among the great apes, all of whose extant descendants are polygamous (Plavcan Reference Plavcan2012: S413). Whether polygamy was a constant or whether it waned and then waxed in the Holocene, we cannot know.

17 To employ the nomenclature of Hedström and Swedberg, these are the “social mechanisms that produce [the] observed relationships between explanands and explanandum” (Hedström and Swedberg Reference Hedström and Swedberg1996: 281).

18 No argument of this kind can be made about the EMP. The characteristics of EMP states are distinctly modern, and an argument in defense of their causal nature must comprehend endogeneities as well as covariates.

19 Elevated birthrate does, of course, produce males as well as females, but as the matrimonial bride price belongs to the father of the bride, every newborn girl is an asset on his balance sheet. Every newborn boy is just another surplus male, which surplus is not his problem to solve.

20 Banning polygamy is more easily said than done. Carmeliza Rosário observed that in Mozambique, banning polygamy “plays against some of the women the law is intended to protect; particularly since the law does not eliminate per se the mechanisms of the patriarchal system” (2008: 1). Because the law works against those women, they are not motivated to observe it. This is an example of norms superseding laws, or what Douglass North would have described as informal institutions superseding formal ones.

21 The age gap differential between ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ is greater than reported here. The data shown is singulate mean age gap at first marriage, and thus does not take into account the effect of plural marriage. Using that singulate data in conjunction with actual plural marriage prevalence, we estimate that the plural marriage age gap differential is greater than the singulate value by 0.9 years, a very large difference given that the standard deviation of age gap in ${\cal nP}$ is 0.7. Tertilt reports an even larger gap of 6.8 years in her study of 28 countries, all from sub-Saharan Africa with the exception of Bangladesh (2005: 1367). It is interesting to note that in some rare instances, age gap at marriage may fall rather than grow as a response to gender-imbalanced scarcity. In a study of marital behavior in France following World War I, Abramitzky et al. (Reference Abramitzky, Delavande and Vasconcelos2011) find that the relative scarcity of males increased the likelihood that men would marry, lowered the ages at which they did so, and thereby lowered the age gap between nuptial partners. But such a mechanism must be transient, not chronic, except in societies that are perpetually in a state of war, and no nation today qualifies as such.

22 Given the value placed on women in polygamous states, it may seem odd that they are commodified, but it seems less odd when we look at the parallels with slavery. Slaves were valuable, being the source of energy that powered multiple industries, and yet slaves were commodified. Had they not been commodified, their labor value would have accrued to their own selves and not to their owners. However, the anthropologist Emmanuel Todd opines—in a little read but important book about the origins of ideology in family structure—that the universality of men withholding power from women is more rigidly observed than the nearly universal strictures against incest (Todd Reference Todd1985: 22).

23 Hartung et al. (Reference Hartung1982) reports that among 1,170 societies documented in George Murdock’s monumental Ethnographic Atlas, polygyny is practiced in at least 860.

24 In principle, such marauders could be male or female, but owing to their larger size and greater strength, and to female sequestration, the marauders are, for the most part, male. A proverb of the traditionally polygamous Bedouins runs as follows: Me against my brother, me and my brother against our cousin, us against the clan, the clan against the tribe, and the tribe against the world. Karen Armstrong writes of this society, “outside the tribe, obligation ceased” (Armstrong Reference Armstrong1993: 58). Thus, raiding other tribes is permitted, consistent with what one would expect of a polygamous society. Within the tribe, trust in all things, says the proverb, is calibrated to familial distance.

25 One stratum, the so-called junior males, is comprised of (mostly young) adults without wives and the other stratum is comprised of married elders.

26 By this logic, married men may be expected to be less violent than their unmarried peers. This is found to be the case in one study which reports that “states of marriage causally inhibit crime over the life course” (Sampson et al. Reference Sampson, Laub and Wimer2006).

