Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-hgkh8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-29T11:03:54.529Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Digging deeper into Hardin's pasture: the complex institutional structure of ‘the tragedy of the commons’

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 March 2014

DANIEL H. COLE*
Affiliation:
Maurer School of Law and School of Public and Environmental Affairs, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USAVincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47408, USA
GRAHAM EPSTEIN*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, School of Public and Environmental Affairs, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USAVincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47408, USA
MICHAEL D. MCGINNIS*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, School of Public and Environmental Affairs, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47405, USAVincent and Elinor Ostrom Workshop in Political Theory and Policy Analysis, Indiana University, Bloomington, IN 47408, USA

Abstract

A revised application of Ostrom's (Ostrom, 2007) Social-Ecological System (SES) framework to Hardin's ‘tragedy of the commons’ (Hardin, G. (1968), Science, 162(3859): 1243–1248) demonstrates that its institutional structure is more complex than either Hardin or Ostrom had imagined. The ‘tragedy’ arises from several interacting resources and institutions. If the grass on the pasture was not subject to appropriation, the cattle were not privately owned, or property- and contract-enforcement institutions supporting market exchange were absent, then the ‘tragedy of the commons’ would not have arisen regardless of the open-access pasture. This paper highlights the utility of the SES framework and the care required to apply it precisely to specific social-ecological situations.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acheson, J. M. (2006), ‘Institutional Failure in Resource Management’, Annual Review of Anthropology, 35 (1): 117134.Google Scholar
Agrawal, A. and Yadama, G. (1997), ‘How Do Local Institutions Mediate Market and Population Pressures on Resources? Forest Panchayats in Kumaon, India’, Development and Change, 28 (3): 435465.Google Scholar
Andersen, P. (trans) (1983), ‘On Rent of Fishing Grounds: A Translation of Jens Warming's 1911 Article, with an Introduction’, History of Political Economy, 15 (3): 391396.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Araral, E. (2013), ‘What Makes Socio-Ecological Systems Robust? An Institutional Analysis of the 2,000 Year-Old Ifugao Society’, Human Ecology, 41 (6): 859870.Google Scholar
Araral, E. (2014), ‘Ostrom, Hardin and the Commons: A Critical Appreciation and a Revisionist View’, Environmental Science & Policy, 36: 1123.Google Scholar
Aristotle (1941), The Basic Works of Aristotle, McKeon, R. (ed. and trans.), New York, NY: Random House, pp. 11271324.Google Scholar
Arnold, E. C. (1921), ‘The Law of Possession Governing the Acquisition of Animals Ferae Naturae’, American Law Review, 55 (3): 393404.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Baland, J.-M. and Platteau, J.-P. (1996), Halting Degradation of Natural Resources, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ban, N. C., Mills, M., Tam, J., Hicks, C. C., Klain, S., Stoeckl, N., Bottrill, M. C., Levine, J., Pressey, R. L., Satterfield, T., and Chan, K. M. A. (2013), ‘A Social-Ecological Approach to Conservation Planning: Embedding Social Considerations’, Frontiers in Ecology and the Environment, 11 (4): 194202.Google Scholar
Basurto, X. and Ostrom, E. (2009), ‘Beyond the Tragedy of the Commons’, Economia delle fonti di energia e dell'ambiente, 52 (1): 3560.Google Scholar
Birks, P. and McLeod, G. (trans.) (1987), Justinian's Institutes, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Blanco, E. (2011), ‘A Social-Ecological Approach to Voluntary Environmental Initiatives: The Case of Nature-Based Tourism’, Policy Sciences, 44 (1): 3552.Google Scholar
Brook, B. W., Sodhi, N. S., and Ng, P. K. L. (2003), ‘Catastrophic Extinctions Follow Deforestation in Singapore’, Nature, 424 (6947): 420426.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chhatre, A. and Agrawal, A. (2009), ‘Trade-Offs and Synergies Between Carbon Storage and Livelihood Benefits from Forest Commons’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 106 (42): 1766717670.Google Scholar
