Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T09:06:30.280Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Nation, the State, and the First Industrial Revolution

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 December 2012

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © North American Conference of British Studies 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Kuznets, Simon, “The State as a Unit of Economic Growth,” Journal of Economic History 11, no. 1 (Winter 1951): 2541CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Work within the regional and global frameworks in recent decades has pointed up the limitations of an exclusive use of the nation as the unit of assessment and analysis. A very useful summary of the regional approach is provided in Hudson, Pat, ed., Regions and Industries: A Perspective on the Industrial Revolution in Britain (Cambridge, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a recent global approach, see Allen, R. C., The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective (Cambridge, 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 Supple, Barry, “The State and the Industrial Revolution, 1700–1914,” in The Fontana Economic History of Europe, ed. Cipolla, C. M. (London, 1971), 3:5Google Scholar.

3 There is a very large literature here, but see particularly: Pocock, J. G. A., The Discovery of Islands: Essays in British History (Cambridge, 2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Colley, Linda, Britons: Forging the Nation, 1707–1837 (New Haven, CT, 1992)Google Scholar; Ellis, Steven G. and Barber, Sarah, eds., Conquest and Union: Fashioning a British State, 1485–1725 (Harlow, 1995)Google Scholar; Burgess, Glenn, ed., The New British History: Founding a Modern State, 1603–1715 (London, 1999)Google Scholar; Eastwood, David and Brockliss, Laurence, eds., A Union of Multiple Identities: The British Isles, c. 1750–c. 1850 (Manchester, 1997)Google Scholar; McLean, Iain and McMillan, Alistair, State of the Union: Unionism and the Alternatives in the United Kingdom since 1707 (Oxford, 2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

4 By the “first industrial revolution” I mean that Britain’s economy was transformed in ways that involved a profound break with earlier economic arrangements and before other national economies. The case for such a view, albeit with a focus on England, is made very clear in Wrigley, E. A., Energy and the English Industrial Revolution (Cambridge, 2010)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 For example, the fine survey by Ron Harris largely ignores the national dimension: “Government and the Economy, 1688–1850,” in The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain, ed. Floud, Roderick and Johnson, Paul, 3 vols. (Cambridge, 2004), 1:204–37Google Scholar. Similarly, despite its title the interesting overview by Lars Magnusson is little concerned with what constituted nations: Nation, State and the Industrial Revolution: The Visible Hand (London, 2009)Google Scholar.

6 Harris, Bob, Politics and the Nation: Britain in the Mid-Eighteenth Century (Oxford, 2002)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Griffiths, Trevor, Hunt, Philip, and O’Brien, Patrick, “Scottish, Irish, and Imperial Connections: Parliament, the Three Kingdoms, and the Mechanization of Cotton Spinning in Eighteenth-Century Britain,” Economic History Review 61, no. 3 (August 2008): 625–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7 Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783 (London, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. As did other important general interpretations of state formation: Corrigan, Philip and Sayer, Derek, The Great Arch: English State Formation as Cultural Revolution (Oxford, 1985)Google Scholar; Braddick, M. J., State Formation in Early Modern England, c. 1550–1700 (Cambridge, 2000)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 For introductions to the large literature, see Viner, Jacob, Studies in the Theory of International Trade (New York, 1937)Google Scholar; Coleman, D. C., ed., Revisions in Mercantilism (London, 1969)Google Scholar; Magnusson, Lars, Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language (London, 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hont, Istvan, Jealousy of Trade: International Competition and the Nation-State in Historical Perspective (Cambridge, MA, 2005)Google Scholar.

9 For good summaries of his valuable approach, O’Brien, P. K., “The Britishness of the First Industrial Revolution and the British Contribution to the Industrialization of ‘Follower Countries’ on the Mainland, 1756–1914,” Diplomacy and Statecraft 8, no. 3 (November 1997): 4867CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and “Inseparable Connections: Trade, Economy, Fiscal State, and the Expansion of Empire, 1688–1815,” in The Oxford History of the British Empire, ed. Louis, W. R., 5 vols. (Oxford, 1998–2001), 2:5477Google Scholar.

