Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-tj2md Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T01:44:18.668Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Intertemporal Choice

Choosing for the Future

from Part II - Finance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2018

Alan Lewis
Affiliation:
University of Bath
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

5.9 References

Ainslie, G. (1975). Specious Reward: A Behavioral Theory of Impulsiveness and Impulse Control. Psychological Bulletin, 82(4), 463496.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ainslie, G. (2001). Breakdown of Will. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I. and Rutström, E. E. (2008). Eliciting Risk and Time Preferences. Econometrica, 76(3), 583618.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, S., Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I. and Rutström, E. E. (2014). Discounting Behavior: A Reconsideration. European Economic Review, 71, 1533.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attema, A. E., Bleichrodt, H., Rohde, K. I. and Wakker, P. P. (2010). Time-Tradeoff Sequences for Analyzing Discounting and Time Inconsistency. Management Science, 56(11), 20152030.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Attema, A. E., Bleichrodt, H., Gao, Y., Huang, Z, and Wakker, P. P. (2016). Measuring Discounting Without Measuring Utility. American Economic Review, 106(6), 14761494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berns, G. S., Laibson, D. and Loewenstein, G. (2007). Intertemporal Choice: Toward an Integrative Framework. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 11(11), 482488.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bickel, W. K. and Marsch, L. A. (2001). Toward a Behavioral Economic Understanding of Drug Dependence: Delay Discounting Processes. Addiction, 96(1), 7386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleichrodt, H., Gao, Y. and Rohde, K. I. (2016). A Measurement of Decreasing Impatience for Health and Money. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 52(3), 213231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bleichrodt, H. and Johannesson, M. (2001). Time Preference for Health: A Test of Stationarity Versus Decreasing Timing Aversion. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 45(2), 265282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casari, M. and Dragone, D. (2011). On Negative Time Preferences. Economics Letters, 111(1), 3739.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cairns, J. (1992). Discounting and Health Benefits: Another Perspective. Health Economics, 1(1), 7679.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cairns, J. A. (1994). Valuing Future Benefits. Health Economics, 3(4), 221229.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chabris, C. F., Laibson, D., Morris, C. L., Schuldt, J. P. and Taubinsky, D. (2008). Individual Laboratory-Measured Discount Rates Predict Field Behavior. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 37(2–3), 237269.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chapman, G. B. (1996). Temporal Discounting and Utility for Health and Money. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 22(3), 771791.Google ScholarPubMed
Chapman, G. B. and Elstein, A. S. (1995). Valuing the Future Temporal Discounting of Health and Money. Medical Decision Making, 15(4), 373386.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chung, S. and Herrnstein, R. J. (1961). Relative and Absolute Strengths of Response as a Function of Frequency of Reinforcement. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Animal Behavior, 4(3), 267272.Google Scholar
Cropper, M. L., Aydede, S. K. and Portney, P. R. (1994). Preferences for Life Saving Programs: How the Public Discounts Time and Age. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 8(3), 243265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cubitt, R. P., McDonald, R. and Read, D. (in press). Time Matters Less When Outcomes Differ: Uni-modal Versus Cross-modal Comparisons in Intertemporal Choice. Management Science.Google Scholar
Cubitt, R. P. and Read, D. (2007). Can Intertemporal Choice Experiments Elicit Time Preferences for Consumption? Experimental Economics, 10(4), 369389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doyle, J. R. (2013). Survey of Time Preference, Delay Discounting Models. Judgment and Decision Making, 8(2), 116135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ebert, J. E. and Prelec, D. (2007). The Fragility of Time: Time-Insensitivity and Valuation of the Near and Far Future. Management Science, 53(9), 14231438.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edgeworth, F. Y. (1879). The Hedonical Calculus. Mind, 4, 394408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. (1979). Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationaltiy and Irrationality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Estle, S. J., Green, L., Myerson, J. and Holt, D. D. (2007). Discounting of Monetary and Directly Consumable Rewards. Psychological Science, 18(1), 5863.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Faralla, V., Benuzzi, F., Lui, F., Baraldi, P., Dimitri, N. and Nichelli, P. (2015). Neural Correlates in Intertemporal Choice of Gains and Losses. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology, and Economics, 8(1), 2747CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figner, B., Knoch, D., Johnson, E. J., Krosch, A. R., Lisanby, S. H., Fehr, E. and Weber, E. U. (2010). Lateral Prefrontal Cortex and Self-control in Intertemporal Choice. Nature Neuroscience, 13(5), 538–539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, I. (1930). The Theory of Interest. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Frederick, S. and Loewenstein, G. (2008). Conflicting Motives in Evaluations of Sequences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 37(2–3), 221235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G. and O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time Discounting and Time Preference: A Critical Review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigliotti, G. and Sopher, B. (1997). Violations of Present-Value Maximization in Income Choice. Theory and Decision, 43, 4569.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glimcher, P. W., Kable, J. and Louie, K. (2007). Neuroeconomic Studies of Impulsivity: Now or Just as Soon as Possible? American Economic Review, 97(2), 142147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, L., Myerson, J. and Macaux, E. W. (2005). Temporal Discounting When the Choice Is Between Two Delayed Rewards. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 31(5), 11211133.Google ScholarPubMed
