Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-mp689 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T06:55:03.969Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

OVERLEVERAGING, FINANCIAL FRAGILITY, AND THE BANKING–MACRO LINK: THEORY AND EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 November 2017

Stefan Mittnik
Affiliation:
Ludwig-Maximilian-Universität München
Willi Semmler*
Affiliation:
New School for Social Research, ZEW, and University of Bielefeld
*
Address correspondence to: Willi Semmler, New School for Social Research, 79 Fifth Avenue, New York, NY 10003, USA; e-mail: semmlerw@newschool.edu.

Abstract

We analyze the consequences of overleveraging and the potential for destabilizing effects from financial- and real-sector interactions. In a theoretical model, we demonstrate that, in the presence of regime-dependent macro feedback relations, a highly leveraged banking system can result in instabilities and downward spirals. To investigate this question empirically, we analyze time series from eight advanced economies on industrial production and the components of the country-specific financial stress indices constructed by the IMF. Employing nonlinear, multiregime vector autoregressions, we examine how industrial production is affected by the individual risk drivers making up the indices. Our results strongly suggest that financial-sector stress has a substantial, nonlinear influence on economic activity and that individual risk drivers affect output rather differently across stress regimes and across groups of countries.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

A previous version, entitled “Estimating a Banking–Macro Model for Europe Using a Multi–regime VAR,” was presented at a conference on “The Future of the Euro and Europe,” Sapienza University, Rome, July 2013, organized by Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, at the 7th International Conference on Computational and Financial Econometrics, University of London, December 2013, and at the conference of the Society of Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, New York, April 2014. We want to thank Lilia Cavallari and participants of the conferences for valuable comments. We are especially grateful for communications with Markus Brunnermeier, James Ramsey, and Timo Teräsvirta. Willi Semmler would also like to thank the Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) for financial support. The research for this paper was partly conducted while Willi Semmler was a visiting researcher at the European Central Bank.