10 Archenholz, J. W., A Picture of England (London, 1789), 2:190Google Scholar; Maurer, Michael, “Germany’s Image of Eighteenth-Century England,” in Britain and Germany Compared: Nationality, Society and Nobility in the Eighteenth Century, ed. Canning, Joseph and Wellenreuther, Hermann (Göttingen, 2001), 1336Google Scholar.

11 Langford, Paul, “Introduction: Time and Space,” in The Eighteenth Century: 1688–1815, ed. Langford, Paul (Oxford, 2002), 9Google Scholar; Giorgio Riello and P. K. O’Brien, “Reconstructing the Industrial Revolution: Analyses, Perceptions and Conceptions of Britain’s Precocious Transition to Europe’s First Industrial Society,” LSE Working Papers in Economic History 84/04 (London School of Economics and Political Science, Department of Economic History, London, 2004); Grieder, Josephine, Anglomania in France, 1740–1789: Fact, Fiction, and Political Discourse (Geneva, 1985)Google Scholar; Crouzet, François, Britain Ascendant: Comparative Studies in Franco-British Economic History (Cambridge, 1990), chap. 4Google Scholar; Tombs, Robert and Tombs, Isabelle, That Sweet Enemy: The French and the British from the Sun King to the Present (New York, 2006), 84Google Scholar.

12 Butterfield, Herbert, The Whig Interpretation of History (London, 1931)Google Scholar. English ideas of their national exceptionalism were reasonably well developed by 1600; surveyed in Wrightson, Keith E., “Kindred Adjoining Kingdoms: An English Perspective on the Social and Economic History of Early Modern Scotland,” in Scottish Society, 1500–1800, ed. Houston, R. A. and Whyte, I. D. (Cambridge, 1989), 246–50Google Scholar.

13 Landes, David S., The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: or Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor (New York, 1998), 219Google Scholar.

14 Greenfeld, Liah, The Spirit of Capitalism: Nationalism and Economic Growth (Cambridge, MA, 2001), 2224Google Scholar. Greenfeld considers English nationalism but British economic performance. There is a fine critical review of this book by Wakefield, Andre in the Journal of Modern History 75, no. 4 (December 2003): 926–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Greenfeld’s, LiahNationalism: Five Roads to Modernity (Cambridge, MA, 1992)Google Scholar.

15 Colley, Britons; Morton, Graeme, Unionist-Nationalism: Governing Urban Scotland, 1830–1860 (East Linton, 1999), 4Google Scholar.

16 Quoted in Whatley, Christopher A., Scottish Society, 1707–1830: Beyond Jacobitism, Towards Industrialization (Manchester, 2000), 118Google Scholar.

17 Smout, T. C., “Problems of Nationalism, Identity and Improvement in Later Eighteenth-Century Scotland,” in Improvement and Enlightenment, ed. Devine, T. M. (Edinburgh, 1989), 58Google Scholar. See also the works cited in n. 3 above.

18 Sowell, Thomas, Conquests and Cultures: An International History (New York, 1998), 32, 87Google Scholar. Similarly, North, Douglass C., “The Paradox of the West,” in The Origins of Modern Freedom in the West, ed. Davis, R. W. (Stanford, CA, 1995), 8Google Scholar.

19 Armitage, David, “The Political Economy of Britain and Ireland after the Glorious Revolution,” in Political Thought in Seventeenth Century Ireland: Kingdom or Colony, ed. Ohlmeyer, Jane (Cambridge, 2000), 231–32Google Scholar.

20 Brown noted this “golden thread” through British history since Magna Carta in speeches in 2006 and 2007. It is restated in his introduction to Himmelfarb, Gertrude, The Roads to Modernity: The British, French and American Enlightenments (London, 2008), xiiGoogle Scholar. A critical view of Brown’s motives is in Nairn, Tom, Gordon Brown: Bard of Britishness (Cardiff, 2006)Google Scholar. Greenspan, Alan, The Age of Turbulence: Adventures in a New World (New York, 2007), 276Google Scholar.