27 The economist and legal scholar John Donohue uses the term “implicit crime rate” to illuminate the dynamic balancing of criminality and enforcement (Donohue Reference Donohue2017: 1307). He notes that the 2014 murder rate in the United States, 44 per million, was lower than at any time since 1957, in part as a consequence of policies that increased incarcerations to the highest level the world has ever seen. The murder rate that would have been observed without exceptional incarcerations and other suppressive forces, what he calls the “implicit murder rate,” is much higher. Thus, a nation’s criminal justice system is a reflection of implicit as well as real or observed criminality within its borders.

28 Amnesty International reports that over the period 2007 to 2011, there were about 2,900 executions or death sentences per annum. The World Health Organization reported that the prevalence of honor killing is not less than 5,000 per year (Garcia-Moreno et al. Reference Garcia-Moreno, Guedes and Knerr2012). That the object of honor violence is usually a woman and that the practice has something to do with polygamy may be understood from the following: sequestration is convention in ${\cal P}$ . It is expected, therefore, that every family will sequester its women and that a violation of sequestration is taboo. Honor killing is consistent with the definition of taboo, which calls for murder or excommunication of the violator (Freud Reference Freud1950 [1913]).

29 Various organizations aim to eradicate fgm/c, and it is in decline, though at least one organization, African Women Are Free to Choose (AWAFC) aims to preserve it on the grounds that only cultural relativism separates those who hold it in high regard from those who condemn it (Ahmadu Reference Ahmadu2016). The AWAFC argument reinforces rather than undermines our argument that fgm/c is a matter of convention because, per Lewis (Reference Lewis1969), the origins of convention are lost in time. To wit, neither AWAFC nor its cofounder, anthropologist Fuambai Sia Ahmadu, who is also Minister of Gender and Social Welfare in ${\cal P}$ state Sierra Leone, offers any cogent theory of fgm/c’s origins.

30 By this measure, 0.2 means that boys receive, on average, 20 percent more schooling than girls.

31 We are grateful to Thomas Martin (private conversation February 15, 2019) who noted that nobility rules on the strength of the privileges it dispenses. The nobility of seventh- and sixth-century BCE Greece was weak in the aftermath of the great wealth- and culture-destroying calamity that took down Mycenaean civilization in or around 1100 BCE. Their weakness left them few privileges to dispense and opened the door to these reforms.

32 His silence cannot be because he was blind to polygamy, for in his descriptions of Asians and Africans, polygamy is a commonplace, with one example being the numerous wives Darius took upon his ascension to the Achaemenid throne in 522 BCE.

33 Hudson and den Boer claim that “high-sex-ratio societies are governable only by authoritarian regimes capable of suppressing violence at home” (Hudson and den Boer Reference Hudson and Andrea2005: 202). While supportive of our argument owing to some similarities between high-sex-ratio societies and ${\cal P}$ , no such claim can be validated by the univariate methods those scholars employ.

34 The median value of the 55 correlations of the 11 different behaviors is 0.50 (σ = 0.12).

35 Robert Merton (Reference Merton and Merton1967) would have called these behaviors middle-range conventions.

36 This categorization is not unlike that described by the World Values Survey Cultural Map, with the main difference being that researchers Ronald Inglehart and Christian Welzel (2017) lump Africa and Islam into one zone whereas we separate them into four, each with its own prevalence, and they subdivide what we call Western (having a single prevalence) into six separate zones.

37 Though Russia straddles the West and Asia, it obeys the logic of the former because it inherited the g = 0 prescriptive monogamy of the West (Witte Reference Witte2015) from Byzantine missionaries in the ninth century.

38 The source of the persistence lies in r-Theory, a dynamical systems theory of the coevolution of institutions and economic performance that is fully described in Seligson and McCants (Reference Seligson and McCants2021).

39 The papers of Hall and Jones (Reference Hall and Jones1999), Acemoglu et al. (Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2001), and Rodrik et al. (Reference Rodrik, Subramanian and Trebbi2004) tautologically employ measures of formal institutions on the input side and development on the output side of their theory and modeling. Of course, robust statistical results, as those papers exhibit, can be expected when an acausal correlate of the output is included as an input.

