Hostname: page-component-77c89778f8-rkxrd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-07-20T19:56:05.110Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

LONGEVITY AND TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 September 2017

Agnieszka Gehringer*
Affiliation:
University of Göttingen
Klaus Prettner
Affiliation:
University of Hohenheim
*
Address correspondence to: Agnieszka Gehringer, Department of Economics, University of Göttingen, Platz der Göttinger Sieben 3, 37073 Göttingen, Germany; e-mail: agnieszka.gehringer@wiwi.uni-goettingen.de.

Abstract

We analyze the impact of increasing longevity on technological progress within an overlapping generations research and development (R&D)-based growth framework and test the model's implication on Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) data from 1960 to 2011. The central hypothesis is that—by raising the incentives of households to invest in physical capital and in R&D—decreasing mortality positively affects technological progress and productivity growth. The empirical results confirm the theoretical prediction. This implies that the demographic changes we observed in industrialized economies over the last decades were not detrimental to economic prosperity, at least as far as technological progress and productivity growth are concerned.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We would like to thank the editor, William A. Barnett, an associate editor, an anonymous referee, Cristiano Antonelli, Giuseppe Bertola, James Fenske, Freddy Heylen, Andreas Irmen, Anastasia Litina, Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Alexia Prskawetz, Russell Thomson, the participants at the Annual Meeting of the German Economic Association 2016, the 1st CREA Workshop on Aging, Culture, and Comparative Development 2016, the MoPAct Workshop on Economic Aspects of Demographic Change 2016, and seminar participants at the University of Göttingen and at the University of Hohenheim for valuable comments and suggestions.

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, Daron and Johnson, Simon (2007) Disease and development: The effect of life expectancy on economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 115 (6), 925985.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Johnson, Simon (2014) Disease and development: A reply to Bloom, Canning, and Fink. Journal of Political Economy 122 (6), 13671375.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Howitt, Peter (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60 (2), 323351.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Howitt, Peter, and Murtin, Fabrice (2011) The relationship between health and growth: When Lucas meets Nelson-Phelps. Review of Economics and Institutions 2 (1), 124.Google Scholar
Anderson, Theodore W. and Hsiao, Cheng (1982) Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data. Journal of Econometrics 18 (1), 4782.Google Scholar
Arellano, Manuel and Bond, Stephen (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies 58 (2), 277297.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. and Lee, Jong-Wha (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics 104, 184198.Google Scholar
Ben-Porath, Yoram (1967) The production of human capital and the life cycle of earnings. Journal of Political Economy 75 (4), 352365.Google Scholar
Bernard, Andrew B., Bradford Jensen, J., and Schott, Peter K. (2006) Trade costs, firms and productivity. Journal of Monetary Economics 53 (5), 917937.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. (1985) Debt, deficits and finite horizons. Journal of Political Economy 93 (2), 223247.Google Scholar
Bloom, David, Canning, David, and Fink, Günther (2014) Disease and development revisited. Journal of Political Economy 122 (6), 13551366.Google Scholar
Bloom, David, Canning, David, and Fink, Günther (2010) Implications of population ageing for economic growth. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26 (4), 583612.Google Scholar
Bloom, David, Canning, David, and Graham, Bryan (2003) Longevity and life-cycle savings. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 105 (3), 319338.Google Scholar
Blundell, Richard and Bond, Stephen (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data methods. Journal of Econometrics 87 (1), 115143.Google Scholar
Borghans, Lex and ter Well, Bas (2002) Do older workers have more trouble using a computer than younger workers? Economics of Skills Obsolescence 21, 139173.Google Scholar