Cinner, J. E., McClanahan, T. R., MacNeil, M. A., Graham, N. A. J., Daw, T. M., Ahmad, Mukminin, Feary, D. A., et al. (2012), ‘Comanagement of Coral Reef Social-Ecological Systems’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 109 (14): 52195222.Google Scholar
Clark, C. W. (1973a), ‘The Economics of Overexploitation’, Science, 181: 630634.Google Scholar
Clark, C. W. (1973b), ‘Profit Maximization and the Extinction of Animal Species’, Journal of Political Economy, 81 (4): 950961.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clement, F. (2010), ‘Analysing Decentralised Natural Resource Governance: Proposition for a “Politicised” Institutional Analysis and Development Framework’, Policy Sciences, 43 (2): 129156.Google Scholar
Cole, D. H. (2002), Pollution and Property: Comparing Ownership Institutions for Environmental Protection, Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cole, D. H. and Grossman, P. Z. (2010), ‘Institutions Matter! Why the Herder Problem is not a Prisoner's Dilemma’, Theory and Decision, 69 (2): 219231.Google Scholar
Cole, D. H. and E. Ostrom (2012), ‘The Variety of Property Systems and Rights in Natural Resources’, in Cole, D. H. and Ostrom, E. (eds.), Property in Land and Other Resources, Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, pp. 3764.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. S. (1987), ‘Norms as Social Capital’, in Radnitzky, G. and Bernholz, P. (eds.), Economic Imperialism: The Economic Approach Applied Outside the Field of Economics, New York, NY: Paragon House, pp. 133155.Google Scholar
Cox, M., Arnold, G., and Tomas, S. Villamayor (2010), ‘A Review of Design Principles for Community-Based Natural Resource Management’, Ecology and Society, 15 (4): 38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, S. E. S. and Ostrom, E. (1995), ‘A Grammar of Institutions’, American Political Science Review, 89 (3): 582600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edmondson, W. T., Anderson, G. C., and Peterson, D. R. (1956), ‘Artificial Eutrophication of Lake Washington’, Limnology and Oceanography, 1 (1): 4753.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (2007), Explaining Social Behavior: More Nuts and Bolts for the Social Sciences, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ensminger, J. and Rutten, A. (1991), ‘The Political Economy of Changing Property Rights: Dismantling a Pastoral Commons’, American Ethnologist, 18 (4): 683699.Google Scholar
Epstein, G., Vogt, J. M., Mincey, S. K., Cox, M., and Fischer, B. (2013), ‘Missing Ecology: Integrating Ecological Perspectives with the Social-Ecological System Framework’, International Journal of the Commons, 7 (2): 432453.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feeny, D., Berkes, F., McCay, B. J., and Acheson, J. M. (1990), ‘The Tragedy of the Commons: Twenty-Two Years Later’, Human Ecology, 18 (1): 119.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., and Gächter, S. (2002), ‘Strong Reciprocity, Human Cooperation, and the Enforcement of Social Norms’, Human Nature, 13 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Fleischman, F., Boenning, K., Garcia-Lopez, G., Mincey, S., Schmitt-Harsh, M., Daedlow, K., Lopez, M. C., Basurto, X., Fischer, B., and Ostrom, E. (2010), ‘Disturbance, Response, and Persistence in Self-Organized Forested Communities: Analysis of Robustness and Resilience in Five Communities in Southern Indiana’, Ecology and Society, 15 (4): 9.Google Scholar
Folke, C., Pritchard, L., Berkes, F., Colding, J., and Svedin, U. (2007), ‘The Problem of Fit Between Ecosystems and Institutions: Ten Years Later’, Ecology and Society, 12 (1): 30.Google Scholar
Gordon, H. S. (1954), ‘The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery’, Journal of Political Economy, 62 (2): 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (2005), ‘Commitment, Coercion, and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Amsterdam, Netherlands: Springer, pp. 727786.Google Scholar
Gutiérrez, N. L., Hilborn, R., and Defeo, O. (2011), ‘Leadership, Social Capital and Incentives Promote Successful Fisheries’, Nature, 470 (7334): 386389.Google Scholar
Hardin, G. (1968), ‘The Tragedy of the Commons’, Science, 162 (3859): 12431248.Google Scholar
Hobbes, T. ([1651] 1994), Leviathan, Cambridge, MA: Hackett.Google Scholar