40 $\mu $ is standardized by design. That is, it is zero-centered and its variance is 1. By construction, $\mu $ is highly correlated with the log of per capita income (r = 0.95). Denoting the latter $$\cal{E}$$ , $\Delta {\cal{E}} = 1.142$ Δ $$\mu $$ . This relation is helpful when interpreting the impact of model parameters on income, however, it is strictly valid only in 2015, the year of the reported GNI data. We note further that our measure of development is formulated in a spirit very similar to the one that motivates the recent work of Leandro Prados de la Escosura, in which he introduces a measure of augmented human development (Reference de la Escosura2021).

41 The simplifying assumption of linearity in Eq. (1) precludes detection of optimal conditions such as one might anticipate for climate and natural resources. This assumption is easily amended, but we have found limited justification for doing so.

42 We note that AJR say climate is spurious and that Rodrik says that NIE seeks to show that climate isn’t important, while Aristotle, Ibn Khaldun, Montesquieu, Diamond, and Dell et al. have written persuasively to the contrary.

43 Though the timescale of persistence tells us that the model must be dominated by sources that vary negligibly over a century, the model must also admit of enough source variation to account for the small decorrelation over that same period. Of the five sources or categories—climate, geography, family structure, natural resources, and communism—the first three are materially constant over centuries and the last two are modern and transient. The former are likely to account for most of the variance of μ, and the latter are likely to contribute to its decorrelation.

45 Insolation outperforms $\varphi $ where $\varphi \lt 30^\circ $ because insolation, like temperature, is independent of latitude near the equator, whereas the same cannot be said for $\varphi $ .

