Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c47g7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T17:07:15.682Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Hicks meets Hotelling: the direction of technical change in capital–resource economies

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 September 2008

CORRADO DI MARIA
Affiliation:
University College Dublin, UCD Richview, Dublin 14, Ireland. Tel: +35317162714. Fax: +35317162788. Email: corrado.dimaria@ucd.ie
SIMONE VALENTE
Affiliation:
Centre of Economic Research, ETH Zurich. Tel: +41446324724. Fax +41446321362. Email: svalente@ethz.ch

Abstract

We analyze a two-sector growth model with directed technical change where man-made capital and exhaustible resources are essential for production. The relative profitability of factor-specific innovations endogenously determines whether technical progress will be capital- or resource-augmenting. We show that any balanced growth equilibrium features purely resource-augmenting technical change. This result is compatible with alternative specifications of preferences and innovation technologies, as it hinges on the interplay between productive efficiency in the final sector, and the Hotelling rule characterizing the efficient depletion path for the exhaustible resource. Our result provides sound micro-foundations for the broad class of models of exogenous/endogenous growth where resource-augmenting progress is required to sustain consumption in the long run, contradicting the view that these models are conceptually biased in favor of sustainability.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. (1998), ‘Why do new technologies complement skills? Directed technical change and wage inequality’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113: 10551089.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2002), ‘Directed technical change’, Review of Economic Studies 69: 781809.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2003), ‘Labour- and capital-augmenting technical change’, Journal of the European Economic Association 1: 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1992), ‘A model of growth through creative destruction’, Econometrica 60: 323351.Google Scholar
Aghion, P. and Howitt, P. (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Amigues, J.P., Grimaud, A., and Moreaux, M. (2004), ‘Optimal endogenous sustainability with an exhaustible resource through dedicated R&D’, Working Paper 04.17.154, LEERNA.Google Scholar
André, F. and Smulders, S. (2006), ‘Fuelling growth when oil peaks: growth, energy supply, and directed technological change’, mimeo, CentER, Tilburg University.Google Scholar
Barbier, E.B. (1999), ‘Endogenous growth and natural resource scarcity’, Environmental and Resource Economics 14: 5174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bretschger, L. (2005), ‘Economics of technological change and the natural environment: how effective are innovations as a remedy for resource scarcity?’, Ecological Economics 54: 148163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bretschger, L. and Smulders, S. (2003), ‘Sustainability and substitution of exhaustible natural resources: how prices affect long-term R&D investments’, Economics Working Paper Series 03/26, ETH Zurich.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, K.-P. (1994), ‘Capital–energy substitution and the multi-level CES production function’, Energy Economics 16: 2226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. and Heal, G. (1974), ‘The optimal depletion of exhaustible resources’, Review of Economic Studies 41, Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources, 3–28.Google Scholar
Di Maria, C. and Smulders, S. (2004), ‘Trade pessimists vs technology optimists: induced technical change and pollution havens’, Advances in Economic Analysis and Policy 4, issue 2, article 7.Google Scholar
Di Maria, C. and Van der Werf, E. (2008), ‘Carbon leakage revisited: unilateral climate policy under directed technical change’, Environmental and Resource Economics 39: 5574.Google Scholar
Drandakis, E. and Phelps, E. (1965), ‘A model of induced invention, growth and distribution’, Economic Journal 126: 823840.Google Scholar
Gaitan, B. and Roe, T.L. (2005), ‘Natural resource abundance and economic growth in a two-country world’, Economic Development Center Bulletin 05-1, University of Minnesota.Google Scholar
Grimaud, A. and Rougé, L. (2003), ‘Non-renewable resources and growth with vertical innovations: optimum, equilibrium and economic policy’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 45: 433453.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and Helpman, E. (1991), Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Groth, C. and Schou, P. (2002), ‘Can non-renewable resources alleviate the knife-edge character of endogenous growth?’, Oxford Economic Papers 54: 386411.Google Scholar
Groth, C. and Schou, P. (2007), ‘Growth and non-renewable resources: the different roles of capital and resource taxes’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 53: 8098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. (1932), The Theory of Wages, London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1931), ‘The economics of exhaustible resources’, Journal of Political Economy 39: 137175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kennedy, C. (1964), ‘Induced bias in innovation and the theory of distribution’, Economic Journal 74: 541547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prywes, M. (1986), ‘A nested CES approach to capital–energy substitution’, Energy Economics 8: 2228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, P.M. (1987), ‘Growth based on increasing returns due to specialization’, American Economic Review 77: 5662.Google Scholar
Romer, P.M. (1990), ‘Endogenous technological change’, Journal of Political Economy 98: S71S102.Google Scholar
Scholz, C. and Ziemes, G. (1999), ‘Exhaustible resources, monopolistic competition, and endogenous growth’, Environmental and Resource Economics 13: 169185.Google Scholar
Solow, R. (1974), ‘Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources’, Review of Economic Studies 41, Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources: 29–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. (1974), ‘Growth with exhaustible natural resources: efficient and optimal growth paths’, Review of Economic Studies 41, Symposium on the Economics of Exhaustible Resources: 123–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valente, S. (2005), ‘Sustainable development, renewable resources and technological progress’, Environmental and Resource Economics 30: 115125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van Der Werf, E. (2007), ‘Production functions for climate policy modeling: an empirical analysis’, Working Paper 1316, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.CrossRefGoogle Scholar