Boucekkine, Raouf, de La Croix, David, and Licandro, Omar (2002) Vintage human capital, demographic trends, and endogenous growth. Journal of Economic Theory 104 (2), 340375.Google Scholar
Boucekkine, Raouf, de La Croix, David, and Licandro, Omar (2003) Early mortality decline at the dawn of modern growth. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 105 (3), 401418.Google Scholar
Brezis, Elise and Ferreira, Rodolphe Dos Santos (2016) Endogenous fertility with a sibship size effect. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (8), 20462066.Google Scholar
Bruno, G. S. F. (2005a) Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters 87, 361366.Google Scholar
Bruno, Giovanni S. F. (2005b) Estimation and inference in dynamic unbalanced panel-data models with a small number of individuals. The Stata Journal 5 (4), 473500.Google Scholar
Bucci, Albert (2008) Population growth in a model of economic growth with human capital accumulation and horizontal R&D. Journal of Macroeconomics 30 (3), 11241147.Google Scholar
Bucci, Alberto (2013) Returns to specialization, competition, population, and growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (10), 20232040.Google Scholar
Bucci, Alberto and Raurich, Xavier (2017) Population and economic growth under different growth engines. German Economic Review 18 (2), 182211.Google Scholar
Bun, Maurice J. G. and Kiviet, Jan F. (2003) On the diminishing returns of higher order terms in asymptotic expansions of bias. Economics Letters 79 (2), 145152.Google Scholar
Canton, Erik J. F., de Groot, Henri L. F., and Nahuis, Richard (2002) Vested interests, population ageing and technology adoption. European Journal of Political Economy 18 (4), 631652.Google Scholar
Caselli, Francesco, Esquivel, Gerardo, and Lefort, Fernando (1996) Reopening the convergence debate: A new look at cross-country growth empirics. Journal of Economic Growth 1 (3), 363389.Google Scholar
Cass, David (1965) Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation. Review of Economic Studies 32 (3), 233240.Google Scholar
Cervellati, Matteo and Sunde, Uwe (2011) Life expectancy and economic growth: The role of the demographic transition. Journal of Economic Growth 16 (2), 99133.Google Scholar
Cervellati, Matteo and Sunde, Uwe (2013) Life expectancy, schooling, and lifetime labor supply: Theory and evidence revisited. Econometrica 81 (5), 20552086.Google Scholar
Chu, Angus C., Cozzi, Guido, and Liao, Chih-Hsing (2013) Endogenous fertility and human capital in a Schumpeterian growth model. Journal of Population Economics 26 (1), 181202.Google Scholar
Crespo-Cuaresma, Jesus, Lábaj, Martin, and Pružinský, Patrik (2014) Prospective ageing and economic growth in Europe. Journal of the Economics of Ageing 3, 5057.Google Scholar
de la Croix, David and Licandro, Omar (1999) Life expectancy and endogenous growth. Economics Letters 65 (2), 255263.Google Scholar
de la Croix, David and Licandro, Omar (2013) The child is father of the man: Implications for the demographic transition. Economic Journal 123, 236261.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A. (1965) National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review 55 (5), 11261150.Google Scholar
Diene, Mbaye, Diene, Bity, and Azomahou, Théophile T. (2016) Human capital productivity, endogenous growth, and welfare: The role of uncerntainty. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (8), 20672092.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K. and Stiglitz, Joseph E. (1977) Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity. American Economic Review 67 (3), 297308.Google Scholar
Feenstra, Robert C., Inklaar, Robert, and Timmer, Marcel (2013) The next generation of the Penn World Table. Available for download at www.ggdc.net/pwt.Google Scholar
Feyrer, James (2007) Demographics and productivity. Review of Economics and Statistics 89 (1), 100109.Google Scholar
Funke, Michael and Strulik, Holger (2000) On endogenous growth with physical capital, human capital and product variety. European Economic Review 44 (3), 491515.Google Scholar
Gehringer, Agnieszka (2013) Financial liberalization, growth, productivity and capital accumulation: The case of European integration. International Review of Economics & Finance 25, 291309.Google Scholar
Gertler, Mark (1999) Government debt and social security in a life-cycle economy. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 50, 61110.Google Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. and Helpman, Elhanen (1991) Quality ladders in the theory of economic growth. Review of Economic Studies 58 (1), 4361.Google Scholar