References

Abramitzky, Ran, Delavande, Adeline, and Vasconcelos, Luis (2011) “Marrying up: The role of sex ratio in assortative matching.American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3 (3): 124–57.Google Scholar
Abu Rabia, Rawia (2011) “Redefining polygamy among the Palestinian Bedouins in Israel: Colonialism, patriarchy, and resistance.American University Journal of Gender Social Policy and Law 19 (2): 459–93.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2001) “The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation.The American Economic Review 91 (5): 13691401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2002) “Reversal of fortune: Geography and institutions in the making of the modern world income distribution.The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1231–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahmadu, Fuambai Sia (2016) “Female circumcision—women must have the right to choose.” Sierra Leone Telegraph, February 8.Google Scholar
Al-Krenawi, Alean (2014) Psychosocial Impact of Polygamy in the Middle East. Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amnesty International (2012) www.amnesty.org (accessed June 3, 2019).Google Scholar
Arbuthnot, John (1710) “An argument for divine providence, taken from the constant regularity observed in the births of both sexes.” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society (27): 186–90.Google Scholar
Armstrong, Karen (1993) Muhammad: A Biography of the Prophet. Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary (1973) “A theory of marriage: Part I.Journal of Political Economy 81 (4): 813–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary (1981) A Treatise on the Family. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Belmaker, R. H. (2012) “Successful cultural change: The example of female circumcision among Israeli Bedouins and Israeli Jews from Ethiopia.Israeli Journal of Psychiatry 49 (3): 178–83.Google ScholarPubMed
Betzig, Laura (1986) Despotism and Differential Reproduction: A Darwinian View of History. Aldine Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Botticini, Maristela, and Aloysius, Siow (2003) “Why dowries?American Economic Review 93 (4): 1385–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brass, William, Coale, Ansely J., Demeny, Paul, Heisel, Don F., Lorimer, Frank, Romaniuk, Anatole, and van de Walle, Etienne (1968) The Demography of Tropical Africa. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carmichael, Sarah G., Alexandra, de Pleijt, Jan Luiten, van Zanden, and Tine De, Moor (2016) “The European marriage pattern and its measurement.Journal of Economic History 76 (1): 196204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chagnon, Napoleon A., Robert F. Lynch, , Shenk, Mary K., Raymond, Hames, and Flinn, Mark V. (2017) “Cross-cousin marriage among the Yanomamo.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 114 (13): E2590E2607, doi: 10.1073/pnas.1618655114.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chamie, J. (1986) “Polygyny among Arabs.Population Studies 40 (1): 5566.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dagum, Camilo (1980) “Inequality measures between income distributions with applications.Econometrica 48 (7): 17911803.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dayal, John (2001) “Lies, half truths and statistics: The fine art of demonization as political demography.” Center for Policy Studies, http://www.cpsindia.org/index.php/pub/87-religious-demography-of-india/reviews/84-indian-currents-lies-half-truths-and-statistics-by-john-dayal (accessed June 28, 2019).Google Scholar
de la Escosura, Leandro Prados (2021) “Inequality beyond GDP: A long view.” Instituto Figuerola Working Papers in Economic History. ISSN: 2341–2542.Google Scholar
Dell, Melissa, Jones, Benjamin F., and Olken, Benjamin A. (2012) “Temperature Shocks and Economic Growth:Evidence from the Last Half Century.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4 (3): 6695.Google Scholar
De Moor, Tina, and Jan Luiten, van Zanden (2010) “Girl power: The European marriage pattern and labour markets in the North Sea Region in the late medieval and early modern period.Economic History Review 63 (1): 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dell, Melissa, Jones, Benjamin F., and Olken, Benjamin A. (2009) “Temperature and income: Reconciling new cross-sectional and panel estimates.American Economic Review 99 (2): 198204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennison, Tracy, and Sheilagh, Ogilvie (2014) “Does the European marriage pattern explain economic growth?Journal of Economic History 74 (3): 651–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doniger, Wendy (2009) The Hindus. Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Donohue, John J. (2017) “Comey, Trump, and the puzzling pattern of crime in 2015 and beyond.Columbia Law Review 117 (5): 12971354.Google Scholar
Edwards, Paul N. (2011) “History of climate modeling.WIRES: Climate Change 2 (1): 128–39.Google Scholar
Edwards, Walter F. (1982) “A description and interpretation of the Kwe-Kwe tradition in Guyana.Folklore 93 (2): 181–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elbedour, Salman, Onwuegbuzie, Anthony J., Caridine, Corin, and Abu-Saad, Hasan (2002) “The effect of polygamous marital structure on behavioral, emotional, and academic adjustment in children: A comprehensive review of the literature.Clinical Child and Family Psychology Review 5 (4): 255–71.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Elvin, Mark (1973) The Pattern of the Chinese Past. Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Farrington, David P. (1986) “Age and crime.Crime and Justice 7: 189250.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenske, James (2015) “African polygamy: Past and present.Journal of Political Economy 117 (C): 5873.Google Scholar
Freedom House (2016) Freedom in the World 2016: The Annual Survey of Political Rights and Civil Liberties, https://freedomhouse.org/ (accessed August 8, 2019).Google Scholar
Freud, Sigmund (1950 [1913]) Totem and Taboo. Trans. James Strachey. W. W. Norton & Company.Google Scholar