Halevy, Y. (2015). Time Consistency: Stationarity and Time Invariance. Econometrica, 83(1), 335352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardisty, D. J., Appelt, K. C. andWeber, E. U. (2013). Good or Bad, We Want It Now: Fixed-Cost Present Bias for Gains and Losses Explains Magnitude Asymmetries in Intertemporal Choice. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 26(4), 348361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardisty, D. J. and Weber, E. U. (2009). Discounting Future Green: Money Versus the Environment. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 138(3), 329340.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hariri, A. R., Brown, S. M., Williamson, D. E., Flory, J. D., de Wit, H. and Manuck, S. B. (2006). Preference for Immediate over Delayed Rewards Is Associated with Magnitude of Ventral Striatal Activity. Journal of Neuroscience, 26(51), 1321313217.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harris, C. R. (2012). Feelings of Dread and Intertemporal Choice. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 25(1), 1328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holcomb, J. H. and Nelson, P. S. (1992). Another Experimental Look at Individual Time Preference. Rationality and Society, 4(2), 199220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Homer, (Translated 1932). The Odyssey, T. E. Lawrence (translator). London: Macmillan Collectors Library (this edition published 2004).Google Scholar
Kable, J. W. (2013). Valuation, Intertemporal Choice, and Self-Control. In Glimcher, P. W and Ernst, F. (Eds.), Neuroeconomics: Decision Making and the Brain (pp. 173192): London: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Kable, J. W. and Glimcher, P. W. (2007). The Neural Correlates of Subjective Value During Intertemporal Choice. Nature Neuroscience, 10(12), 16251633.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kable, J. W. and Glimcher, P. W. (2010). An ‘as Soon as Possible’ Effect in Human Intertemporal Decision Making: Behavioral Evidence and Neural Mechanisms. Journal of Neurophysiology, 103(5), 25132531.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Wakker, P. P. and Sarin, R. (1997). Back to Bentham? Explorations of Experienced Utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 375405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kayser, A. S., Allen, D. C., Navarro-Cebrian, A., Mitchell, J. M. and Fields, H. L. (2012). Dopamine, Corticostriatal Connectivity, and Intertemporal Choice. Journal of Neuroscience, 32(27), 94029409.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Keynes, J. M (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan (reprinted 2007).Google Scholar
Kinari, Y., Ohtake, F. and Tsutsui, Y. (2009). Time Discounting: Declining Impatience and Interval Effect. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 39(1), 87112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirby, K. N. and Herrnstein, R. J. (1995). Preference Reversals Due to Myopic Discounting of Delayed Reward. Psychological Science, 6(2), 8389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirby, K. N., Petry, N. M. and Bickel, W. K. (1999). Heroin Addicts Have Higher Discount Rates for Delayed Rewards Than Non-Drug-Using Controls. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 128(1), 7887.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Knapman, A. and Tronde, J. (2011). Temporal Discounting of Different Commodities in Airline Customer Reward Programs. (MBA), Blekinge Institute of Technology. Retrieved from www.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:829832/FULLTEXT01.pdfGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D. (1997). Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landsberger, M. (1971). Consumer Discount Rate and the Horizon: New Evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 79(6), 13461359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laury, S. K., McInnes, M. M. and Swarthout, J. T. (2012). Avoiding the Curves: Direct Elicitation of Time Preferences. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 44(3), 181217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LeBoeuf, R. A. (2006). Discount Rates for Time Versus Dates: The Sensitivity of Discounting to Time-Interval Description. Journal of Marketing Research, 43(1), 5972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lempert, K. M. and Phelps, E. A. (2016). The Malleability of Intertemporal Choice. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 20(1), 6474.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loewenstein, G. (1987). Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption. Economic Journal, 97(387), 666684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. (1988). Frames of Mind in Intertemporal Choice. Management Science, 34(2), 200214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. and Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 573597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. and Prelec, D. (1993). Preferences for Sequences of Outcomes. Psychological Review, 100(1), 91108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Rick, S. and Cohen, J. D. (2008). Neuroeconomics. Annual Review of Psychology, 59, 647672.