References

REFERENCES

Adrian, T., Moench, A., and Shin, H. S. (2010) Macro Risk Premium and Intermediary Balance Sheet Quantities. Federal Reserve Bank of New York staff report 428.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., and Gilchrist, S. (1999) The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. In Taylor, J. and Woodford, M. (eds.), Handbook of Macroeconomics, pp. 211241. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Bijlsma, M. J. and Zwart, G. T. J. (2013) The Financial Market in Europe, the United States and Japan. Bruegel working paper 2013/02.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. (1983) Debt and the current account deficit in Brazil. In Rudiger Dornbusch and Maurice Obstfeld (eds.), Financial Policies and the World Capital Market: The Problem of Latin American Countries, pp. 187198. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Leigh, D. (2013) Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers. IMF working paper WP/13/1.Google Scholar
Bohn, H. (2007) Are stationarity and cointegration restrictions really necessary for the intertemporal budget constraint? Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 18371847.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. (2009) Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007–2008. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23, 77100.Google Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. K. and Oehmke, M. (2012) Bubbles, Financial Crises and Systemic Risk. NBER working paper 18398.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. and Sannikov, Y. (2014) A macroeconomic model with a financial sector. American Economic Review 104 (2), 379421.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunnermeier, M. and Sannikov, Y. (2015) Monetary Analysis: Price and Financial Stability. Manuscript, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Bruno, R. and Dimand, R. W. (2009) The corridor of stability in Tobin's Keynesian model of recession and depression. International Journal of Applied Economics & Econometrics 17, 1725.Google Scholar
Cardarelli, R., Elekdag, S., and Lall, S. (2011) Financial stress and economic contractions. Journal of Financial Stability 7, 7897.Google Scholar
Chen, P. and Semmler, W. (2013) Financial Stress, Regime Switching and Macrodynamics: Theory and Empirics for the U.S., EU and Non-EU Countries. Working paper, Economics, the Open Access, Open Assessment E Journal, No. 2013-24.Google Scholar
Christensen, I. and Dib, A. (2008) The financial accelerator in an estimated New Keynesian model. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11, 155178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corsetti, G., Meier, A., and Mueller, G. (2012) What Determines Government Spending Multipliers? IMF working paper 12/150, International Monetary Fund.Google Scholar
De Grauwe, P. and Ji, Y. (2012) Self-Fulfilling Crises in the Eurozone: An Empirical Test. Center for European Policy Studies.Google Scholar
De Grauwe, P. and Macchiarelli, C. (2013) Animal Spirits and Credit Cycles. CESIFO working paper 4480, November.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimand, R. W. (2005) Fisher, Keynes, and the corridor of stability. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 64, 185199.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. and Krugman, P. (2012) Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher–Minsky–Koo Approach. Manuscript, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Gerali, A., Neri, S., Sessa, L., and Signoretti, F. (2010) Credit and banking in a DSGE model of the euro area. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (1), 107141.Google Scholar
Gilchrist, S., Ortiz, A., and Zagrajsek, S. (2009) Credit Risk and the Macroeconomy: Evidence from an Estimated DSGE Model. Manuscript, Department of Economics, Boston University.Google Scholar
Gruene, L., Semmler, W., and Stieler, M. (2015) Using nonlinear model predictive control for dynamic decision problems in economics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 60, 112133.Google Scholar
Hansen, B. E. (2000) Sample splitting and threshold estimation. Econometrica 68, 575603.Google Scholar
He, Z. and Krishnamurthy, A. (2013) Intermediary asset pricing. American Economic Review, 103 (2), 732770.Google Scholar
Koop, G., Pesaran, M., and Potter, S. (1996) Impulse responses in nonlinear multivariate models. Journal of Econometrics 74, 119147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lorenzoni, G. and Werning, I. (2013) Slow Moving Debt Crises. Manuscript, MIT.Google Scholar
Mittnik, S. and Semmler, W. (2012) Regime dependence of the fiscal multiplier. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 83, 502522.Google Scholar
Mittnik, S. and Semmler, W. (2013) The real consequences of financial stress. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 14791499.Google Scholar
Mittnik, S. and Semmler, W. (2015) Overleveraging, Financial Fragility and the Banking–Macro Link: Theory and Emprical Evidence. ZEW, discussion paper 14-110.Google Scholar
Mittnik, S. and Zadrozny, P. (1993) Asymptotic distributions of impulse responses, step responses, and variance decompositions of estimated linear dynamic models. Econometrica 61, 857887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. S. (2009) This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Roch, F. and Uhlig, H. (2012), The Dynamics of Sovereign Debt Crises and Bailouts. Working paper, University of Chicago, CentER, NBER, CERP.Google Scholar
Schinasi, G. J. (2005) Preserving Financial Stability. International Monetary Fund, Economic Issues, 36.Google Scholar
Schleer, F. and Semmler, W. (2015) Financial sector and output dynamics in the Euro area: Non-linearities reconsidered. Journal of Macroeconomics 46, 235263.Google Scholar
Schleer, F., Semmler, W., and Illig, J. (2014) Overleveraging in the Banking Sector: Evidence from Europe. ZEW, Discussion Paper 14-066Google Scholar
Semmler, W. and Bernard, L. (2012) Boom–bust cycles; Leveraging, complex securities and asset prices. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 81, 442465.Google Scholar
Stein, J. L. (2011) The Diversity of Debt Crises in Europe. CESIFO working paper 3348, Category 6: Fiscal Policy; Macroeconomics and Growth, February.Google Scholar
Stein, J. L. (2012) Stochastic Optimal Control and the US Financial Crisis. Heidelberg, Germany: Springer Publishing House.Google Scholar
Tong, H. (1978) On a threshold model. In Chen, C. H. (ed.), Pattern Recognition and Signal Processing. Amsterdam: Kluwer.Google Scholar
Tong, H. (1983) Threshold Models in Non-linear Time Series Analysis. New York: Springer–Verlag.Google Scholar
Tsay, R. S. (1998) Testing and modelling multivariate threshold models. Journal of the American Statistical Association 93, 11881212.Google Scholar