Garcia-Moreno, Claudia, Guedes, Alessandra and Knerr, Wendy (2012) “Femicide.” WHO/RHR/12.38 World Health Organization, https://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/handle/10665/77421/WHO_RHR_12.38_eng.pdf (accessed April 20, 2021).Google Scholar
Glowacki, Luke, and Richard, Wrangham (2015) “Warfare and reproductive success in a tribal population.Proceedings of the National Academy of Science 112 (2): 348–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golden, Paul Rakita (2002) The Culture of Sex in Ancient China. University of Hawai‘i Press.Google Scholar
Granovetter, Mark (1985) “Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness.American Journal of Sociology 91 (3): 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruber, Siegfried (2002) “Regional variation in marriage patterns in Albania at the beginning of the 20th century.” Paper presented at the Social Science History Association, St. Louis, MO, November 16.Google Scholar
Hagerty, Barbara (2008) “Philly’s black Muslims increasingly turn to polygamy.” All Things Considered, Transcript of National Public Radio, May 28.Google Scholar
Hajnal, John (1965) “European marriage patterns in perspective,” in David Glass and D. Eversley, E. C. (eds.) Population in History: Essays in Historical Demography. Aldine: 101–43.Google Scholar
Hall, R. E., and Jones, C. (1999) “Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (1): 83116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartman, Mary S. (2004) The Household and the Making of History: A Subversive View of the Western Past. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartmann, Dennis L. (1994) Global Physical Climatology. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Hartung, John (1982) “Polygyny and inheritance of wealth [and comments and replies].Current Anthropology 23 (1): 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedström, P., and Swedberg, R. (1996) “Social mechanisms.Acta Sociologica 39 (3): 281308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hrdy, Sarah (1999) Mother Nature: A History of Mothers, Infants and Natural Selection. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Hudson, Valerie (2016) Bride price/Dowry Scale 1. WomanStats Project Database, http://www.womanstats.org (accessed July 2, 2019).Google Scholar
Hudson, Valerie, and Andrea, den Boer (2005) Bare Branches: The Security Implications of Asia’s Surplus Male Population. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Hughes, Diane Owen (1978) “From bride price to dowry in Mediterranean Europe.Journal of Family History 3 (3): 262–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Inglehart, Ronald, and Welzel, Christian (2017) “Cultural map,” http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/images/Culture_Map_2017_conclusive.png (accessed May 24, 2020).Google Scholar
Kass, R. E., and Raftery, A. E. (1995) “Bayes factors.Journal of the American Statistical Association 90 (430): 773–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornai, Janos (1980) Economics of Shortage. North-Holland Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Lape, S. (2002) “Solon and the institution of the ‘democratic’ family form.The Classical Journal 98 (2): 117–39.Google Scholar
Lee, James, and Wang, Feng (2001) One Quarter of Humanity: Malthusian Mythology and Chinese Realities, 1700–2000. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lewis, David (1969) Convention: A Philosophical Study. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Luker, Vicki (2015) “Chiefly polygamy in Fiji during the 1840s and 1850s: A political and economic imperative?” Slides presented at the Department of Pacific and Asian History Seminar Series, Australian National University, March 3.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. (2002) “Three books of oomph.Eastern Economic Journal 27 (1): 115118.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. (2016) “Max U versus Humanomics: A critique of neo-institutionalism.Journal of Institutional Economics 12 (1): 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDermott, Rose (2007) McDermott Female Circumcision Prevalence Scale. WomanStats Project Database, http://www.womanstats.org (accessed July 2, 2019).Google Scholar
McDermott, Rose (2010) McDermott Polygyny Scale. WomanStats Project Database, http://www.womanstats.org (accessed July 2, 2019).Google Scholar
McDermott, Rose (2018) The Evils of Polygyny: Evidence of Its Harm to Women, Men, and Society (The Easton Lectures). Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Merton, Robert K. (1967) “On sociological theories of the middle range,” in Merton, Robert K. (ed.) On Theoretical Sociology. The Free Press: 3972.Google Scholar
Montesquieu (2008 [1721]) Persian Letters: A New Translation, trans. Margaret Mauldon. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William (1994) “Climate and economic development: Climates past and climate change future.Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics, 1993.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1991) “Institutions.Journal of Economic Perspectives 5 (1): 97112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1993) “Economic performance through time.” Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel, http://www.nobelprize.org (accessed April 20, 2021).Google Scholar
Nunn, Nathan, and Diego, Puga (2012) “Ruggedness: The blessing of bad geography in Africa.The Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (1): 2036.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orchid Project (2020) www.orchidproject.org (accessed December 28, 2020).Google Scholar
Osborn, Alan (1996) “Cattle, co-wives, children, and calabashes.Journal of Anthropological Archaeology 15 (2): 107–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearl, Judea, and Dana, Mackenzie (2018) The Book of Why. Basic Books.Google Scholar