21 Quoted in Rothschild, Emma, “Condorcet and the Conflict of Values,” Historical Journal 39, no. 3 (September 1996): 684CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

22 Such arguments build upon major studies of the growth of the British state’s power dating back to Dickson. Dickson, P. G. M., The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in Public Credit, 1688–1756 (London, 1967)Google Scholar; Mathias, Peter and O’Brien, P. K., “Taxation in Britain and France, 1715–1810: A Comparison of the Social and Economic Incidence of Taxes Collected for the Central Government,” Journal of European Economic History 5, no. 3 (Winter 1976): 601–50Google Scholar; Brewer, Sinews of Power; Rodger, N. A. M., The Command of the Ocean: A Naval History of Britain, 1649–1815 (London, 2004)Google Scholar.

23 North, D. C. and Weingast, Barry R., “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” Journal of Economic History 49, no. 4 (December 1989): 830–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar. They acknowledged, at 804 n. 1, that since they emphasize “the problems the winners (the Whigs) sought to solve, it necessarily contains strong elements of ‘Whig’ history.”

24 Ferguson, Niall, The Cash Nexus: Money and Power in the Modern World, 1700–2000 (London, 2001), 20Google Scholar.

25 For recent views of Scotland: Whatley, Scottish Society, especially chap. 3; Devine, T. M., “The Modern Economy: Scotland and the Act of Union,” in The Transformation of Scotland: The Economy since 1700, ed. Devine, T. M., Lee, C. H., and Peden, G. C. (Edinburgh, 2005), 1333Google Scholar. The economic context of the Union negotiations have long been emphasized. See the references in two recent major interpretations: Whatley, C. A. and Patrick, Derek J., The Scots and the Union (Edinburgh, 2006)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Macinnes, Allan I., Union and Empire: The Making of the United Kingdom in 1707 (Cambridge, 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a penetrating review of these, see Harris, Bob, “The Anglo-Scottish Treaty of Union, 1707 in 2007: Defending the Revolution, Defeating the Jacobites,” Journal of British Studies 49, no. 1 (January 2010): 2846CrossRefGoogle Scholar. On Ireland, see Cullen, L. M., An Economic History of Ireland since 1660 (London, 1972)Google Scholar.

26 Wrigley, E. A., “Urban Growth and Agricultural Change: England and the Continent in the Early Modern Period,” Journal of Interdisciplinary History 15, no. 4 (Spring 1985): 683728CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27 The threshold of 10,000 persons for a town used here is, of course, a high one, and somewhat different patterns might be uncovered if lower thresholds were used.

28 For acts passed at Dublin, see The Statutes at Large, Passed in the Parliaments Held in Ireland, 21 vols. (Dublin, 1786–1804)Google Scholar. Short titles of both public and private acts prior to 1799 are listed in the index volume, vol. 8. Private acts for 1799 and 1800 have been taken from Journals of the House of Commons of … Ireland, vols. 18–19 (1796–1800). For Edinburgh, see The Acts of the Parliaments of Scotland, 12 vols. (Edinburgh, 1820–75)Google Scholar. Sources for acts passed at Westminster are Statutes at Large, ed. Ruffhead, Owen, 18 vols. (London, 1769–1800)Google Scholar. Research for this article was undertaken before the completion of both the Irish Legislation Database at http://www.qub.ac.uk/ild/ and the Records of the Parliaments of Scotland Prior to 1707 at http://www.rps.ac.uk/.

29 Because of the numbers involved, most acts have been categorized on the basis of their short title. For some questions about the categories employed, see Horwitz, Henry, “Changes in the Law and Reform of the Legal Order: England (and Wales) 1689–1760,” Parliamentary History 21, no. 3 (November 2002): 314–15Google Scholar.

30 Hurstfield, Joel, Freedom, Corruption and Government in Elizabethan England (London, 1973), 32Google Scholar.

31 Hoppit, Julian, “Patterns of Parliamentary Legislation, 1660–1800,” Historical Journal 39, no. 1 (March 1996): 109–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hoppit, Julian, ed., Failed Legislation, 1660–1800, Extracted from the Commons and Lords Journals (London, 1997)Google Scholar.

