Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T17:50:54.861Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

TEAM REASONING AND A MEASURE OF MUTUAL ADVANTAGE IN GAMES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 August 2017

Jurgis Karpus
Affiliation:
King’s College London, Department of Philosophy, Strand, London WC2R 2LS, UK. E-mail: jurgis.karpus@kcl.ac.uk.
Mantas Radzvilas
Affiliation:
London School of Economics, Department of Philosophy, Logic and Scientific Method, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK. E-mail: m.radzvilas@lse.ac.uk. URL: https://sites.google.com/site/mantasradzvilas/.

Abstract:

The game theoretic notion of best-response reasoning is sometimes criticized when its application produces multiple solutions of games, some of which seem less compelling than others. The recent development of the theory of team reasoning addresses this by suggesting that interacting players in games may sometimes reason as members of a team – a group of individuals who act together in the attainment of some common goal. A number of properties have been suggested for team-reasoning decision-makers’ goals to satisfy, but a few formal representations have been discussed. In this paper we suggest a possible representation of these goals based on the notion of mutual advantage. We propose a method for measuring extents of individual and mutual advantage to the interacting decision-makers, and define team interests as the attainment of outcomes associated with maximum mutual advantage in the games they play.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Bacharach, M. 1999. Interactive team reasoning: a contribution to the theory of co-operation. Research in Economics 53: 117147.Google Scholar
Bacharach, M. 2006. Beyond Individual Choice: Teams and Frames in Game Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bacharach, M. and Bernasconi, M.. 1997. The variable frame theory of focal points: an experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior 19: 145.Google Scholar
Bardsley, N., Mehta, J., Starmer, C. and Sugden, R.. 2010. Explaining focal points: cognitive hierarchy theory versus team reasoning. Economic Journal 120: 4079.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B. D. 1984. Rationalizable strategic behavior. Econometrica 52: 10071028.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1992. Fun and Games: A Text on Game Theory. Lexington, MA: D. C. Heath and Company.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 2005. Natural Justice. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 2009. Interpersonal comparison of utility. In The Oxford Handbook of Philosophy of Economics, ed. Ross, D. and Kincaid, H., 540559. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Chaudhuri, A. 2011. Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: a selective survey of the literature. Experimental Economics 14: 4783.Google Scholar
Colman, A. M., Pulford, B. D. and Rose, J.. 2008. Collective rationality in interactive decisions: evidence for team reasoning. Acta Psychologica 128: 387397.Google Scholar
Colman, A. M., Pulford, B. D. and Lawrence, C. L.. 2014. Explaining strategic coordination: cognitive hierarchy theory, strong Stackelberg reasoning, and team reasoning. Decision 1: 3558.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dietrich, F. and List, C.. 2016. Mentalism versus behaviourism in economics: a philosophy-of-science perspective. Economics and Philosophy 32: 249281.Google Scholar
Faillo, M., Smerilli, A. and Sugden, R.. 2016. Can a single theory explain coordination? an experiment on alternative modes of reasoning and the conditions under which they are used. CBES [Centre for Behavioural and Experimental Social Science] Working paper 16–01, University of East Anglia.Google Scholar
Fudenberg, D. and Tirole, J.. 1991. Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gauthier, D. 2013. Twenty-five on. Ethics 123: 601624.Google Scholar
Gold, N. 2012. Team reasoning, framing and cooperation. In Evolution and Rationality: Decisions, Co-operation and Strategic Behaviour, ed. Okasha, S. and Binmore, K., 185212. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gold, N. and Sugden, R.. 2007a. Collective intentions and team agency. Journal of Philosophy 104: 109137.Google Scholar
Gold, N. and Sugden, R.. 2007b. Theories of team agency. In Rationality and Commitment, ed. Peter, F. and Schmid, H. B., 280312. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. M. 1995. The impossibility of interpersonal utility comparisons. Mind 104: 473490.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. M. 2012. Preference, Value, Choice, and Welfare. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hurley, S. 2005a. Rational agency, cooperation and mind-reading. In Teamwork: Multi-Disciplinary Perspectives, ed. Gold, N., 200215. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hurley, S. 2005b. Social heuristics that make us smarter. Philosophical Psychology 18: 585612.Google Scholar
Karpus, J. and Gold, N.. 2017. Team reasoning: theory and evidence. In The Routledge Handbook of Philosophy of the Social Mind, ed. Kiverstein, J., 400417. Abingdon: Routledge Taylor Francis.Google Scholar
Ledyard, J. O. 1995. Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In The Handbook of Experimental Economics, ed. Kagel, J. H. and Roth, A. E., 111194. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Luce, R. D. and Raiffa, H.. 1957. Games and Decisions: Introduction and Critical Survey. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Pearce, D. G. 1984. Rationalizable strategic behavior and the problem of perfection. Econometrica 52: 10291050.Google Scholar
Perea, A. 2012. Epistemic Game Theory: Reasoning and Choice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, A. and Salant, Y.. 2016. ‘Isn’t everyone like me?’: on the presence of self-similarity in strategic interactions. Judgment and Decision Making 11: 168173.Google Scholar
Smerilli, A. 2012. We-thinking and vacillation between frames: filling a gap in Bacharach’s theory. Theory and Decision 73: 539560.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1993. Thinking as a team: towards an explanation of nonselfish behavior. Social Philosophy and Policy 10: 6989.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2000. Team preferences. Economics and Philosophy 16: 175204.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2003. The logic of team reasoning. Philosophical Explorations: An International Journal for the Philosophy of Mind and Action 6: 165181.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2011. Mutual advantage, conventions and team reasoning. International Review of Economics 58: 920.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 2015. Team reasoning and intentional cooperation for mutual benefit. Journal of Social Ontology 1: 143166.Google Scholar