Pearsall, Sarah M. S. (2019) Polygamy: An Early American History. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Perel, Esther (2006) Mating in Captivity. Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Plavcan, J. Michael (2012) “Body size, size variation, and sexual size dimorphism in early homo.Current Anthropology 53 (S6): S409S423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polo, Marco (1958) The Travels. Trans. Ronald Latham. Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
Raffield, Ben, Price, Neil, and Collard, Mark (2017) “Male-biased operational sex ratios and the Viking phenomenon: An evolutionary anthropological perspective on Late Iron Age Scandinavian raiding.Evolution and Human Behavior 38 (3): 315–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., and Trebbi, F. (2004) “Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development.Journal of Economic Growth 9 (2): 131–65.Google Scholar
Rosário, Carmeliza (2008) “Desperate co-wives: The illegality of polygamy in the new Mozambican family law.” MP Thesis, University of Bergen.Google Scholar
Rose, Brian E. J. (2020) “Insolation, the climate laboratory,” https://brian-rose.github.io/ClimateLaboratoryBook/courseware/insolation.html (accessed November 9).Google Scholar
Roser, Max (2020) “Fertility rate,” https://ourworldindata.org/fertility-rate (accessed May 22).Google Scholar
Sampson, Robert J., Laub, John H., and Wimer, Christopher (2006) “Does marriage reduce crime? A counterfactual approach to within-individual causal effects.Criminology 44 (3): 465508.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheidel, Walter (2009) “Monogamy and polygyny.” Princeton/Stanford Working Papers in Classics, http://www.princeton.edu/˜pswpc/pdfs/scheidel/010903.pdf (accessed April 20, 2021).Google Scholar
Schulz, Jonathan F., Beauchamp, Jonathan P., and Henrich, Joseph (2019) “The church, intensive kinship, and global psychological variation.Science 366 (6466), doi: 10.1126/science.aau5141.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Seligson, Daniel and McCants, Anne E. C. (2021) “Co-evolving institutions and the paradox of informal constraints.” Journal of Institutional Economics, doi: 10.1017/S1744137420000600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya (2000) Development as Freedom. Anchor.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert (1985) “Economic history and economics.American Economic Review 75 (2): 328–31.Google Scholar
Tertilt, Michele (2005) “Polygyny, fertility, and savings.Journal of Political Economy 113 (6): 1341–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tetrault-Farber, Gabrielle (2015) “Chechen official’s call to legalize polygamy stirs social debate.” The Moscow Times, May 19.Google Scholar
The Economist (2016) “Democracy index: Revenge of the ‘deplorables.’” A report by The Economist Intelligence Unit, https://www.eiu.com/topic/democracy-index (accessed August 8, 2019).Google Scholar
Tignor, Robert (1972) “The Maasai warriors: Pattern maintenance and violence in colonial Kenya.The Journal of African History 13 (2): 271–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Todd, Emmanuel (1985) The Explanation of Ideology: Family Structure and Social Systems. Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Trevithick, Alan (1997) “On a panhuman preference for monandry: Is polyandry an exception?Journal of Comparative Family Studies 28 (3): 154–81.Google Scholar
UNICEF (2014) “Guyana: Multiple indicator cluster survey,” https://microdata.worldbank.org/index.php/catalog/2731 (accessed May 24, 2020).Google Scholar
UNICEF (2016) “UNICEF’s work on FGM/C,” www.unicef/org/media/files (accessed July 2, 2019).Google Scholar
Unisa, Sayeed, and Grace Bahalen, Mundu (2011) “Bigamy in India: Finding from National Family Health Survey.International Institute for Population Sciences.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver (2000) “The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead.Journal of Economic Literature 38 (3): 595613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witte, John Jr. (2015) The Western Case for Monogamy over Polygamy. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Womanstats (2020) “Physical security of women.” WomanStats Project Database, http://www.womanstats.org (accessed July 2, 2019).Google Scholar
World Bank (2018) Worldwide Governance Indicators, https://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/ (accessed November 20, 2020).Google Scholar
World Bank (2020a) Natural Resource Rents, https://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.TOTL.RT.ZS (accessed November 20, 2020).Google Scholar
World Bank (2020b) Popular Indicators, https://databank.worldbank.org (accessed November 20, 2020).Google Scholar
Zomer, R. J., Trabucco, A., Bossio, D. A., van Straaten, O., and Verchot, L. V. (2008) “Climate change mitigation: A spatial analysis of global land suitability for clean development mechanism afforestation and reforestation.Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment 126 (1/2): 6780.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zurndorfer, Harriett (2016) “Polygamy and masculinity in China: Past and present,” in Kam, Louie (ed.) Changing Chinese Masculinities: From Imperial Pillars of State to Global Real Men. Hong Kong University Press: 1333.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. McDermott’s polygamy scale: (A) tabulation and (B) histogram. Notes: 1A: (a) Multiple cohabitations: <2 percent; (b) multiple cohabitations: >2 percent; (c) only applies to select minorities and/or within enclaves; (d) w is the fraction, specified in percent, of women in plural marriages; and (e) no US agency compiles statistics on covert polygamous marriages. One source has reported, without documentation, that 50,000 to 100,000 Muslims live in polygamous households (Hagerty 2008). Another says, also without documentation, that 50,000 to 100,000 Black Muslims live in polygamous relationships (Al-Krenawi 2014). From these it seems fair to estimate that no more than 0.1 percent of American marriages are polygamous. In figure 1B, the vertical axis label (#) signifies the number of states in each classification category. The world according to McDermott’s coding scheme is evidently bimodal, cleaving along the line of customary and religious law’s view of polygamy.