Holling, C. S. and Meffe, G. K. (1996), ‘Command and Control and the Pathology of Natural Resource Management’, Conservation Biology, 10 (2): 328337.Google Scholar
Hugo, V. ([1862] 1887), The Works of Victor Hugo, Hapgood, I. F. (trans.), New York, NY: Thomas Y. Crowell.Google Scholar
Ingham, J. H. (1900), Law of Animals: A Treatise on Property in Animals: Wild and Domestic and the Rights and Responsibilities Arising Therefrom, Philadelphia, PA: T & J Johnson.Google Scholar
Johnston, J. S. (2005), ‘The Rule of Capture and the Economic Dynamics of Natural Resource Use and Survival Under Open Access Management Regimes’, Environmental Law, 35 (4): 855898.Google Scholar
Larson, A. M. and Soto, F. (2008), ‘Decentralization of Natural Resource Governance Regimes’, Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 33 (1): 213239.Google Scholar
Libecap, G. D. (1989), Contracting for Property Rights, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ludwig, D., Hilborn, R., and Waters, C. (1993), ‘Uncertainty, Resource Exploitation and Conservation: Lessons from History’, Science, 260 (5104): 1736.Google Scholar
Mors, P. O. (1954), ‘Cattle in Buhaya’, Anthropology Quarterly, 27 (1): 2329.Google Scholar
Myers, R. A., Hutchings, J. A., and Barrowman, N. J. (1997), ‘Why Do Fish Stocks Collapse? The Example of Cod in Atlantic Canada’, Ecological Applications, 7 (1): 91106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1998), ‘A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action’, American Political Science Review, 92 (1): 122.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2007), ‘A Diagnostic Approach for Going Beyond Panaceas’, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 104 (39): 1518115187.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2009), ‘A General Framework for Analyzing Sustainability of Social-Ecological Systems’, Science, 325 (5939): 419422.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. and Cox, M. (2010), ‘Moving Beyond Panaceas: A Multi-Tiered Diagnostic Approach for Social-Ecological Analysis’, Environmental Conservation, 37 (4): 451463.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. (2008), The Intellectual Crisis in American Public Administration, 3rd edn, Tuscaloosa, AL: University of Alabama Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, V. and Ostrom, E. (1997), ‘Public Goods and Public Choices’, in Savas, E. S. (ed.), Alternatives for Delivering Public Services: Toward Improved Performance, Boulder, CO: Westview Press, pp. 749.Google Scholar
Pierson, P. (2000), ‘Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics’, American Political Science Review, 94 (2): 251267.Google Scholar
Poteete, A. R. and Ostrom, E. (2004), ‘Heterogeneity, Group Size and Collective Action: The Role of Institutions in Forest Management’, Development and Change, 35 (3): 435461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rechlin, M. A., Hammett, A. L., Burch, W. R., and Song, Y. (2002), ‘Sharing the Wealth: A Comparative Study of the Distribution of Benefits from Community Forestry Management in Southern China and Nepal’, Journal of Sustainable Forestry, 15 (2): 123.Google Scholar
Ribot, J. C., Agrawal, A., and Larson, A. M. (2006), ‘Recentralizing While Decentralizing: How National Governments Reappropriate Forest Resources’, World Development, 34 (11): 18641886.Google Scholar
Scott, A. D. (1955), ‘The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership’, Journal of Political Economy, 63 (2): 116124.Google Scholar
Searle, J. R. (1995), The Construction of Social Reality, London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Simon, H. A. (1962), ‘The Architecture of Complexity’, Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106 (6): 467482.Google Scholar
Smith, A. ([1776] 1994), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, New York, NY: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Wade, R. (1994), Village Republics, San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.Google Scholar
Young, O. R. (2002), The Institutional Dimensions of Environmental Change: Fit, Interplay, and Scale, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Young, O. R. (2008), ‘The Architecture of Global Environmental Governance: Bringing Science to Bear on Policy’, Global Environmental Politics, 8 (1): 1432.Google Scholar