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Loewenstein, G. and Sicherman, N. (1991). Do Workers Prefer Increasing Wage Profiles? Journal of Labor Economics, 9(1) 6784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loewenstein, G. and Thaler, R. H. (1989). Anomalies: Intertemporal Choice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3(4), 181193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magen, E., Dweck, C. S. and Gross, J. J. (2008). The Hidden-Zero Effect Representing a Single Choice as an Extended Sequence Reduces Impulsive Choice. Psychological Science, 19(7), 648649.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Manuck, S. B., Flory, J. D., Muldoon, M. F. and Ferrell, R. E. (2003). A Neurobiology of Intertemporal Choice. In Loewenstein, G., Read, D and Baumeister, R (Eds.), Time and Decision: Economic and Psychological Perspectives on Intertemporal Choice (pp. 139172). New York: Russell Sage.Google Scholar
Manzini, P., Mariotti, M. and Mittone, L. (2010). Choosing Monetary Sequences: Theory and Experimental Evidence. Theory and Decision, 69(3), 327354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mazur, J. E. (1987). An Adjusting Procedure for Studying Delayed Reinforcement. In Commons, M. L, Mazur, J. E., Nevin, J. A and Rachlin, H. (Eds.), The Effect of Delay and of Intervening Events on Reinforcement Value: Quantitative Analyses of Behavior (pp. 5573). Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.Google Scholar
McClure, S. M., Ericson, K. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G. and Cohen, J. D. (2007). Time Discounting for Primary Rewards. Journal of Neuroscience, 27(21), 57965804.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McClure, S. M., Laibson, D. I., Loewenstein, G. and Cohen, J. D. (2004). Separate Neural Systems Value Immediate and Delayed Monetary Rewards. Science, 306(5695), 503507.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
McAlvanah, P. (2010). Subadditivity, Patience, and Utility: The Effects of Dividing Time Intervals. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 76(2), 325337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, R., Chilton, S., Jones-Lee, M. W. and Metcalf, H. (2017). Evidence of Variable Discount Rates and Non-standard Discounting in Mortality Risk Valuation. Journal of Environmental Economics and ManagementCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, M. J. and Viscusi, W. K. (1990). Models for Estimating Discount Rates for Long-Term Health Risks Using Labor Market Data. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 3(4), 381401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, J., Green, L. and Warusawitharana, M. (2001). Area Under the Curve as a Measure of Discounting. Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior, 76(2), 235243.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (1999). Doing It Now or Later. American Economic Review, 89(1), 103124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (2000). The Economics of Immediate Gratification. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13(2): 2332503.0.CO;2-U>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelps, E. S. and Pollak, R. A. (1968). On Second-Best National Saving and Game-Equilibrium Growth. Review of Economic Studies, 35(2), 185199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plato, . (trans. 1956). Protagoras. in B. Jowett and M. Ostwald (Trans.), Vlastos, G., (Ed.). Indianapolis: Bobbs-Merrill.Google Scholar
Read, D. (2001). Is Time-Discounting Hyperbolic or Subadditive? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 23(1), 532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D. (2004). Intertemporal Choice. In Koehler, D. J and Harvey, N. (Eds.), Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making (pp. 424443). New Jersey: Blackwell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D. (2007). Experienced Utility: Utility Theory from Jeremy Bentham to Daniel Kahneman. Thinking & Reasoning, 13(1), 4561.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Frederick, S., Orsel, B. and Rahman, J. (2005). Four Score and Seven Years from Now: The Date/Delay Effect in Temporal Discounting. Management Science, 51(9), 13261335.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Frederick, S. and Scholten, M.2013). DRIFT: An Analysis of Outcome Framing in Intertemporal Choice. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 39(2), 573588.Google ScholarPubMed
Read, D., Loewenstein, G. and Kalyanaraman, S. (1999). Mixing Virtue and Vice: Combining the Immediacy Effect and the Diversification Heuristic. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12(4), 257273.3.0.CO;2-6>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D., Olivola, C. Y. and Hardisty, D. (in press). The Value of Nothing: Asymmetric Attention to Opportunity Costs Drives Intertemporal Decision Making, Management Science, dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2016.2547Google Scholar
Read, D. and Powell, M. (2002). Reasons for Sequence Preferences. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15(5), 433460.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D. and Read, N. L. (2004). Time Discounting over the Lifespan. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 94(1), 2232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D. and Roelofsma, P. H. (2003). Subadditive Versus Hyperbolic Discounting: A Comparison of Choice and Matching. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 91(2), 140153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Read, D. and Van Leeuwen, B. (1998). Predicting Hunger: The Effects of Appetite and Delay on Choice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76(2), 189205.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Reuben, E., Sapienza, P. and Zingales, L. (2010). Time Discounting for Primary and Monetary Rewards. Economics Letters, 106(2), 125127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rick, S. and Loewenstein, G. (2008). The Role of Emotion in Economic Behavior. In Lewis, M., Haviland-Jones, J. M and Barrett, L. F (Eds.), Handbook of Emotions (pp. 138156). New York: Guilford Press.Google Scholar