Figure 1

Map 1. World map of 102${\cal P}$-states (in gray) and 75 ${\cal nP}$-states (in white).

Figure 2

Figure 2. Male-to-female sex ratios for 177 nations. Notes: (A) Sex ratios in the first four years of life and (B) sex ratios in the first decade after puberty. Means and medians for both age groups are about 1.05. Population weighted means are larger by about 0.03 owing to sex ratios greater than 1.12 in China and India. Five states—Qatar, UAE, Bahrain, Maldives, and Kuwait—have sex ratios after puberty exceeding 1.2, a fact that may be attributed to a preference for males in their immigrant workforces.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Hudson’s index of wealth transfers at marriage. Notes: (A) The distribution of wealth transfers at marriage per Hudson’s index in 73 ${\cal nP}$ states. (B) The distribution of wealth transfers at marriage per Hudson’s index in 100 ${\cal P}$ states. (C) The cumulative distribution functions of the ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$ distributions. The maximum difference, $\delta $, of these is approximately 0.9, generating a vanishingly small pks, from which we conclude that the distributions are distinct, as expected.

Figure 4

Table 1. Eleven social conventions and descriptive statistics of their distributions in ${\cal P}$ and ${\cal nP}$

Figure 5

Figure 4. The cumulative distribution functions of ${\cal P}$ (to the right) and ${\cal nP}$ (to the left) distributions of gS. Notes: Within the ${\cal nP}$ distribution, we identify members of the EMP (black) and non-EMP (gray) subgroups. Though those two subgroups are themselves distinct, the distinction is modest compared to that between ${\cal P}$ and$\;{\cal nP}$ as a whole.

Figure 6

Table 2. Regional and or cultural traditions, nominal prevalences of plural marriage fraction c. 1900, and exemplary states

Figure 7

Figure 5. Distribution of prevalence of polygamous marriage in 1900.

Figure 8

Map 2. A micromeasure of gamos, g, mapped for 177 states. Note: The scale is such that deepest grays correspond to 22.5 percent prevalence in 1900.

Figure 9

Figure 6. Two views of development, $\mu $. Notes: (A) The correspondence between HDI and $\mu $ (r = 0.93). (B) The well-separated CDFs of \mu in ${\cal P}$ (left/gray) and$\;{\cal nP}$ (right/black).

Figure 10

Map 3. The map of$\mu $by nation. Note: The deepest grays correspond to the lowest states of development and white to the highest, or $\mu = \mp \;2$ respectively.

Figure 11

Table 3. Candidate proxies for sources of development across five categories

Figure 12

Figure 7. Five-parameter model selection. Notes: Each dot or polygon represents one of 648 different combinations of the 14 proxies. Black coloring signifies that g, the prevalence of male plural marriage, is one of the model variables. ${{\cal M}_5}$, the optimal five-parameter model, is represented by the five-sided polygon in the lower left corner. ${{\cal M}_4}$, the optimal four-parameter model (from which all measures of family structure are excluded), is represented by the four-sided polygon.

Figure 13

Table 4. ${{\cal M}_5}$ parameter summary table

Supplementary material: PDF

Seligson and McCants supplementary material

Appendix

Download Seligson and McCants supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 414.8 KB