32 The full categories are listed in Hoppit, Failed Legislation, 30–32.

33 See Hoppit, Julian, “The Landed Interest and the National Interest, 1660–1800,” in Parliaments, Nations and Identities in Britain and Ireland, 1660–1850, ed. Hoppit, Julian (Manchester, 2003), 83102Google Scholar; Bogart, Dan and Richardson, Gary, “Making Property Productive: Reorganizing Rights to Real and Equitable Estates in Britain, 1660–1830,” European Review of Economic History 13, no. 1 (April 2009): 330CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Albert, William, The Turnpike Road System in England, 1663–1840 (Cambridge, 1972)Google Scholar; Pawson, Eric, Transport and Economy: The Turnpike Roads of Eighteenth-Century Britain (New York, 1977)Google Scholar.

34 Innes, Joanna, Inferior Politics: Social Problems and Social Policies in Eighteenth-Century Britain (Oxford, 2009), chap. 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 1 William and Mary, c. 12 was the foundational statute for the eighteenth-century Corn Laws, though based on earlier, lapsed, legislation; see Barnes, D. G., A History of the English Corn Laws (London, 1930)Google Scholar. The textile industries were subject to a range of regulation via legislation. Much of it is listed in Sickinger, Raymond L., “Regulation or Ruination: Parliament’s Consistent Pattern of Mercantilist Regulation of the English Textile Trade, 1660–1800,” Parliamentary History 19, no. 2 (June 2000): 211–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Surveyed in Morgan, Kenneth, “Mercantilism and the British Empire, 1688–1815,” in The Political Economy of British Historical Experience, 1688–1914, ed. Winch, Donald and O’Brien, P. K. (Oxford, 2002), 165–91Google Scholar.

37 Webb, Sidney and Webb, Beatrice, English Local Government from the Revolution to the Municipal Corporation Act: Statutory Authorities for Special Purposes (London, 1922)Google Scholar; Langford, Paul, Public Life and the Propertied Englishman, 1688–1798 (Oxford, 2001)Google Scholar; Handley, Stuart, “Local Legislative Initiatives for Economic and Social Development in Lancashire, 1689–1731,” Parliamentary History 9, no. 1 (March 1990): 1437CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Innes, Inferior Politics, chap. 3.

38 I address the question of the security of property rights in Julian Hoppit, “Compulsion, Compensation and Property Rights in Britain, 1688–1833,” Past and Present, no. 210 (2011): 93–128.

39 This question has been well explored in Joanna Innes, “Legislating for Three Kingdoms: How the Westminster Parliament Legislated for England, Scotland and Ireland, 1707–1830,” in Hoppit, Parliaments, Nations and Identities, 15–47.

40 20 George II, c. 42, § 3.

41 It should be noted that turnpikes were usually authorized for twenty-one years, requiring new legislation to extend their lives.

42 Brown, Keith M. and Mann, A. J., “Introduction,” in The History of the Scottish Parliament, ed. Brown, Keith M., 3 vols. (Edinburgh, 2004–10), 2:52Google Scholar.

43 Generally, see Brown, The History of the Scottish Parliament, vol. 2; Terry, C. S., The Scottish Parliament: Its Constitution and Procedure, 1603–1707 (Glasgow, 1905)Google Scholar.

44 In addition to the works cited in n. 25 above, see also Smout, T. C., “The Anglo-Scottish Union, 1707, 1: The Economic Background,” Economic History Review 16, no. 3 (April 1964): 455–67Google Scholar; Whatley, C. A., “Economic Causes and Consequences of the Union of 1707: A Survey,” Scottish Historical Review 68, no. 2 (October 1989): 150–81Google Scholar; Devine, T. M., “The Union of 1707 and Scottish Development,” Scottish Economic and Social History 4 (1984): 2340Google Scholar.

45 A number of historians have stated that Westminster passed only nine acts relating specifically to Scotland between 1727 and 1745; e.g., Shaw, J. S., The Management of Scottish Society, 1707–1764: Power, Nobles, Lawyers, Edinburgh Agents and English Influence (Edinburgh, 1983), 126Google Scholar; Devine, “The Union of 1707 and Scottish Development,” 30. It may be that what is meant is that only nine acts related to the whole of Scotland, but twenty-eight acts relating only to Scotland were passed in those years, many of them public and general, and eighty-one acts between 1707 and 1745.