Robles, E. (2010). Delay and Loss of Subjective Value. Journal of Behavior, Health & Social Issues, 2(1), 105118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roelofsma, P. H. (1996). Modelling Intertemporal Choices: An Anomaly Approach. Acta Psychologica, 93(1), 522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. (2003). ‘Economics and Psychology’? The Case of Hyperbolic Discounting. International Economic Review, 44(4), 12071216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P. A. (1937). A Note on Measurement of Utility. Review of Economic Studies, 4(2), 155161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sayman, S. and Öncüler, A. (2009). An Investigation of Time Inconsistency. Management Science, 55(3), 470482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholten, M. and Read, D. (2006). Discounting by Intervals: A Generalized Model of Intertemporal Choice. Management Science, 52(9), 14241436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholten, M. and Read, D. (2010). The Psychology of Intertemporal Tradeoffs. Psychological Review, 117(3), 925944.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Scholten, M. and Read, D. (2013). Time and Outcome Framing in Intertemporal Tradeoffs. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 39(4), 11921212.Google ScholarPubMed
Scholten, M., Read, D. and Sanborn, A. (2016). Cumulative Weighing of Time in Intertemporal Tradeoffs. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 145(9), 11771205.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sellitto, M., Ciaramelli, E. and di Pellegrino, G. (2010). Myopic Discounting of Future Rewards After Medial Orbitofrontal Damage in Humans. Journal of Neuroscience, 30(49), 1642916436.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shapiro, J. M. (2005). Is There a Daily Discount Rate? Evidence from the Food Stamp Nutrition Cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2), 303325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, C. T., Wallace, D. L., Dang, L. C., Aarts, E., Jagust, W. J., D’Esposito, M. and Boettiger, C. A. (2016). Modulation of Impulsivity and Reward Sensitivity in Intertemporal Choice by Striatal and Midbrain Dopamine Synthesis in Healthy Adults. Journal of Neurophysiology, 115(3), 11461156.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smith, P. K., Bogin, B. and Bishai, D. (2005). Are Time Preference and Body Mass Index Associated? Evidence from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth. Economics & Human Biology, 3(2), 259270.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sopher, B. and Sheth, A. (2006). A Deeper Look at Hyperbolic Discounting. Theory and Decision, 60(2–3), 219255.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Story, G. W., Vlaev, I., Seymour, B., Winston, J. S., Darzi, A. and Dolan, R. J. (2013). Dread and the Disvalue of Future Pain. PLoS Computational Biology, 9(11), e1003335.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Strotz, R. H. (1955). Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization. Review of Economic Studies, 23(3), 165180.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Takahashi, T. (2005). Loss of Self-Control in Intertemporal Choice May Be Attributable to Logarithmic Time-Perception. Medical Hypotheses, 65(4), 691693.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Thaler, R. (1981). Some Empirical Evidence on Dynamic Inconsistency. Economics Letters, 8(3), 201207CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsukayama, E. and Duckworth, A. L. (2010). Domain-Specific Temporal Discounting and Temptation. Judgment and Decision Making, 5(2), 7282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., Sattath, S. and Slovic, P. (1988). Contingent Weighting in Judgment and Choice. Psychological Review, 95(3), 371384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ubfal, D. (2016). How General Are Time Preferences? Eliciting Good-Specific Discount Rates. Journal of Development Economics, 118, 150170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Urminsky, O. and Zauberman, G. (2015). The Psychology of Intertemporal Preferences. In Wu, G. and Keren, G. (Eds.), The Wiley Blackwell Handbook of Judgment and Decision Making (pp. 141181). Malden, MA: Wiley-BlackwellCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Van der Pol, M. and Cairns, J. (2001). Estimating Time Preferences for Health Using Discrete Choice Experiments. Social Science & Medicine, 52(9), 14591470.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Weatherly, J. N. and Ferraro, F. R. (2011). Executive Functioning and Delay Discounting of Four Different Outcomes in University Students. Personality and Individual Differences, 51(2), 183187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, E. U., Johnson, E. J., Milch, K. F., Chang, H., Brodscholl, J. C. and Goldstein, D. G. (2007). Asymmetric Discounting in Intertemporal Choice a Query-Theory Account. Psychological Science, 18(6), 516523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wu, C. Y. and He, G.-B. (2012). The Effects of Time Perspective and Salience of Possible Monetary Losses on Intertemporal Choice. Social Behavior and Personality, 40, 16451653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yates, J. F. and Watts, R. A. (1975). Preferences for Deferred Losses. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance, 13(2), 294306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zauberman, G., Kim, B. K., Malkoc, S. A. and Bettman, J. R. (2009). Discounting Time and Time Discounting: Subjective Time Perception and Intertemporal Preferences. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(4), 543556.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×