Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-jbqgn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-25T14:13:14.899Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HOUSING WEALTH REALLOCATION BETWEEN SUBPRIME AND PRIME BORROWERS DURING RECESSIONS

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 March 2021

Ayse Sapci*
Affiliation:
Utah State University
Nam T. Vu
Affiliation:
Miami University
*
Address correspondence to: Ayse Sapci, Department of Economics and Finance, Utah State University, 3565 Old Main Hill, Logan, UT 84322-3565, USA. email: ayse.sapci@usu.edu. Phone: 435 797 2332.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

The Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) indicates that, unlike subprime borrowers, prime borrowers are more likely to own investment homes during recessions than during recoveries. Drawing on this empirical fact, we present and estimate a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model that distinguishes between borrowers through their credit access. We find that the relative ease of credit access among borrowers explains the divergence in investment homeownership seen in the data. This divergence is amplified when subprime borrowers are subject to lax credit conditions prior to a financial shock or when the nominal interest rate is constrained at the zero lower bound (ZLB). An expansionary monetary policy helps bridge this gap across borrowers.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press 2021

References

Aaronson, D. and French, E. (2009) The effects of progressive taxation on labor supply when hours and wages are jointly determined. The Journal of Human Resources 44, 386408.Google Scholar
Adelino, M., Schoar, A. and Severino, F. (2017) Dynamics of housing debt in the recent boom and great recession. Working Paper 23502, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Albanesi, S., De Giorgi, G. and Nosal, J. (2017) Credit growth and the financial crisis: A new narrative. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alpanda, S. and Zubairy, S. (2016) Housing and tax policy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 48, 485512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amromin, G. and Paulson, A. L. (2010) Default rates on prime and subprime mortgages: Differences and similarities. Chicago Fed Research Review.Google Scholar
Aoki, K., Proudman, J. and Vlieghe, G. (2004) House prices, consumption, and monetary policy: A financial accelerator approach. Journal of financial intermediation 13, 414435.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (1989) Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American Economic Review 79, 1431.Google Scholar
Bernanke, B. S., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1999) The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework. Handbook of Macroeconomics 1, 13411393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, J. R. and Hercowitz, Z. (2005) The role of collateralized household debt in macroeconomic stabilization. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, M., Garriga, C. and Schlagenhauf, D. E. (2009) Accounting for changes in the homeownership rate. International Economic Review 50, 677726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charles, K. K. and Hurst, E. (2002) The transition to home ownership and the black-white wealth gap. Review of Economics and Statistics 84, 281297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, I., Corrigan, P., Mendicino, C. and Nishiyama, S.-I. (2016) Consumption, housing collateral and the Canadian business cycle. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d’économique 49, 207236.Google Scholar
Christensen, I. and Dib, A. (2008) The financial accelerator in an estimated new Keynesian model. Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 155178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Motto, R. and Rostagno, M. (2004) The great depression and the Friedman-Schwartz hypothesis. Tech. rep., National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eickmeier, S. and Hofmann, B. (2013) Monetary policy, housing booms, and financial (IM) balances. Macroeconomic Dynamics 17, 830.Google Scholar
Favilukis, J., Kohn, D., Ludvigson, S. and Van Nieuwerburgh, S. G. (2013) International capital flows and house prices: Theory and evidence. Housing and the Financial Crisis, 235299.Google Scholar
Ferreira, F. and Gyourko, J. (2015) A new look at the U.S. foreclosure crisis: Panel data evidence of prime and subprime borrowers from 1997 to 2012. Working Paper 21261, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Foote, C. L., Loewenstein, L. and Willen, P. S. (2016) Cross-sectional patterns of mortgage debt during the housing boom: Evidence and implications. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Working Paper.Google Scholar
Forlati, C. and Lambertini, L. (2011) Risky mortgages in a DSGE model. International Journal of Central Banking.Google Scholar
Greenwald, D. (2018) The Mortgage Credit Channel of Macroeconomic Transmission. MIT Sloan Research Paper.Google Scholar
Guerrieri, V. and Lorenzoni, G. (2017) Credit crises, precautionary savings, and the liquidity trap. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 132, 14271467.Google Scholar
Hobijn, B. and Ravenna, F. (2010) Loan securitization and the monetary transmission mechanism. IMF Working Paper.Google Scholar
Huo, Z. and Rios-Rull, J.-V. (2016) Financial frictions, asset prices, and the great recession. Working Paper, 155.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review 95, 739764.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. (2015a) Financial business cycles. Review of Economic Dynamics 18, 140163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iacoviello, M. (2015b) OccBin: A toolkit for solving dynamic models with occasionally binding constraints easily. Journal of Monetary Economics 70, 2238.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, M. and Pavan, M. (2013) Housing and debt over the life cycle and over the business cycle. Journal of Monetary Economics 60, 221238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jeske, K. and Liu, Z. (2013) Should the Central Bank be concerned about housing prices? Macroeconomic Dynamics 17, 2953.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G. E. and Tambalotti, A. (2015) Credit supply and the housing boom. Chicago Fed Working Paper.Google Scholar
Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G. E. and Tambalotti, A. (2016) A simple model of subprime borrowers and credit growth. New York Fed Staff Report, 126.Google Scholar
Kaplan, G., Mitman, K. and Violante, G. L. (2016) Non-durable consumption and housing net worth in the great recession: Evidence from easily accessible data. Working Paper 22232, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J. (1997) Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105, 211248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krause, M. U., Lopez-Salido, D. and Lubik, T. A. (2008) Inflation dynamics with search frictions: A structural econometric analysis. Journal of Monetary Economics 55, 892916.Google Scholar
Krueger, D., Mitman, K. and Perri, F. (2016) Macroeconomics and household heterogeneity. Handbook of Macroeconomics 2, 843921.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambertini, L., Nuguer, V. and Uysal, P. (2017) Mortgage default in an estimated model of the US housing market. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 76, 171201.Google Scholar
Lambie-Hanson, L., Li, W. and Slonkosky, M. (2019) Leaving households behind: Institutional investors and the U.S. housing recovery. Working Papers 19-1, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia.Google Scholar
Liu, Z., Wang, P. and Zha, T. (2013) Land-price dynamics and macroeconomic fluctuations. Econometrica 81, 11471184.Google Scholar
Mian, A., Rao, K. and Sufi, A. (2013) Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic slump. Quarterly Journal of Economics 128, 16871726.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2009) The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: Evidence from the U.S. mortgage default crisis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 14491496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mian, A. and Sufi, A. (2016) Who bears the cost of recessions? The role of house prices and household debt. Handbook of Macroeconomics 2, 255296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miao, J. and Ngo, P. V. (2019) Does calvo meet rotemberg at the zero lower bound? Macroeconomic Dynamics, 122.Google Scholar
Philippon, T. and Midrigan, V. (2011) Household leverage and the recession. Working Paper 16965, National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Segal, L. M., Sullivan, D. G., et al. (1998) Trends in homeownership: Race, demographics, and income. Economic Perspectives-Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago 22, 5372.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39, 195214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vu, N. T. (2020) Price flexibility and output volatility under menu costs. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 124.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Sapci and Vu supplementary material

Sapci and Vu supplementary material

Download Sapci and Vu supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 493.5 KB