46 See also Hayton, David W., “Introduction: The Long Apprenticeship,” Parliamentary History 20, no. 1 (February 2001): 126CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 Delaney, Ruth, Ireland’s Inland Waterways (Belfast, 1986)Google Scholar; Broderick, David, The First Toll Roads: Ireland’s Turnpike Roads, 1729–1858 (Cork, 2002)Google Scholar.

48 “Propertied interests” is obviously a catchall term, including owners of land, businesses, and rights, but there is not space here to differentiate them nor to consider the various ways they sought to attain their ends.

49 Emery, Frank, “Wales,” in The Agrarian History of England and Wales, ed. Thirsk, Joan, 8 vols. (Cambridge, 1967–2000), 5, pt. 1:393428Google Scholar. The suggestions in Cambrensis, Giraldus, Proposals for Enriching the Principality of Wales: Humbly Submitted to the Consideration of his Countrymen (London, 1755)Google Scholar, were wholly for improving agriculture. Industry was ignored.

50 The most concerted effort by the government in London to legislate for Scotland followed the failure of the Jacobite rising in 1746. See Jewell, B. F., “The Legislation Relating to Scotland after the ’45” (PhD diss., University of North Carolina, 1975)Google Scholar. More generally, Riley, P. W. J., The English Ministers and Scotland, 1707–1727 (London, 1964)Google Scholar; Shaw, The Management of Scottish Society.

51 Henretta, J. A., “Salutary Neglect”: Colonial Administration under the Duke of Newcastle (Princeton, NJ, 1972)Google Scholar.

52 Pagan, Theodora, The Convention of the Royal Burghs of Scotland (Glasgow, 1926)Google Scholar; Keith, T., “The Influence of the Convention of the Royal Burghs of Scotland on the Economic Development of Scotland before 1707,” Scottish Historical Review 10 (1913): 250–71Google Scholar; Bob Harris, Politics and the Nation, 63, and also “The Scots, the Westminster Parliament, and the British State in the Eighteenth Century,” in Hoppit, Parliaments, Nations, and Identities, 124–45.

53 The quotation is from Smout, T. C., “Scottish Landowners and Economic Growth, 1650–1850,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 11 (1964): 218Google Scholar; Hoppit, “The Landed Interest,” 94–95; Devine, T. M., “The Great Landowners of Lowland Scotland and Agrarian Change in the Eighteenth Century,” in Scottish Power Centres from the Early Middle Ages to the Twentieth Century, ed. Foster, Sally, Macinnes, Allan, and MacInnes, Ranald (Glasgow, 1998), 147–61Google Scholar.

54 Kelly, James, Poynings’ Law and the Making of Law in Ireland, 1660–1800 (Dublin, 2007)Google Scholar; Victory, I., “The Making of the 1720 Declaratory Act,” in Parliament, Politics and People: Essays in Eighteenth-Century Irish History, ed. O’Brien, Gerard (Dublin, 1989), 929Google Scholar.

55 Edie, Carolyn A., “The Irish Cattle Bills: A Study in Restoration Politics,” Transactions of the American Philosophical Society 60, no. 2 (February 1970): 166CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kearney, Hugh F., “The Political Background to English Mercantilism, 1695–1700,” Economic History Review 11, no. 3 (April 1959): 484–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Kelly, P. H., “The Irish Woollen Export Prohibition Act of 1699: Kearney Re-visited,” Irish Economic and Social History 7 (1980): 2243CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

56 Calendar of State Papers, Colonial Series, 1706–1708, June, ed. Headlam, C. (London, 1916), 426–27, 431Google Scholar.

57 O’Brien, Patrick, Griffiths, Trevor, and Hunt, Philip, “Political Components of the Industrial Revolution: Parliament and the English Cotton Textile Industry, 1660–1774,” Economic History Review 44 (1991): 395423CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

58 James, F. G., “Irish Smuggling in the Eighteenth Century,” Irish Historical Studies 12, no. 48 (September 1961): 299316CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cullen, L. M., Smuggling and the Ayrshire Economic Boom in the 1760s and 1770s (Ayr, 1994)Google Scholar; Nash, R. C., “The English and Scottish Tobacco Trades in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries: Legal and Illegal Trade,” Economic History Review 35, no. 3 (August 1982): 354–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Stott, R. M., “Revolution? What Revolution? Some Thoughts about Revestment,” Proceedings of the Isle of Man Natural and Antiquarian Society 11, no. 4 (2003–5): 541–52Google Scholar.