Grossmann, Volker, Steger, Thomas M., and Trimborn, Timo (2013) Dynamically optimal R&D subsidization. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (3), 516534.Google Scholar
Gruescu, Sandra (2007) Population Ageing and Economic Growth. Heidelberg: Physica-Verlag.Google Scholar
Ha, Joonkyung and Howitt, Peter (2007) Accounting for trends in productivity and R&D: A Schumpeterian critique of semi-endogenous growth theory. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39 (4), 733774.Google Scholar
Hauk, William R. and Wacziarg, Romain (2009) A Monte Carlo study of growth regressions. Journal of Economic Growth 14 (2), 103147.Google Scholar
Heer, Burkhard and Irmen, Andreas (2014) Population, pensions, and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 46, 5072.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J. and Mierau, Jochen O. (2010) Growth effects of consumption and labor-income taxation in an overlapping-generations life-cycle model. Macroeconomic Dynamics 14, 151175.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J. and Mierau, Jochen O. (2011). The individual life cycle and economic growth: An essay on demographic macroeconomics. De Economist 159 (1), 6387.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J. and Mierau, Jochen O. (2012). The individual life-cycle, annuity market imperfections and economic growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36, 876890.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J., Mierau, Jochen O., and Reijnders, Larie S. M. (2014) A tragedy of annuitization? Longevity insurance in general equilibrium. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18 (7), 16071634.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J. and Reijnders, Laurie (2017) Longevity shocks with age-dependent productivity growth. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance. doi:10.1017/S147474721600024X.Google Scholar
Heijdra, Ben J. and van der Ploeg, Frederick (2002) Foundations of Modern Macroeconomics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Heston, Alan, Summers, Robert, and Aten, Bettina (2012). Penn World Table version 7.1, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania, November 2012.Google Scholar
Hineline, David R. (2008) Parameter heterogeneity in growth regressions. Economics Letters 101, 126129.Google Scholar
Howitt, Peter (1999). Steady endogenous growth with population and R&D inputs growing. Journal of Political Economy 107 (4), 715730.Google Scholar
Irmen, Andreas (2017) Capital- and labor-saving technical change in an aging economy. International Economic Review 58 (1), 261285.Google Scholar
Irmen, Andreas and Litina, Anastasia (2016) Population Aging and Inventive Activity. CESifo working paper no. 5841.Google Scholar
Islam, Nazrul (1995) Growth empirics: A panel data approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (4), 11271170.Google Scholar
Jones, Charles I. (1995) R&D-based models of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 103 (4), 759783.Google Scholar
Jones, Charles I. (2002) Sources of U.S. economic growth in a world of ideas. American Economic Review 92 (1), 220239.Google Scholar
Judson, Ruth A. and Owen, Ann L. (1999) Estimating dynamic panel data models: A guide for macroeconomists. Economics Letters 65 (1), 915.Google Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem (2002) Does the mortality decline promote economic growth? Journal of Economic Growth 7 (4), 411439.Google Scholar
Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility, and human capital investment. Journal of Development Economics 70 (1), 103118.Google Scholar
Keller, Wolfgang (2002) Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American Economic Review 92 (1), 120142.Google Scholar
Kiviet, Jan F. (1995) On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 68 (1), 5378.Google Scholar
Koopmans, Tjalling C. (1965) On the concept of optimal economic growth. Academiae Scientiarum Scripta Varia 28 (1), 225300.Google Scholar
Kortum, Samuel (1997) Research, patenting and technological change. Econometrica 65 (6), 13891419.Google Scholar
Krueger, Dirk and Ludwig, Alexander (2007) On the consequences of demographic change for rates of returns on capital, and the distribution of wealth and welfare. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 4987.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Michael and Prettner, Klaus (2016a) Growth and welfare effects of health care in knowledge based economies. Journal of Health Economics 46, 100119.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Michael and Prettner, Klaus (2016b) Increasing Life Expectancy, Optimal Retirement, and Endogenous Growth. Mimeo.Google Scholar
Lindh, Thomas and Malmberg, Bo (1999) Age structure effects and growth in the OECD, 1950–1990. Journal of Population Economics 12 (3), 431449.Google Scholar
Lorentzen, Peter, McMillan, John, and Wacziarg, Romain (2008) Death and development. Journal of Economic Growth 13, 81124.Google Scholar
Maddala, Gangadharrao S. and Wu, Shaowen (2002) Cross-country growth regressions: Problems of heterogeneity, stability and interpretation. Applied Economics 32 (5), 635642.Google Scholar
Mankiw, Gregory N. and Weil, David N. (1989) The baby-boom, the baby-bust and the housing market. Regional Science and Urban Economics 19, 235258.Google Scholar
Miller, Stephen M. and Upadhyay, Mukti P. (2000) The effects of openness, trade orientation, and human capital on total factor productivity. Journal of Development Economics 63, 399423.Google Scholar
Nickell, Stephen S. (1981) Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica 49 (6), 11171126.Google Scholar
Peretto, Pietro F. (1998) Technological change and population growth. Journal of Economic Growth 3 (4), 283311.Google Scholar
Peterson, Peter G. (1999) Gray dawn: The global aging crisis. Foreign Affairs (January/February).Google Scholar
Prettner, Klaus (2013) Population aging and endogenous economic growth. Journal of Population Economics 26 (2), 811834.Google Scholar
Prettner, Klaus and Strulik, Holger (2017) Technology, trade, and growth: The role of education. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20 (5), 13811394.Google Scholar
Prettner, Klaus and Trimborn, Timo (2016) Demographic change and R&D-based economic growth. Economica. doi:10.1111/ecca.12195.Google Scholar
Pritchett, Lant (2001) Where has all the education gone? World Bank Economic Review 15 (3), 367391.Google Scholar
Psacharopoulos, George (1994) Returns to investment in education: A global update. World Development 22 (9), 13251343.Google Scholar
Reinhart, V. R. (1999) Death and taxes: Their implications for endogenous growth. Economics Letters 62 (3), 339345.Google Scholar
Romer, Paul (1990) Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98 (5), 71102.Google Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey D. and Warner, Andrew M. (1997) Fundamental sources of long-run growth. American Economic Review 87 (2), 184188.Google Scholar
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier S. (1997). I Just Ran Four Million Regressions. NBER working paper 6252.Google Scholar
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier S., Doppelhofer, Gernot, and Miller, Ronald I. (2004) Determinants of long-term growth: A Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. American Economic Review 94 (4), 813835.Google Scholar
Segerström, Paul S. (1998) Endogenous growth without scale effects. American Economic Review 88 (5), 12901310.Google Scholar
Shastry, Gauri K. and Weil, David N. (2003) How much of cross-country income variation is explained by health? Journal of the European Economic Association 1 (2–3), 387396.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70 (1), 6594.Google Scholar
Strulik, Holger (2005) The role of human capital and population growth in R&D-based models of economic growth. Review of International Economics 13 (1), 129145.Google Scholar
Strulik, Holger, Prettner, Klaus, and Prskawetz, Alexia (2013) The past and future of knowledge-based growth. Journal of Economic Growth 18 (4), 411437.Google Scholar
The Economist (2004) Demographic change: Old Europe. The Economist. September 30th 2004.Google Scholar
Weil, David N. (2007) Accounting for the effect of health on economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (3), 12651306.Google Scholar
WHO (2012) Strategy and action plan for healthy ageing in europe, 2012–2020. WHO, Regional Committee for Europe. Available on: http://www.euro.who.int/_data/assets/pdf_file/0008/175544/RC62wd10Rev1-Eng.pdf.Google Scholar
World Bank (2014) World Development Indicators & Global Development Finance Database. Available on: http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators.Google Scholar
Yaari, Menahem E. (1965) Uncertain lifetime, life insurance and the theory of the consumer. Review of Economic Studies 32 (2), 137150.Google Scholar
Young, Alwyn (1998). Growth without scale effects. Journal of Political Economy 106 (5), 4163.Google Scholar
Zhang, Jie and Zhang, Junsen (2005) The effect of life expectancy on fertility, saving, schooling and economic growth: Theory and evidence. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 107 (1), 4566.Google Scholar