59 Hoppit, Julian, “Reforming Britain’s Weights and Measures, 1660–1824,” English Historical Review 108, no. 426 (January 1993): 82104CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

60 Julian Hoppit, “Bounties, the Economy and the State in Britain, 1689–1800,” in The Regulation of the Economy, 1660–1850, ed. P. Gauci (forthcoming); Anderson, J., Observations on the means of Exciting a Spirit of National Industry; Chiefly Intended to Promote the Agriculture, commerce, Manufactures, and Fisheries of Scotland (Edinburgh, 1777), 372Google Scholar.

61 Gambles, Anna, “Free Trade and State Formation: The Political Economy of Fisheries Policy in Britain and the United Kingdom, circa 1780–1850,” Journal of British Studies 39, no. 3 (July 2000): 292CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

62 Anderson, Observations, 460.

63 The National Archives (TNA): Public Record Office (PRO), T1/487, fol. 314. Innes, Joanna, “The Distinctiveness of the English Poor Laws, 1750–1850,” in Winch, and O’Brien, , The Political Economy of British Historical Experience, 381407Google Scholar; Solar, Peter, “Poor Relief and English Economic Development before the Industrial Revolution,” Economic History Review 48, no. 1 (February 1995): 122CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

64 Slack, Paul, From Reformation to Improvement: Public Welfare in Early Modern England (Oxford, 1999), esp. 80–81Google Scholar; Barnard, Toby, Improving Ireland? Projects, Prophets and Profiteers, 1641–1786 (Dublin, 2008)Google Scholar; Mitchison, Rosalind, “Patriotism and National Identity in Eighteenth Century Scotland,” in Nationality and the Pursuit of National Independence, ed. Moody, T. W. (Belfast, 1978), 7395Google Scholar; Devine, T. M., ed., Lairds and Improvement in the Scotland of the Enlightenment (Dundee, 1979)Google Scholar; Tarlow, Sarah, The Archaeology of Improvement in Britain, 1750–1850 (Cambridge, 2007), 1018CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jenkins, G. H., The Foundations of Modern Wales: Wales, 1642–1780 (Oxford, 1987), 280Google Scholar.

65 “The Reactive State: English Governance and Society, 1689–1750,” in Stilling the Grumbling Hive: The Response to Social and Economic Problems in England, 1689–1750, ed. Davison, Lee, Hitchcock, Tim, Keirn, Tim, and Shoemaker, Robert B. (Stroud, 1992), xilivGoogle Scholar.

66 Central government also spent £169,000 on roads in 1760–1800, well after their military purpose became secondary. Colquhoun, Patrick, A Treatise on the Wealth, Power, and Resources of the British Empire (London, 1814), 228Google Scholar; BPP, 1868–89, 35:448.

67 Campbell, R. H., ed., States of the Annual Progress of the Linen Manufacture, 1727–1754 (Edinburgh, 1964), vviiGoogle Scholar.

68 Durie, A. J., The Scottish Linen Industry in the Eighteenth Century (Edinburgh, 1979), 29, 164Google Scholar.

69 Durie, A. J., The British Linen Company, 1745–1775 (Edinburgh, 1996), 15Google Scholar.

70 Harris, Bob, “Scotland’s Herring Fisheries and the Prosperity of the Nation, c. 1660–1760,” Scottish Historical Review 79, no. 1 (April 2000): 3960CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

71 Harris, Bob, “Patriotic Commerce and National Revival: The Free British Fishery Society and British Politics, c. 1749–1758,” English Historical Review 114, no. 456 (April 1999): 285313CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

72 Report Respecting the British fisheries (1798), 218–25, reprinted in House of Commons Sessional Papers of the Eighteenth Century, ed. Lambert, Sheila (Wilmington, DE, 1975), 118:506–13Google Scholar.

73 Innes, Inferior Politics, 102.

74 Graham, E. J., A Maritime History of Scotland, 1650–1790 (East Linton, 2002), 319Google Scholar.

75 Kiernan, T. J., History of the Financial Administration of Ireland to 1817 (London, 1930), 165–79Google Scholar; Gribbon, Harry, “The Irish Linen Board, 1711–1828,” in The Warp of Ulster’s Past, ed. Cohen, Marilyn (Basingstoke, 1997), 7191Google Scholar.

76 Johnston-Liik, Edith Mary, History of the Irish Parliament, 1692–1800, 6 vols. (Belfast, 2002), 1:307Google Scholar; Barnard, Improving Ireland? 168.

77 Barnard, Toby, The Kingdom of Ireland, 1641–1760 (Basingstoke, 2004), 88CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Magennis, E., “Coal, Corn and Canals: Parliament and the Dispersal of Public Moneys 1695–1772,” Parliamentary History 20, no. 1 (February 2001): 74Google Scholar.

78 Magennis, “Coal, Corn and Canals,” 81; Gill, Conrad, The Rise of the Irish Linen Industry (Oxford, 1925), 197Google Scholar.

79 Barnard, Kingdom of Ireland, 82; Magennis, “Coal, Corn and Canals,” 86.

80 Epstein, S. R., Freedom and Growth: The Rise of States and Markets in Europe, 1300–1750 (London, 2000), 6CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Also Greene, J. P., Negotiated Authorities: Essays in Colonial Political and Constitutional History (Charlottesville, VA, 1994), 11, 23Google Scholar.

81 Hechter, Michael, Internal Colonialism: The Celtic Fringe in British National Development, 1536–1966 (London, 1975)Google Scholar.

82 J. H. Elliott, “A Europe of Composite Monarchies,” Past and Present, no. 137 (November 1992): 48–71; Koenigsberger, H. G., “Composite States, Representative Institutions and the American Revolution,” Historical Research 62, no. 148 (June 1989): 135–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar; David Hayton, “Constitutional Experiments and Political Expediency, 1689–1725,” in Ellis and Barber, Conquest and Union, 276–305.

83 Interesting points are made in Connolly, S. J., Houston, R. A., and Morris, R. J., “Identity, Conflict and Economic Change: Themes and Issues,” in Conflict, Identity and Economic Development: Ireland and Scotland, 1600–1939, ed. Connolly, S. J., Houston, R. A., and Morris, R. J. (Preston, 1995), 113Google Scholar.

84 Murdoch, Alexander, “Scottish Sovereignty in the Eighteenth Century,” in The Challenge of Westminster: Sovereignty, Devolution and Independence, ed. Dickinson, H. T. and Lynch, M. (East Lothian, 2000), 49Google Scholar.

85 Horwitz, Henry and Polden, Patrick, “Continuity or Change in the Court of Chancery in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries?Journal of British Studies 35, no. 1 (January 1996): 2457CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

86 Connolly, Houston, and Morris, “Identity, Conflict and Economic Change,” 2.

87 McLean and McMillan, State of the Union, 6.

88 Schmidt, H. D., “The Idea and Slogan of ‘Perfidious Albion,’Journal of the History of Ideas 14, no. 4 (October 1953): 604–16CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bell, David A., The Cult of the Nation in France: Inventing Nationalism, 1680–1800 (Cambridge, MA, 2001), chap. 3Google Scholar; Acomb, Frances, Anglophobia in France, 1763–1789: An Essay in the History of Constitutionalism and Nationalism (Durham, NC, 1950)Google Scholar; Hampson, Norman, The Perfidy of Albion: French Perceptions of England during the French Revolution (Houndmills, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Crick, Bernard, “The English and the British,” in National Identities: The Constitution of the United Kingdom, ed. Crick, B. (Oxford, 1991), 96Google Scholar.

89 I go some of the way with Pincus, Steve, 1688: The First Modern Revolution (New Haven, CT, 2009)Google Scholar, but I put much greater weight on the collective importance of specific legislation and the multinational aspects of political action than he does.

90 O’Brien, “The Britishness of the First Industrial Revolution,” 50–51; Bates, Robert H., “Lessons from History, or the Perfidy of English Exceptionalism and the Historical Significance of France,” World Politics 15, no. 4 (July 1988): 499516CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Some suggestive points are also made by Horn, Jeff, The Path Not Taken: French Industrialization in the Age of Revolution, 1750–1830 (Cambridge, MA, 2006), chap. 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar.