Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-797576ffbb-jhnrh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2023-12-02T20:01:42.552Z Has data issue: false Feature Flags: { "corePageComponentGetUserInfoFromSharedSession": true, "coreDisableEcommerce": false, "useRatesEcommerce": true } hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2010

Éric Brousseau
Affiliation:
Université de Paris X
Jean-Michel Glachant
Affiliation:
Université de Paris XII
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
New Institutional Economics
A Guidebook
, pp. 489 - 542
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbink, K., Brandts, J., Tanga McDaniel, T. 2003. “Asymmetric Demand Information in Uniform and Discriminatory Call Auctions: An Experimental Analysis Motivated by Electricity Markets,” J. Regul. Econy., 23, 2, pp 125–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abowd, J. M. and Allain, L. 1996. “Compensation Structure and Product Market Competition,” Ann. Econ. Statist., 41:42, pp 207–218.Google Scholar
Abreu, D. 1986. “Extremal Equilibria of Oligopolistic Supergames,” J. Econ. Theory, 39, pp 191–225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. 2003. “Root Causes: A Historical Approach to Assessing the Role of Institutions in Economic Development,” Finance Devel., 40, 2, pp 27–30.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. 2005. “Constitutions, Politics and Economics: A Review Essay on Persson and Tabellini's The Economic Effects of Constitutions,” J. Econ. Lit., 43, 4, pp 1025–1048.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Johnson, D. 2005. “Unbundling Institutions”. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 949–995.
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. 2000. “Why Did the West Extend the Franchise?Quart. J. Econ., 115, pp 1167–1199.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 91, pp 1369–1401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acheson, J. M. 1985. “The Main Lobster Market: Between Market and Hierarchy,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 1, 2, pp 385–398.Google Scholar
Ackerberg, D. A. and Botticini, M. 2002. “Endogenous Matching and the Empirical Determinants of Contract Form,” J. Polit. Economy., 110, 3, pp 564–591.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, B. 2000. “The New Separation of Powers,” Harvard Law Rev., 113, 3, pp 633–639.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adserà, A., Boix, C., and Payne, M. E. 2001. “Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 19, 2, pp 445–490.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Afuah, A. 2001. “Dynamic Boundaries of the Firm: Are Firms Better off Being Vertically Integrated in the Face of a Technological Change?Acad. Manage. J., 44, 6, pp 1211–1228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agarwal, S. and Ramaswarmy, S. N. 1992. “Choice of Foreign Market Entry Mode: Impact of Ownership, Location and Internalization Factors,” J. Int. Bus. Stud., 23, pp 1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and Bolton, P. 2003. “Incomplete Social Contracts,” J. Europ. Econ. Assoc., 1, 1, pp 38–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., Alesina, A. F., and Trebbi, F. 2004. “Endogenous Political Institutions,” Quart. J. Econ., 119, 2, pp 565–611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., and Rey, P. 1994. “Renegotiation Design with Unverifiable Information,” Econometrica, 62, 2, pp 257–282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. 1970. “The Market for ‘Lemons’ Quality, Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,” Quart. J. Econ., 84, 3, pp 488–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. 1976. “The Economics of Caste and of the Rat Race and Other Woeful Tales,” Quart. J. Econ., 90, 4, pp 599–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alchian, A. A. 1961. Some Economics of Property. Santa Monica, CA: Rand Corporation.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H. 1972. “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 62, pp 772–795.Google Scholar
Alexander, R. 1987. The Biology of Moral Systems. Aldine de Gruyter: Hawthorne.Google Scholar
Allais, M. 1943. A la Recherche d'Une Discipline Economique. Atelier Industria.Google Scholar
Allen, D. W. and Lueck, D. 1998. “The Nature of the Farm,” J. Law Econ., 41, 2, pp 343–387.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. and Lueck, D. 1992. “Contract Choice in Modern Agriculture: Cash Rent versus Cropshare,” J. Law Econ., 35, 2, pp 397–426.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, D. W. and Lueck, D. 2002. The Nature of the Farm – Contracts, Risk, and Organization in Agriculture. Cambridge, MA, and London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Al-Najjar, N. I. 1995. “Incomplete Contracts and the Governance of Complex Contractual Relationships,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 85, 2, pp 433–436.Google Scholar
Alston, L. J. and Ferrie, J. P. 1993. “Paternalism in Agricultural Labor Contracts in the U.S. South: Implications for the Growth of the Welfare State,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 83, 4, pp 852–875.Google Scholar
Alston, L. J. and Ferrie, J. P. 1999. Paternalism and the American Welfare State: Economics, Politics, and Institutions in the U.S. South, 1865–1965. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J. and Gallo, A. 2008. “Electoral fraud, the rise of Peron, and the demise of checks and balances in Argentina,” IBS work. Paper PEC2008:0001, University of Colorado. (Available at: www.colorado.edu/ibs/eb/alston)
Alston, L. J. and Higgs, R. 1982. “Contractual Mix in Southern Agriculture since the Civil War: Facts, Hypotheses, and Tests,” J. Econ. Hist., 42, pp 327–353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J. and Mueller, B. 2004. “Property Rights and the State,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds, Handbook for New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp 573–590.Google Scholar
Alston, L. J. and Mueller, B. 2006. “Pork for Policy: Executive and Legislative Exchange in Brazil,” J. Law Econ. Organ., 22, 1, pp 12–36.Google Scholar
Alston, L. J., Datta, S. K., and Nugent, J. B. 1984. “Tenancy Choice in a Competitive Framework with Transaction Costs,” J. Polit. Economy, 92, pp 1121–1133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J., Eggertsson, T., and North, D. 1996. Empirical Studies in Institutional Change. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., and Mueller, B. 1999a. “A Model of Rural Conflict: Violence and Land Reform Policy in Brazil,” Environ. Devel. Econ., 4, 2, pp 135–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., and Mueller, B. 1999b. Titles, Conflict, and Land Use: The Development of Property Rights and Land Reform on the Brazilian Amazon Frontier. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., and Mueller, B. 2000. “Land Reform Policies: The Sources of Violent Conflict, and Implications for Deforestation in the Brazilian Amazon,” J. Environ. Econ. Manage., 39, 2, pp 162–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, L. J., Libecap, G. D., and Schneider, R. 1996. “The Determinants and Impact of Property Rights: Land Titles on the Brazilian Frontier,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 12, pp. 25–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, J. E. and Lassen, D. D. 2003. “The Political Economy of Institutions and Corruption in American States,” J. Theo. Polit., 5, 3, pp 341–365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ames, B. 2001. The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anand, B. N. and Khanna, T. 2000. “Do Companies Learn to Create Value?Strategic. Manage. J., 21, 3, pp 295–316.3.0.CO;2-O>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderlini, L. and Felli, L. 1999. “Incomplete Contracts and Complexity Costs,” Theory Dec., 46, pp 23–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderlini, L. and Felli, L. 2004. “Bounded Rationality and Incomplete Contracts,” Res. Econ., 58, pp 3–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, E. and Schmittlein, D. C. 1984. “Integration of the Sales Force: An Empirical Examination,” RAND J. Econ., 15, 3, pp 385–395.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, J. and Young, L. 2002. “Imperfect Contract Enforcement,” NBER work. paper, 8847, pp 1–50.
Anderson, J. H., Lee, Y., and Murrell, P. 2000. “Competition and Privatization Amidst Weak Institutions: Evidence from Mongolia,” Econ. Inquiry, 38, 4, pp 527–549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, T. L. and Hill, P. J. 2002. “Cowboys and Contracts,” J. Legal Stud., 31, 2, pp 489–514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, T. L. and McChesney, F. 2003. Property Rights: Cooperation, Conflict and Law. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ansoff, I. H. and Brandenburg, R. C. 1967. “A Program of Research in Business Planning,” Manage. Sci., 13, 6, pp 219–241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, S., Figueiredo, J. M., and Snyder, J. M. 2003. “Why Is There So Little Money in US Politics?J. Econ. Perspect., 17, 1, pp 105–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., and Tripathi, M. 2002. “Are PAC Contributions and Lobbying Linked? New Evidence from the 1995 Lobby Disclosure Act,” Bus. Polit., 4, 2, pp 131–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. 1984. The Co-operative Game Theory of the Firm. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 1988. Information, Incentives and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. 1995. “Controlling Insider Control: Issues of Corporate Governance in Transition Economies,” in Aoki, M. and Hyung-Ki, K., eds, Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies: Insider Control and the Role of Banks. Washington, DC: World Bank, pp 3–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, M. 2001. Towards a Comparative Institutional Analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Aoki, M. 2004. “An Organizational Architecture of T-Form: Silicon Valley Clustering and Its Institutional Coherence,” Ind. Corp. Change, 13, 6, pp 473–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argyres, N. S. 1995. “Technology Strategy, Governance Structure and Interdivisional Coordination,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 28, pp 337–358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argyres, N. S. 1996a. “Capabilities, Technological Diversification and Divisionalization,” Strategic. Manage. J., 17, 5, pp 395–410.3.0.CO;2-E>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argyres, N. S. 1996b. “Evidence on the Role of Firm Capabilities in Vertical Integration Decisions,” Strategic Manage. J., 17, pp 129–150.3.0.CO;2-H>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argyres, N. S. and Bigelow, L. 2005. “Do transaction costs matter for survival at all stages of the industry life cycle?” Work paper, Boston University, presented at the 2004 ISNIE meetings in Tucson, AZ. (Available at: http://smgnet.bu.edu/mgmt_new/profiles/ArgyresNicholas.html).
Argyres, N. S. and Liebeskind, J. P. 1999. “Contractual Commitments, Bargaining Power, and Governance Inseparability: Incorporating History into Transaction Cost Theory,” Acad. Manage. Rev., 24, 1, pp 49–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Argyres, N. S. and Mayer, K. J. 2004. “Learning to Contract: Evidence from the Personal Computer Industry,” Organization Sci., 15, 4, pp 394–410.Google Scholar
Argyres, N. S. and Silverman, B. S. 2004. “R&D, Organizational Structure, and the Development of Corportae Technological Knowledge,” Strategic Manage. J., 25, pp 929–958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armour, H. O. and Teece, D. J. 1978. “Organizational Structure and Economic Performance: A Test of the Multidivisional Hypothesis,” Bell J. Econ., 9, 1, pp 106–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aron, J. 2000. “Growth and Institutions: A Review of the Evidence,” World Bank Res. Observer, 15, 1, pp 99–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. 1971. Essays in the Theory of Risk. Amsterdam, North Holland Publishing.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. 1987. “Reflections on the Essays,” in Feiwel, G., ed. Arrow and the Foundations of the Theory of Economic Policy. New York University Press, pp 727–734.Google Scholar
Arruñada, B. 2001. “The Role of Institutions in the Contractual Process,” in Deffains, B. and Kirat, T., eds, Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science, pp 177–196.Google Scholar
Arruñada, B. 2003. “Third Party Moral Enforcement: The Rise and Decline of Christian Confession,” Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Economics and Business. Work paper 653. (Available at: www.econ.upf.es/cgi-bin/onepaper?653).
Arruñada, B. 2004. “The Economic Effects of Christian Moralities,” Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Economics and Business. Work paper 743. (Available at: www.econ.upf.es/cgi-bin/onepaper?743).
Arruñada, B and Andonova, V., forthcoming. “Judges' Cognition, and Market Order,” Review of Law and Economics.
Arruñada, B and Andonova, V., 2005. “Market Institutions and Judicial Rulemaking,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M., eds, Handbook of New Institutional Economics,” Norwelll, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp 229–50.Google Scholar
Arruñada, B. and Garoupa, N. 2005. “The Choice of Titling System in Land,” J. Law Econ., 48, 2, pp 709–727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, B., Gonzále Díaz, M., Fernández, A. 2004. “Determinants of Organizational Form: Transaction Costs and Institutions in the European Trucking Industry,” Ind. Corp. Change, 13, 6, pp 687–692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arruñada, B., Garicano, L., and Vázquez, L. 2001. “Contractual Allocation of Decision Rights and Incentives: The Case of Automobile Distribution,” J. Law Econ. Organ., 17, 1, pp 257–284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arthur, B. W. 1989. “Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events,” Econ. J., 99, 394, pp 116–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. 2000. “Redistributing Income under Proportional Representation,” J. Pol. Econ., 108, 6, pp 1235–1269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. and Wright, J. R. 1994. “Counteractive Lobbying,” Amer. J. Polit. Sci., 38, 1, pp 25–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1997. The Complexity of Cooperation – Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhaus, J. 1999. “Introduction,” in The Elgar Companion to Law and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp 1–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bai, C.-E. and Zhijian, T. 2000. “Contract Mixing in Franchising as a Mechanism for Public-Goods Provision,” J. Econ. Manage. Strategic., 9, 1, pp 85–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bailey, M. J. 1992. “Approximate Optimality of Aboriginal Property Rights,” J. Law Econ., 35, pp 183–198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bajari, P. and Tadelis, S. 2001. “Incentives versus Transactions Costs: A Theory of Procurement Contracts,” RAND J. Econ., 32, 3, pp 387–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, G. P. and Hubbard, T. N. 2001. “Empirical Strategies in Contract Economics: Information and the Boundary of the Firm,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 91, 2, pp 189–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, G. P. and Hubbard, T. N. 2003. “Make or Buy in Trucking: Assets Ownership, Job Design and Information,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 93, 3, pp 551–572.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, G. P. and Hubbard, T. N. 2004. “Contractibility and Asset Ownership: On-Board Computers and Governance in US Trucking,” Quart. J. Econ., 119, 4, pp 1443–1479.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, G. P., Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K. 2004. “Strategic Alliances: Bridges Between ‘Islands of Conscious Power’,” Work paper: Harvard Business School, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, University of Southern California.
Baker, M. 2001. The Atoms of Language. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Bakken, H. and Schaars, M. 1937. The Economics of Cooperative Marketing. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Bakos, Y. and Dellarocas, C. 2003. “Cooperation Without Enforcement? A Comparative Analysis of Litigation and Online Reputation as Quality Assurance Mechanisms,” MIT Sloan Work paper 4295-03, pp 1–33.
Balakrishnan, S. and Wernerfelt, B. 1986. “Technical Change, Competition and Vertical Integration,” Strategic. Manage. J., 7, 4, pp 347–359.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J.-M. and Platteau, J.-P. 1996. Halting Degradation of Natural Resources – Is There a Role for Rural Communities?Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, C. and Clark, K. 2000. Design Rules: The Power of Modularity. Boston, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Bambaci, J., Spiller, P. T. and Tommasi, M. 2001. “Bureaucracy and Public Policy in Argentina,” American Political Science Association Meetings.
Banerjee, A. V. and Duflo, E. 2000. “Reputation Effects and the Limits of Contracting: A Study of the Indian Software Industry,” Quart. J. Econ., 15, 3, pp 989–1017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. V. and Iyer, L. 2004. “History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,” Mimeo, MIT. (Available at: http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/download_pdf.php?id=517).
Banerjee, A. V. and Munshi, K. D. 2004. “How Efficiently is Capital Allocated? Evidence from the Knitted Garment Industry in Tirupur,” Rev. Econ. Stud., 71, 1, pp 19–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banfield, E. 1958. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York, NY: Free Press.Google Scholar
Barker, R. P., and Ricker, W. H., 1982. “A Political Theory of Regulation with some Observations on Railway Abandonments,” Public Choice, 39, pp 73–106.Google Scholar
Barnard, Chester. 1938. The Functions of the Executive. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Barney, J. B. 1991. “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Advantage,” J. Manage., 17, 1, pp 99–120.Google Scholar
Baron, D. P. 1994. “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters,” Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., 88, 1, pp 33–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, D. P. 2000. Business and Its Environment, third edition. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Barquin, J., Bergman, L., Crampes, C., Green, R., Glachant, J.-M., Hirchhausen, C., et al. 2006. “The Acquisition of Endesa by Gas Natural: Why the Antitrust Authorities Are Right to Be Cautious,” Electricity J., 19, 2, pp 62–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. 1982. “Measurement Cost and Organization of Markets,” J. Law Econ. 25, pp 27–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barzel, Y. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barzel, Y. 2002. A Theory of the State: Economic Rights, Legal Rights, and the Scope of the State. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Basu, K. 2000. Prelude to Political Economy – A Study of the Social and Political Foundations of Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basu, K., Jones, E., and Schlicht, E. 1987. “The Growth and Decay of Custom: The Role of the New Institutional Economics in Economic History,” Explorations Econ. Hist. 24, 1, pp 1–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, R., Greif, A., Levi, M., Rosenthal, J.-L., and Weingast, B. 1998. Analytic Narratives. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baum, J. A. C., Calabrese, T., and Silverman, B. S. 2000. “Don't Go It Alone: Alliance Networks and Startup Performance in Canadian Biotechnology,” Strategic. Manage. J. 21, 3, pp 267–294.3.0.CO;2-8>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baum, J. A. C., Shipilov, A. V., and Rowley, T. J. 2003. “Where Do Small Worlds Come From?Industrial Corpor. Change., 12, 4, pp 697–725.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, W. and Sidak, G. 1994. Toward Competition in Local Telephony, Boston, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Beales, H. J. and Muris, T. J. 1995. “The Foundation of Franchise Regulation: Issues and Evidence,” J. Corp. Finan., 2, pp 157–197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., and Walsh, P. 2000. “New Tools and New Tests,” in Comparative Political Economy: The Database of Political Institutions, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Beers, G., Beulens, A., and van Dalen, J. 1998. “Chain Science as an Emerging Discipline,” in Ziggers, G. W., Trienekens, J. H., and Zuurbier, P. J. P, eds, Proceedings of the Third International Conference on Chain Management in Agribusiness and the Food Industry. Wageningen University, Management Studies Group, pp 295–330.Google Scholar
Benabou, R. and Tirole, J. 2003. “Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation,” Rev. Econ. Stud., 70, 3, pp 489–520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bennedsen, M. and Feldmann, S. E. 2002. “Lobbying Legislatures,” J. Polit. Econ., 110, 4, pp 919–948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benz, M. and Stutzer, A. 2004. “Are Voters Better Informed when They Have a Larger Say in Politics? Evidence for the European Union and Switzerland,” Public Choice, 119, 1–2, pp 31–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bercovitz, J. 2001. An Analysis of Contract Provisions in Business-Format Franchise Agreement. Mimeo, Duke University, Fuqua School of Business.Google Scholar
Bercovitz, J. 2003. The Option to Expand: The Use of Multi-Unit Opportunities to Support Self-Enforcing Agreements in Franchise Relationships. Mimeo, Duke University, Fuqua School of Business.Google Scholar
Bercovitz, J., Jap, S. and Nickerson, J. A. 2006. “The Antecedents and Performance Implications of Cooperative Exchange Norms,” Organization Science, 17, 6, pp 724–740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergara, M., Richman, B. D., and Spiller, P. T. 2003. “Modeling Supreme Court Strategic Decision Making: the Congressional Constraint,” Legisl. Stud. Quart., 28, pp 247–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, L. 1992. “Opting out of the Legal System: Extralegal Contractual Relations in the Diamond Industry,” J. Legal Stud., 21, 1, pp 115–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernstein, L. 2001. “Private Commercial Law in the Cotton Industry: Creating Cooperation through Norms, Rules, and Institutions,” Mich. Law Rev., 99, pp 1724–1788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besanko, D., Dranove, D., and Shanley, M. 1996. Economics of Strategy. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Besley, T. and Payne, A. 2003. “Judicial Accountability and Economic Policy Outcomes: Evidence from Employment Discrimination Charges.” Mimeo, June.
Bhattacharyya, S. and Lafontaine, F. 1995. “Double-Sided Moral Hazard and the Nature of Share Contracts,” RAND J. Econ., 26, 4, pp 761–781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhide, A. 1990. “Reversing Corporate Diversification,” J. Appl. Corp. Fin., 3, 2, pp 70–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bigelow, L. 2003. “Transaction Alignment and Survival: Performance Implications of Transaction Cost Alignment,” Work paper, Olin School of Business, Washington University.
Bigelow, L. 2006. “Technology Choice, Transaction Alignment and Survival: The Impact of Sub-Population Organizational Structure,” Advan. Strategic. Manage., 23, pp 301–334.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. 1992. Funs and Games: A Text on Game Theory. Cambridge, MA: DC Heath & Co.Google Scholar
Blankart, C. B. 2000. “The Process of Government Centralization: A Constitutional View,” Constit. Polit. Econ., 11, 1, pp 27–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bliss, C. and Stern, N. 1982. Palanpur. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Blomberg, B. S., Hess, G. D., and Weerapana, A. 2004. “The Impact of Voter Initiatives on Economic Activity,” Europ. J. of Polit. Econ., 20, 1, pp 207–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blumm, M. C. and Schwartz, T. 1995. “Mono Lake and the Evolving Public Trust in Western Water,” Arizona Law Rev., 37, pp 701–738.Google Scholar
Boehmke, F. J., Gailmard, S., and Patty, J. W. 2005. “Whose Ear to Bend? Information Sources and Venue Choice in Policy Making,” Quart. J. of Polit. Sci., 1, pp 139–169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boehmke, F. J., Gailmard, S., and Patty, J. W. 2005. “Patterns of Interest Group Lobbying Across Venues and Policies,” paper presented at the 2005 Annual Meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association.
Boemare, C. and Quirion, P. 2002. “Implementing Greenhouse Gas Trading in Europe – Lessons from Economic Theory and International Experiences,” Ecolog. Econ., 43, 2–3, pp 213–230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boerner, C. and Macher, J. 2001. “Transaction Cost Economics: An Assessment of Empirical Research in the Social Science,” Georgetown University, work paper. (Available at: www.msb.edu/faculty/jtm4/Macher.CV.htm).
Boger, S., Hobbs, J. E., and Kerr, W. A. 2001. “Supply Chain Relationships in the Polish Pork Sector,” Suppl. Chai. Manage., 6, 2, pp 74–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boisot, M. and Child, J. 1996. “From Fiefs to Clans and Network Capitalism: Explaining China's Emerging Economic Order,” Admin. Sci. Quart., 41, 4, pp 600–628.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boix, C. 1999. “Setting the Rules of the Game: The Choice of Electoral Systems in Advanced Democracies,” Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., 93, 3, pp 609–724.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G. E. 1991. “A Comparative Model of Bargaining: Theory and Evidence,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 81, 5, pp 1097–1136.Google Scholar
Boomgard, J. J., Davies, S. P., Haggblade, S. J., and Mead, D. C. 1991. “A Subsector Approach to Small Enterprise Promotion and Research,” Worl. Devel. 19, pp 199–212.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. 2004. Microeconomics – Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation and Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. and Gintis, H. 1999. “Power in Competitive Exchange,” in Bowles, S., Franzini, M., and Pagano, U., eds, The Politics and the Economics of Power. London: Routledge, pp 13–31.Google Scholar
Boyd, R. and Richerson, P. 1985. Culture and the Evolutionary Process. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Braddach, J. L. 1997. “Using the Plural Form in the Management of Restaurant Chains,” Admin. Sci. Quart., 42, 2, pp 276–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, G. and Hamlin, A. 1994. “A Revisionist View of the Separation of Powers,” J. Theo. Polit., 6, 3, pp 345–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, G. and Kliemt, H. 1994. “Finite Lives and Social Institutions,” Kyklos, 47, 4, pp 551–571.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A. 1999. “Incentives Conflicts and Contractual Restraints: Evidence from Franchising,” J. Law Econ., 42, 2, pp 745–774.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A. 2002. “Royalty Rates and Upfront Fees in Share Contracts: Evidence from Franchising,” J. Law Econ. Org., 18, 2, pp 511–535.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A. and Dark, F. H. 1987. “The Choice of Organizational Form: the Case of Franchising,” J. Finan. Econ., 18, pp 401–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brickley, J. A., Dark, F. H., and Weisbach, W. S. 1991. “The Economic Effects of Franchise Termination Laws,” J. Law Econ., 34, 1, pp 101–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bronars, S. G. and Lott, J. R., Jr. 1997. “Do Campaign Donations Alter How A Politician Votes? Or, Do Donors Support Candidates Who Value the Same Things That They Do?J. Law Econ., 40, 2, pp 317–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brousseau, E. 2000a. “Confiance ou Contrat, Confiance et Contrat,” in Aubert, F. and Sylvestre, J.-P., eds, Confiance et Rationalité. INRA: Les Colloques, 97, pp 65–80.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. 2000b. “Processus Evolutionnaires et Institutions: Quelles alternatives à la rationalité parfaite?Revue Economique, Special Issue, 51, 5, pp 1185–1213.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. 2000c. “What Institutions to Organize Electronic Commerce: Private Institutions and the Organization of Markets,” Econ. Innovation New Tech., 9, 3, pp 245–273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brousseau, E. 2004. “Property Rights in the Digital Space,” in Colombatto, , ed., Companion to Economics of Property Rights. Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, pp 438–472.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Bessy, C. 2006. “Public and Private Institutions in the Governance of Intellectual Property Rights,” in Andersen, B., ed, Intellectual Property Rights: Innovation, Governance and the Institutional Environment. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar Publishers, pp 243–277.
Broussea, E. and Curien, N., eds. 2007. Internet and Digital Economics: Principles Methods and Applications. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Fares, M. 2000. “Incomplete Contracts and Governance Structures: Are Incomplete Contract Theory and Transaction Cost Economics Substitutes or Complements?” in Ménard, C., ed., Institutions, Contracts and Organizations: Perspectives from the New Institutional Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp 399–421.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Fares, M. 2002. “Règle de Droit et Exécution des Contrats : Réflexion d'Économistes sur le Droit comparé des Contrats,“ Revue Econ. Politique, N° Spécial “L'Economie du Droit”, sld Deffains, B., 112, 6, pp 823–844.Google Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Glachant, J. M. 2002. The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brousseau, E. and Raynaud, E. 2006. “The Economics of Private Institutions: An Introduction to the Dynamics of Institutional Frameworks and to the Analysis of Multilevel Multi-Type Governance,” Mimeo, EconomiX, University of Paris X.
Brousseau, E. and Raynaud, E. 2007. “The Economics of Multilevel Governance,” Mimeo, EconomiX, University of Paris X.
Brown, D. 1991. Human Universals. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Brown, D. and Earle, J. 2000. “Privatization and Enterprise Restructuring in Russia: New Evidence from Panel Data on Industrial Enterprises.” Work paper 1, RECEP, Moscow.
Brown, M., Falk, A., and Fehr, E. 2003. “Relational Contracts and the Nature of Market Interactions,” IZA Discussion Paper, 897.
,Brown Versus Board of Education of Topeka, Kansas, 347 U.S. 483, 47 S. Ct. 686, 98 L. eds. 873.
Buchanan, J. 1977. Freedom in Constitutional Contract – Perspectives of a Political Economist. London: College Station and Texas, TX: A&M University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James. 1984. “Sources of Opposition to Constitutional Reform,” in Constitutional Economics – Containing the Economic Powers of Government. McKenzie, R. B., ed. Lexington: Lexington Books. pp 21–34.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. 1986. “Political Economy and Social Philosophy,” in Buchanan, J., ed., Liberty, Market and State – Political Economy in the 1980s. New York, pp 261–274.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. 1987. “Constitutional Economics,” in The New Palgrave. Basingstoke: Macmillan, pp 588–595.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1959. “Positive Economics, Welfare Economics, and Political Economy,” J. Law Econ., 2, pp 124–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1975a. “A Contractarian Paradigm for Applying Economic Theory: Conflict and Contract,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 65, 2, pp 225–230. (Papers and Proceedings of the Eighty-Seventh Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association.)Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. 1975b. The Limits of Liberty – Between Anarchy and Leviathan. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. and Tullock, G. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchner, B., Carraro, C., and Ellerman, D. 2006. “The Allocation of European Union Allowances: Lessons, Unifying Themes and General Principles,” FEEM work paper, 116, Milan.
Bueno de Mesquita, E. and Stephenson, M. 2006. “Legal Institutions and the Structure of Informal Networks,” J. Theoret. Pol., 18, 1, pp 40–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bull, J. and Watson, J. 2001. “Evidence Disclosure and Verifiability,” J. Econ. Theory, 118, 1, pp 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burt, R. 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Buskens, V., Raub, W., and Snijders, C. 2003. The Governance of Relations in Markets and Organizations. Amsterdam: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Cafaggi, F., Nicita, A. and Pagano, U. 2007. “Law, economics and institutional complexity: An introduction,” in Legal Orderings and Economics Institutions. in Cafaggi, F., Nicita, A. and Pagano, U., eds. London, Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, G. 1965. “The Decision for Accidents: An Approach to Non-Fault Allocation for Costs,” Harvard Law Rev., 78, 4, pp 713–745.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, G. 1968. “Transaction Costs, Resource Allocation and Liability Rules: A Comment,” J. Law Econ., 11, 1, pp 67–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabresi, G. 1970. The Costs of Accidents: A Legal and Economic Analysis. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Calabresi, G. and Melamed, D. A. 1972. “Property Rules, Liability Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral,” Harvard Law Rev., 85, 6, pp 1089–1128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calvert, R. L. 1985. “Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidate Motivations, Uncertainty, and Convergence,” Amer. J. Polit. Sci., 29, 1, pp 69–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Camara de Senadores de la Nacion. 1947. Diario de Sesiones del Honorable Senado de la Nacion. Constituido en Tribunal. 4, Buenos Aires.
Camerer, C. F. 1998. “Behavioral Economics and Nonrational Organizational Decision Making,” in Halpern, J. J. and Stern, R. N., eds, Debating Rationality. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, pp 53–77.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. 1999. “Behavioral Economics: Reunifying Psychology and Economics,” Proceed. National Acad. Sci., 9, 19, pp 10575–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. New York, NY: Princeton University Press and Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Ho, T.-H. 1999. “Experienced-Weighted Attraction Learning in Normal Form Games,” Econometrica, 67, 4, pp 827–874.Google Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Thaler, R. H. 1995. “Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and Manners,” J. Econ. Perspect., 9, 2, pp 209–219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, C. F. and Knez, M. 1996. “Coordination, Organizational Boundaries and Fads in Business Practice,” Industrial Corp. Change, 5, 1, pp 89–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carey, J. M. and Shugart, M. S. 1995. “Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas,” Elect. Stud., 14, 4, pp 417–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carmichael, L. H. and MacLeod, B. W. 2003. “Caring About Sunk Costs: A Behavioral Solution to the Hold-up Problem,” J. Law Econ. Organ., 19, pp 106–118.Google Scholar
Cashdan, E. A. 1980. “Egalitarianism Among Hunters and Gatherers,” Amer. Anthropol., 82, 1, pp 116–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casson, M. 1997. Information and Organization. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
,Castalia Strategic Advisor. 2005. Explanatory Notes on Key Topics in the Regulation of Water and Sanitation Services, World Bank edition.
Caves, R. E. and Murphy, W. F. 1976. “Franchising: Firms, Markets and Intangible Assets,” Southern Econ. J., 42, 4, pp 572–586.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chakravarty, S. and MacLeod, B. 2004. “On the Efficiency of Standard Form Contracts: The Case of Construction,” USC CLEO Research paper series, C04-17.
Chamberlin, E. H. 1948. “An Experimental Imperfect Market,” J. Polit. Econ., 56, 2, pp 95–108.Google Scholar
Chao, H.-P., and Peck, S., 1998. “Reliability management in competitive electricity markets,” Journal of Regulatory Economics, 14, pp 189–200.Google Scholar
Chao, H.-P. and Huntington, H. 1998. Designing Competitive Electricity Markets. Kluwer Academic Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Che, J. and Qian, Y. 1998. “Insecure Property Rights and Government Ownership of Firms,” Quart. J. Econ., 113, 2, pp 467–496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Che, Y.-K. and Hausch, D. B. 1999. “Cooperative Investments and the Value of Contracting,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 89, 1, pp 125–148.Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. 1970. “The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource,” J. Law Econ., 13, 1, pp 49–70.Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. 1973. “The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation,” J. Law Econ., 16, 1, pp 11–33.Google Scholar
Cheung, S. N. S. 1983. “The Contractual Nature of the Firm,” J. Law Econ., 26, 1, pp 1–21.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, pp 386–405. Reprinted in Coase, R. H. 1988. The Firm, the Market and the Law. Chicago Univerrsity Press, pp 55–57.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1946. “The Marginal Cost Controversy,” in Coase, R. H., 1988.
Coase, R. H. 1959. “The Federal Communications Commission,” J. Law Econ., 2, 2, pp 1–40.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost,” J. Law Econ., 3, 1, pp 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1964. “The Regulated Industries – Discussion,” American Economic Review, 54, 3, pp 194–197.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1972. “Industrial Organization: A Proposal for Research,” in Coase, R. H. 1988, pp 57–74.
Coase, R. H. 1974. “The Lighthouse in Economics,” in Coase, R. H., 1988, Chapter 7.
Coase, R. H. 1976. “Adam Smith View of Man,” J. Law Econ., 19, 3, pp 529–546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1988. The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1988. “The Nature of the Firm: Origin, Meaning, Influence,” J. Law Econ. Org., 4, pp 3–59.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1992. “The Institutional Structure of Production,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 82, 4, pp 713–719.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1993a. “Coase on Posner on Coase and Concluding Comment,” J. Inst. Theoretical Econ., 149, 1, pp 73–87.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1993b. “Law and Economics at Chicago,” J. Law Econ., 36, pp 239–254.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 1998. “The New Institutional Economics,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 88, 2, pp 72–74Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. 2000. “The Acquisition of Fisher Body by General Motors,” J. Law Econ., 43, 1, pp 15–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Codognet, M. K., Glachant, J. M., Lévêque, F., and Plagnet, M. A. 2003. “Mergers and Acquisitions in the European Electricity Sector.” GRJM and CERNA, École Nationale Supérieure des Mines de Paris.
Coen, D. 1998. “The European Business Interest and the Nation State: Large Firm Lobbying in the European Union and Member States,” J. of Public Polit., 118, 1, pp 75–100.Google Scholar
Coeurderoy, R. and Quélin, B. 1997. “Transaction Cost Theory: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Vertical Integration,” Rev. Econ. Polit., 107, 2, pp 145–181.Google Scholar
Cohen, M. D., Burkhart, R., Dosi, G., Egidi, M., Marengo, L., Warglien, M., and Winter, S. G. 1996. “Routines and Other Recurring Action Patterns of Organizations,” Contemp. Res. Issues, Industrial and Corporate Change, 5, 3, pp 653–698.Google Scholar
Cohen, W. M. and Levinthal, D. A. 1990. “Absorptive Capacity: A New Perspective on Learning and Innovation,” Administ. Scien. Quart., 35, 1, pp 128–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colby, B. G. 1990. “Transaction Costs and Efficiency in Western Water Allocation,” Amer. J. Agr. Econ., 72, 5, pp 1184–1192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collis, D. and Montgomery, C. 1995. “Competing on Resources: Strategy in the 1990s,” Harvard Bus. Rev., 73, 4, pp 118–128.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. 1924. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. Clifton: Augustus M. Kelley, reprinted: Transaction Publishers, 1995.Google Scholar
Commons, J. R. 1932–1933. “The Problems of Correlating Law, Economics and Ethics,” Wisconsin Law Rev. 8, 1, pp 3–26.Google Scholar
Conner, K. R. and Prahalad, C. K. 1996. “A Resource-based Theory of the Firm: Knowledge versus Opportunism,” Organ. Sci., 7, 5, pp 477–502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Contractor, F. J. and Lorange, P. 1988. “Why Should Firms Cooperate? The Strategy and Economics Basis for Cooperative Ventures,” in Contractor, F. J. and Lorange, P., eds., Cooperative Strategies in International Business. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Cook, M. L. 1995. “The Future of U.S. Agricultural Cooperatives: A Neo-Institutional Approach,” Amer. J. Agr. Econ., 77, 5, pp 1153–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cook, M. and Iliopoulos, C. 2000. “Ill-defined Property Rights in Collective Action: The Case of US Agricultural Cooperatives,” in Ménard, C., ed., Institutions, Contracts and Organizations. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp 335–348.Google Scholar
Cook, M. L. and Chaddad, F. R. 2004. “Redesigning Cooperative Boundaries: The Emergence of New Models,” Amer. J. Agr.Econ. 86, 5, pp 1249–1253.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. D. and Janet, L. T. 1984. “Personal versus Impersonal Trade: The Size of Trading Groups and Contract Law,” Int. Rev. Law Econ, 4, 1, pp 15–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, R. D. and Rubinfeld, L. D. 1989. “Economic Analysis of Legal Dispute and Their Resolution,” J. Econ. Lit., 27, 3, pp 1067–1097.Google Scholar
Corts, K. S. and Singh, J. 2004. “The Effect of Repeated Interaction on Contract Choice: Evidence from Offshore Drilling,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 20, 1, pp 230–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, L. 1985. “Deduction or Darwinian Algorithms? An Explanation of the Elusive Content Effect of the Wason Selection Task.” PhD dissertation, Department of Psychology, Harvard University.
Cosmides, L. 1989. “The Logic of Social Exchange: Has Natural Selection Shaped How Humans Reason? Studies with the Wason Selection Task,” Cognition, 31, 3, pp 187–196.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cosmides, L. and Tooby, J. 1992. “Cognitive Adaptations for Social Exchange,” in Barkow, J. H., Cosmides, L., and Tooby, J., eds, The Adapted Mind. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, pp 163–228.Google Scholar
Cosmides, L. and Tooby, J. 1994. “Better than Rational: Evolutionary Psychology and the Invisible Hand,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 84, 2, pp 327–332.Google Scholar
Craswell, R. 2001. “Two Economic Theories of Enforcing Promises,” in Benson, P., ed., Readings in the Theory of Contract Law. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Crawford, V. P. and Broseta, B. 1998. “What Price Coordination? The Efficiency-Enhancing Effect of Auctioning the Right to Play,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 88, 1, pp 198–225.Google Scholar
Crisp, B. F., Escobar-Lemmon, M. C., Jones, B. S., Jones, M. P., and Taylor-Robinson, M. M. 2004. “Vote-Seeking Incentives and Legislative Representation in Six Presidential Democracies,” J. Polit., 166, 3, pp 823–846.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crocker, K. J. and Masten, S. E. 1988. “Mitigating Contractual Hazards: Unilateral Options and Contract Length,” RAND J. Econ., 19, 3, pp 327–343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crocker, K. J. and Masten, S. E. 1991. “Pretia ex Machina?: Prices and Process in Long Term Contracts,” J. of Law and Econ., 34, pp 64–99.Google Scholar
Crocker, K. J. and Masten, S. E. 1996. “Regulation and Administered Contracts Revisited: Lessons From Transaction-Cost Economics for Public Utility Regulation,” J. Regul. Econ., 9, pp 5–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crocker, K. J. and Reynolds, J. K. 1993. “The Efficiency of Incomplete Contracts: An Empirical Analysis of Air Force Engine Procurement,” RAND J. Econ., 24, 1, pp 126–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cyert, R. and March, J. 1963. A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Dahlman, C. J. 1979. “The Problem of Externality,” J. Law Econ., 22, 1, pp 141–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bó, E. 2006a. Bribing Voters. Mimeo: Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, E. 2006b. Regulatory Capture: A Review. Mimeo: Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Dal Bó, E., Dal Bó, P., and Di Tella, R. 2006. “Plato O Plomo? Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence,” Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., 100, 1, pp 41–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damasio, A. 1994. Descartes' Error: Emotion, Reason and the Human Brain. New York, NY: Grosset/Putnam.Google Scholar
Datta, S. K., O'Hara, D. J., and Nugent, J. B. 1986. “Choice of Agricultural Tenancy in the Presence of Transaction Costs,” Land Econ., 62, 2, pp 145–158.Google Scholar
David, P. A. 1985. “Clio and the Economics of QWERTY,” Amer. Econ. Rev. 75, 2, pp 332–337.Google Scholar
Davis, D. and Holt, C. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, J. and Goldberg, R. 1957. A Concept of Agribusiness. Boston, MA: Division of Research, Harvard Business School.Google Scholar
Davis, L. and North, D. 1971. Institutional Change and American Economic Growth. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davoodi, H. and Heng-fu, Z. 1998. “Fiscal Decentralization and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Study,” J. Urban Econ., 43, 2, pp 244–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawkins, R. 1976. The Selfish Gene. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dawkins, R. 1982. The Extended Phenotype. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Day, G. S. and Klein, S. 1987. “Cooperative Behavior in Vertical Markets: The Influence of Transaction Costs and Competitive Strategies,” Rev. Marketing, pp 39–66.Google Scholar
Figueiredo, J. M. 1998. “Litigating Regulation: Corporate Strategy in Telecommunication,” unpublished manuscript.
Figueiredo, J. M. 2005. “Strategic Plaintiffs and Ideological Judges in Telecommunications Litigation,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 21, 2, pp 501–523.Google Scholar
Figueiredo, J. M. and Figueiredo, R. J. P, Jr. 2002. “The Allocation of Resources by Interest Groups: Lobbying, Litigation, and Administrative Regulation,” Bus. Politics, 14, 2, pp 161–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figueiredo, J. P. R, Jr. and Edwards, G. 2004. “Why Do Regulatory Outcomes Vary So Much? Economic, Political and Institutional Determinants of Regulated Prices in the US Telecommunications Industry.” Work paper, Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley.
Figueiredo, J. M. and Silverman, B. S. 2002. “Academic Earmarks and the Returns to Lobbying,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 49, pp 597–625.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figueiredo, J. P. R, Jr., Spiller, P. T., and Urbiztondo, S. 1999. “An Informational Perspective on Administrative Procedures,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 15, 1, pp 283–305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Janvry, A., Gordillo, G., Platteau, J.-P., and Sadoulet, E. 2001. Access to Land, Rural Poverty, and Public Action. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deakin, S. and Michie, J. 1997a. “Contracts, Co operation, and Competition,” in Studies in Economics, Management, and Law. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Deakin, S. and Michie, J. 1997b. “Contracts and Competition,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21, 2, pp 121–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, E. and Ryan, R. 1985. Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human behavior. New York, NY: Plenum.Google Scholar
Deffains, B. and Kirat, T. 2001, in Mercuro, N., ed., Law and Economics in Civil Law Countries, the Economics of Legal Relationship. Amsterdam: JAI Press, Elsevier Science BV.Google Scholar
Dellarocas, C., Fan, M., and Wood, C. 2004. “Self-Interest, Reciprocity, and Participation in Online Reputation Systems,” MIT Sloan work paper 4500–04 (Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=585402).
Demsetz, H. 1967. “Toward a Theory of Property Rights,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 57, 2, pp 347–359.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1968. “Why Regulate Utilities?J. Law Econ, 11, 1, pp 55–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1969. “Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint,” J. Law Econ., 12, 1, pp 1–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demsetz, H. 1988. “Profit as a Functional Return: Reconsidering Knight's Views,” in Demsetz, H., ed., Ownership, Control and the Firm. The Organization of Economic Activity. Oxford and New York, NY: Blackwell, pp 236–247.Google Scholar
Dennen, T. R. 1976. “Cattlemen's Associations and Property Rights in Land in the American West,” Explorations Econ. Hist., 13, 4, pp 423–436.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Denton, M. J., Rassenti, S. J., Smith, V. L., and Backerman, S. R. 2001. “Market Power in a Deregulated Electrical Industry,” Decision Support Systems, 30, 3, pp 357–381.Google Scholar
Denzau, A. T. and Munger, M. C. 1986. “Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests get Represented,” Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., 80, 1, pp 89–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dick, A. R. 1996. “When are Cartels Stable Contracts?J. Law Econ., 39, 1, pp 241–283.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, P. 1994. “Culture and Economy,” in Smelser, N. and Swedberg, R., eds, The Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton University Press, pp 27–57.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. 1996. The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction Cost Politics Perspective. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. 2004. Lawlessness and Economics. Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. and Nalebuff, B. 1993. Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Every Day Life. New York, NY: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Djankov, S. and Murrell, P. 2002. “Enterprise Restructuring in Transition: A Quantitative Survey,” J. Econ. Lit., 40, 3, pp 793–837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. 2003. “The New Comparative Economics,” J. Compar. Econ., 31, 4, pp 595–619.Google Scholar
Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. 2002. “The Regulation of Entry,” Quart. J. Econ., 117, 1, pp 1–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dnes, A. W. 1993. “A Case-Study Analysis of Franchise Contracts,” J. Legal Stud., 22, 2, pp 367–393.Google Scholar
Donaldson, L. 1996. For Positivist Organization Theory: Proving the Hard Core. London: Sage.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. 2000. Innovation, Organization, and Economic Dynamics: Selected Essays. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. and Marengo, L. 1994. “Some Elements of an Evolutionary Theory of Organizational Competences,” in Englander, R. W., ed., Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Economics. Ann Arbor, MI: Michigan University Press, pp 157–178.Google Scholar
Dosi, G. and Marengo, L. 2000. “On the Tangled Discourse between Transaction Cost Economics and Competence-based Views of the Firm: Some Comments,” in Foss, N. J. and Mahnke, V., eds, Competence, Governance, and Entrepreneurship. Oxford University Press, pp 80–92.Google Scholar
Dow, G. K. 1987. “The Function of Authority in Transaction Cost Economics,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 8, 1, pp 13–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dubois, W. E. B. 1965. Three Negro Classics: Up from Slavery. The Souls of Black Folks. The Autobiography of an Ex-Colored Man. New York, NY: Avon Books.Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, M. and Kirchsteiger, G. 2004. “A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity,” Games Econ. Behav., 47, 2, pp 268–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dussauge, P., Garrette, B., and Will, M. 2000. “Learning from Competing Partners: Outcomes and Durations of Scale and Link Alliances in Europe, North America and Asia,” Strategic Manag. J., 21, 2, pp 99–126.3.0.CO;2-G>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutta, S., Bergen, M., Heide, J. B., and John, G. 1995. “Understanding Dual Distribution: The Case of Rep and House Accounts,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 11, 1, pp 189–204.Google Scholar
Duverger, M. 1954. Political Parties: Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. New York, NY: Wiley.Google Scholar
Duxbury, N. 1995. Patterns of American Jurisprudence. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Dyer, J. H. 1997. “Effective Interfirm Collaboration: How Firms Minimize Transaction Costs and Maximize Transaction Value,” Strategic Manage. J., 18, 7, pp 535–356.3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Easterly, W. 2001. The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Edlin, A. S. 1998. “Breach Remedies,” in The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law. London: Macmillan, pp 174–179.Google Scholar
Edlin, A. S. and Reichelstein, S. J. 1996. “Holdups, Standard Breach Remedies, and Optimal Investment,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 86, 3, pp 478–01.Google Scholar
,EDRD (European Bank for Reconstrucion and Development). 2004. Transition Report : Infrastructure, London.
Eggertsson, T. 1990. Economic Behaviour and Institutions. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eilers, C. and Campbell Hanf, C. 1999. “Contracts between Farmers and Farmers Processing Cooperatives: A Principal Agent Approach for the Potato Starch Industry,” in Galizzi, G. and Venturini, L., eds, Vertical Relationships and Coordination in the Food System. Hiedelberg: Physica, pp 267–284.Google Scholar
Elazar, D. J. 1995. “From Statism to Federalism: A Paradigm Shift,” Publius, 25, 2, pp 5–18.Google Scholar
Elfenbein, D. W. and Lerner, J. 2003. “Ownership and Control Rights in Internet Portal Alliances, 1995–1999,” RAND J Econ., 34, 2, pp 356–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J. 1983. Explaining Technical Change. A Case Study in the Philosophy of Science. Cambridge: Cambidge University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, J. 1994. “Arguing and Bargaining in Two Constituent Assemblies,” unpublished manuscript, remarks given at the University of California, Berkeley.
Enikolopov, R. and Zhuravskaya, E. 2003. “Decentralization and Political Institutions,” CEPR Discussion paper 3857.
Ensminger, J. 1992. Making a Market: The Institutional Transformation of an African Society. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Epstein, D. and O'Halloran, S. 1995. “A Theory of Strategic Oversight: Congress, Lobbyist and the Bureaucracy,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 11, 2, pp 227–255.Google Scholar
Epstein, L. 1985. Conservatives in Court. Knoxville, TN: Tennessee University Press.Google Scholar
Eskridge, J. R., William, N. 1991. “Overriding Supreme Court Statutory Interpretation Decisions,” Yale Law J., 101, 2, pp 331–355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, M. 1996. “The Enforcement of Commercial Contracts in Ghana,” World Devel., 24, 3, pp 427–448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fan, J. P. H. 2000. “Price Uncertainty and Vertical Integration: An Examination of Petrochemical Firms,” J. Corp. Finan: Contracting, Governance, and Organ., 6, 4, pp 345–376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fan, J. P.H. and Lang, L. H.P. 2000. “The Measurement of Relatedness: An Application to Corporate Diversification,” J. Bus., 73, 4, pp 629–660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fares, M. and Saussier, S. 2002. “Contrats Incomplets et Coûts de Transaction,” Rev. Fr. Econ., pp 193–230.Google Scholar
Fearon, J. 1999. “Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance,” in Manin, B., Przeworski, A., and Stokes, S., eds, Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press,Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. 2002. “Why Social Preferences Matter. The Impact of Non Selfish Motives on Competition, Cooperation and Incentives,” Econ. J., 112, 478, pp C1–C33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gachter, S. 2000. “Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity,” J. Econ. Perspect., 14, pp. 159–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E. and Gachter, S. 2002. “Do Incentive Contracts Crowd-out Voluntary Cooperation?” Work paper W34. (Available at: www.iew.unizh.ch/wp/iewwp034.pdf).
Fehr, E. and Gächter, S. 2006. “Reciprocity and Contract Enforcement,” Handbook of Experimental Economics, in press.Google Scholar
Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. 1999. “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation,” Quart. J. Econ., 114, pp 769–816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E., Klein, A., and Schmidt, K. 2001. “Fairness, Incentives and Contractual Incompleteness,” CESifo work paper W445, Zurich IEER work paper W72. (Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=262015).
Fein, A. J. and Anderson, E. 1997. “Patterns of Credible Commitments: Territory and Brand Selectivity in Industrial Distribution Channels,” J. Marketing, 61, 2, pp 19–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, L. P. and Kirchgässner, G. 2001. “The Political Economy of Direct Legislation: Direct Democracy and Local Decision-Making,” Econ. Pol. Rev., 33, pp 329–367.Google Scholar
Feld, L. P. and Savioz, M. R. 1997. “Direct Democracy Matters for Economic Performance: An Empirical Investigation,” Kyklos, 50, 4, pp 507–538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, L. P. and Voigt, S. 2003. “Economic Growth and Judicial Independence: Cross-Country Evidence Using a New Set of Indicators,” Europ. J. Polit. Economy, 19, 3, pp 497–527.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feld, L. P. and Voigt, S. 2004. “Making Judges Independent – Some Proposals Regarding the Judiciary,” CESifo work paper W1260.
Feld, L., Kirchgässner, G., and Schaltegger, C. 2003. “Decentralized Taxation and the Size of Government: Evidence from Swiss State and Local Governments,” CESifo Work paper W1087.
Feld, L., Zimmermann, H., and Doring, T. 2004. “Federalism, Decentralization and Economic Growth,” Discussion Paper Series Work papers 200430, Philipps-Universität Marburg, Faculty of Business Administration and Economics, Department of Economics (Volkswirtschaftliche Abteilung).
Felin, T. and Foss, N. 2004. “Methodological Individualism and the Organizational Capabilities Approach,” Work paper W2004-5, Center for Knowledge Governance, Copenhagen Business School. (Available at www.cbs.dk/ckg).
Ferejohn, J. 1999. “Accountability and Authority: Toward a Theory of Political Accountability,” in Manin, B., Przeworski, A., and Stokes, S., eds, Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. and Shipan Charles, C. 1990. “Congressional Influence on Bureaucracy,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 6, pp 1–20.Google Scholar
Festré, A. and Garrouste, P. 2006. “Incentives and Motivations: To What Extent Can Economics Benefit from Psychology?” Mimeo, ATOM, University of Paris 1.
Figueiredo, R. J. and Weingast, B. R. 2005. “Self-Enforcing Federalism,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 21, 1, pp 103–135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiorina, M. P. 1982. “Legislative Choice of Regulatory Forms: Legal Process or Administrative Process?Public Choice, 39, 1, pp 33–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, F. M. 1989. “Games Economists Play: A Non-Cooperative View,” RAND J. Econ., 20, 1, pp 113–124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R. J. and Gatti, R. 2002. “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries,” J. Public Econ., 83, pp 325–345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, K. and Foss, N. J. 2001. “Assets, Attributes and Ownership,” Int. J. Econ. Bus., 8, pp 19–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. 1993. “Theories of the Firm: Contractual and Competence Perspectives,” J. Evolutionary Econ., 3, 2, pp 127–144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. 2000. The Theory of the Firm. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. 2002. “The Rhetorical Dimensions of Bounded Rationality: Herbert A. Simon and Organizational Economics,” in Rizzelo, S., ed., Cognitive Paradigms in Economics. London: Routledge, pp 158–176.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. 2003. “Herbert Simon's Grand Theme in the Economics of Organization: Much Cited and Little Used,” J. Econ. Psych., 24, pp 245–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. 2005. Strategy and Economic Organization in the Knowledge Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Foss, N. J. and Klein, P. 2005. “Entrepreneuship and the Theory of the Firm: Any Gains From Trade?” in Agarwal, R., Alvarez, S. A., and Sorenson, O., eds, Handbook of Entrepreneurship: Disciplinary Perspectives. New York, NY: Kluwer.Google Scholar
Frank, R. H. 1987. “If Homo Economicus Could Choose His Own Utility Function, Would He Want One with a Conscience?Amer. Econ. R., 79, 3, pp 594–596.Google Scholar
Frank, S. D. and Henderson, D. R. 1992. “Transaction Costs as Determinants of Vertical Coordination in the US Food Industries,” Amer. J. Agr. Econ., 74, 4, pp 941–950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeland, R. F. 2002. “The Firm as a Minisociety,” draft manuscript.
Frey, B. S. 1997. Not Just for the Money: An Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. 1997. “The Cost of Price Incentives: An Empirical Analysis of Motivation Crowding-Out,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 87, 4, pp 746–755.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Stutzer, A. 2006. “Direct Democracy: Designing a Living Constitution,” in Congleton, R., ed., Democratic Constitutional Design and Public Policy – Analysis and Evidence, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, D. 1998. “Law and Economics,” in The New Palgrave. A Dictionary in Economics. London: Macmillan, pp 144–147.Google Scholar
Friedman, J. W. 1971. “A Non-Cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames,” Rev. Econ. Stud., 28, pp 1–12.Google Scholar
Friedman, M. 1997. “Modern Macroeconomics and its Evolution from a Monetarist Perspective,” Rev. Econ. Stud, 24, 4, pp 192–222.Google Scholar
Fuller, L. 1969. The Morality of Law. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Furquim de Azevedo, P. and Dos Santos Silva, V. L. 2001. “Contractual Mix Analysis in the Brazilian Franchising,” Work paper, University of Sao Paulo.
Furubotn, E. 2002. “Entrepreneurship, Transaction-Cost Economics, and the Design of Contracts,” in Brousseau, E. and Glachant, J.-M., eds, The Economics of Contracts. Cambridge University Press, pp 72–97.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. 1997. Institutions and Economic Theory: An Introduction to and Assessment of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. 2000. Institutions and Economics Theory: The Contributions of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Gagne, M. and Deci, E. L. 2005. “Self-Determination Theory and Work Motivation,” J. Organ. Behavior, 26, pp 331–362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gallini, N. T. and Lutz, N. A. 1992. “Dual Distribution and Royalty Fees in Franchising,” J Law, Econ. Organ. 8, 3, pp 471–501.Google Scholar
Gallo, A. 2003. The Political Economy of Argentine Development. PhD dissertation, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.
Gambetta, D. 1988. Trust, Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Gandal, N., Salant, D., and Waverman, L. 2003. “Standards in Wireless Telephone Networks,” Telecommunications Pol. 27, pp 325–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia-Canal, E. 1996. “Contractual Form in Domestic and International Strategic Alliances,” Organization Studies, 17, 5, pp 773–794.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garicano, L. 2000. “Hierarchies and the Organization of Knowledge in Production,” J. Polit. Economy, 108, 5, pp 874–904.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garrouste, P. 2004. “The New Property Rights Theory of the Firm,” in Colombatto, E., ed., The Edward Elgar Companion to the Economics of Property Rights, E. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp 370–382.Google Scholar
Garrouste, P. and Saussier, S. 2005. “Looking for a Theory of the Firm,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 58, 2, pp 178–199.Google Scholar
Geddes, R. R. 1997. “Ownership, Regulation, and Managerial Monitoring in the Electric Utility Industry,” J. Law Econ., 40, 1, pp 261–288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gely, R. and Spiller, P. T. 1990. “A Rational Choice Theory of Supreme Court Statutory Decisions with Applications to the State Farm and Grove City Cases,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 6, 2, pp 263–300.Google Scholar
Gely, R. and Spiller, P. T. 1992a. “The Political Economy of Supreme Court Constitutional Decisions: The Case of Roosevelt's Court-Packing Plan,” Int. Rev. Law Econ., 12, 1, pp 45–67.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, N. 1971. The Entropy Law and Economic Process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geringer, M. J. and Hebert, L. 1989. “The Importance of Control in International Joint Ventures,” J. Int. Bus. Stud., 20, pp 235–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geringer, M. J. and Hebert, L. 1991. “Measuring Performance of International Joint Ventures,” J. Int. Bus. Stud., 22, 2, pp 249–264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gersbach, H. 2004. “Fiscal Constitutions,” Constit. Polit. Economy, 15, 1, pp 3–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghosh, M. and John, G. 1999. “Governance Value Analysis and Marketing Strategy,” J. Marketing, 63, pp 131–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghoshal, S. and Moran, P. 1996. “Bad for Practice: A Critique of the Transaction Cost Theory,” Acad. Man. Rev., 21, 1, pp 13–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, R. S. 1992. Game Theory for Applied Economists. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. S. 2000. “Why Organizations Are Such a Mess (and What an Economist Might Do About It)?” MIT Sloan work paper. (Available at: http://web.mit.edu/rgibbons/www/Org_mess.pdf).
Gibbons, R. S. 2001. “Trust in Social Structures: Hobbes and Coase Meet Repeated Games,” in Cook, K., ed., Trust in Society. New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation, pp 332–353.Google Scholar
Gibbons, R. S. 2005. “Four Formalizeable Theories of the Firm,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 58, 2, pp 200–245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. 2000. Adaptive Thinking: Rationality in the Real World. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, G. and Todd, P. 1999. “Fast and Frugal Heuristics: The Adaptive Toolbox,” in Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M., and ,the ABC Research Group, eds, Simple Heuristics That Make Us Smart. G. New York, NY: Oxford University Press, pp 3–34.Google Scholar
Ginsburg, T. 2002. “Economic Analysis and the Design of Constitutional Courts,” Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 3, 1, pp 49–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. 1998. “England Wholesale Electricity Market,” Utilities Policy, 7, pp 63–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. 2002. “Why Regulate Deregulated Network Industries?J. Network Industries, 3, pp 297–311.Google Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. and Finon, D. 2000. “Why do the European Union's electricity industries continue to differ? A new institutional analysis,” in Ménard, Claude, eds., Institutions, Contracts and Organizations. Edward Elgar, pp. 313–34.Google Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. and Finon, D. 2003. Competition in European Electricity Markets: A Cross Country Comparison. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. and Finon, D. 2006. “France Electricity Reform: A Competitive Fringe in the Shadow of a State Owned Incumbent,” in Energy Journal, 26.Google Scholar
Glachant, J.-M. and Lévêque, F. 2007. European Union Electricity Internal Market: Towards an Achievement?Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Glachant, J.-M., Dubois, U., Perez, Y. 2007. “Deregulating with No Regulator: Is the German Electricity Transmission Regime Institutionally Correct? Energy Policy, 36, pp 1600–1610.
Glaeser, E. L. and Shleifer, A. 2003. “The Rise of the Regulatory State,” J. Econ. Lit., 41, 2, pp 401–425.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, E. L., Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. 2004. “Do Institutions Cause Growth?J. Econ. Growth, 9, 3, pp 271–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gneezy, U. and Rustichini, A. 2000. “Pay Enough or Don't Pay at All,” Quart. J. Econ., 115, 3, pp 791–810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, V. P. 1976. “Regulation and Administered ContractsBell J. Econ., 7, 2, pp 426–452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomes-Casseres, B. 1989. “Ownership Structures of Foreign Subsidiaries: Theory and Evidence,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 11, 1, pp 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomes-Casseres, B. 1994. “Group vs. Group: How Alliance Networks Compete,” Harvard Bus. Rev., 72, 4, pp 62–74.Google Scholar
Gomes-Casseres, B. 1996. The Alliance Revolution. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gomez-Ibanez, J. 2003. Regulating Infrastructure: Monopoly, Contracts and Discretion. Boston, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Gompers, P. A. and Lerner, J. 1996. “The Use of Covenants: An Empirical Analysis of Venture Partnership Agreements,” J. Law Econ., 39, 2, pp 405–434.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González-Díaz, M., Arruñada, B., and Fernández, A. 1998. “Regulation as Cause of Firm Fragmentation: The Case of Spanish Construction Industry,” Int. Rev. Law Econ., 18, 4, pp 433–450.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Scott H. 1954. “The Economic Theory of A Common-property Resource: The Fishery,” J. Polit. Economy, 62, 2, pp 124–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goshal, S. and Moran, P. 1996. “Bad Practice: A Critique of Transaction Cost Theory,” Academy of Management Review, 21, 1, pp 13–47.Google Scholar
Grafton, Q. R., Squires, D., and Fox, K. J. 2000. “Private Property and Economic Efficiency: A Study of a Common-Pool Resource,” J. Law Econ., 43, pp 679–713.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. 1985. “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,” Amer. J. Sociology, 91, 3, pp 481–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greene, W. 2003. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Green, R., Lorenzoni, A., Perez, Y. and Pollitt, M. 2006. “Benchmarking in the European Union,” work paper, University of Cambridge.
Greif, A. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions in Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders,” J. Econ. Hist., 49, 4, pp 857–882.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. 1992. “Institutions and International Trade: Lessons from the Commercial Revolution,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 82, 2, pp 128–33.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade: The Magrhibi Traders Coalition,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 83, 3, pp 525–548.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 1994. “Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A Historical and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies,” J. Pol. Econ., 102, 5, pp 912–950.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. 1997. “Microtheory and Recent Developments in the Study of Economic Institutions Through Economic History,” in Kreps, D. and Wallis, K., eds, Advances in Economic Theory. Cambridge University Press, pp 79–113.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 1998. “Historical and Comparative Institutional Analysis,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 88, 2, pp 80–89.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2000. “Economic History and Game Theory: A Survey,” in Aumann, R. and Hart, S., eds, Handbook of Game Theory. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2004. Institutions: Theory and History. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2005. “Commitment, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds, Handbook of New Institutional Economics, New York, NY: Kluwer Academic Press, pp 727–786.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A., Milgrom, P., and Weingast, B. R. 1994. “Coordination, Commitment and Enforcement: The Case of the Merchant Guild,” J. Polit. Economy, 102, 4, pp 745–776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin, R. C. and Boadu, F. O. 1992. “Water Marketing in Texas: Opportunities for Reform,” Natural Res. J., 32, pp 265–288.Google Scholar
Grimes, G., Plain, R., and Meyer, S. 2004. “US Hog Marketing Contract Study,” University of Missouri, Work paper AEWP 2004–07.
Grosfeld, I. and Nivet, J.-F. 1999. “Insider Power and Wage Setting in Transition: Evidence from a Panel of Large Polish Firms,” Europ. Econ. Rev., 43, 4, pp 1137–1147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, S. J. and Hart, O. D. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” J. Polit. Economy, 94, 4, pp 691–719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guash, J. L. 2004. Granting and Renegotiating Infrastructure Concessions: Doing It Right. Washington, DC: World Bank Institute.Google Scholar
Guash, J. L. and Spiller, P. 1999. Managing the Regulatory Process: Design, Concepts, Issues, and the Latin America and Caribbean Story, Washington, DC: International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Chapter 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulati, R. 1995a. “Does Familiarity Breed Trust? The Implications of Repeated Ties for Contractual Choice in Alliances,” Academy of Manage. J., 38, 1, pp 85–112.Google Scholar
Gulati, R. 1995b. “Social Structure and Alliance Formation Patterns: A Longitudinal Analysis,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 4, pp 619–650.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulati, R. 1999. “Network Location and Learning: The Influence of Network Resources and Firm Capabilities on Alliance Formation,” Strategic Manage. J., 20, 5, pp 397–420.3.0.CO;2-K>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulati, R. and Nickerson, J. 2005. Interorganizational-Trust: The Choice of Make, Buy, or Ally; and the Performance of Interorganizational Relationships in the U.S. Auto Industry. Manuscript, Olin School of Business.Google Scholar
Gulati, R. and Nickerson, J. A., forthcoming. “Inter–organizational Trust: the Choice of Make, Buy, or Ally; and the Performance of Interorganizational Relationships in the US. Auto Industry”, Organization Science.
Gulati, R., Lawrence, P. R., and Puranam, P. 2005. “Adaptation in Vertical Relationships: Beyond Incentive Conflict,” Strategic Manage. J., 26, 5, pp 415–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., Bernd Schwarz, B. 1982. “An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 3, pp 367–388.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haas, R., Glachant, J.-M., Perez, Y., Auer, H., and Keseric, N. 2007. “The Liberalisation of the Continental European Electricity Market,” Energy Stud. Rev., 14, 2, pp 1–29.Google Scholar
Hadfield, G. K. 1990. “Problematic Relations: Franchising and the Law of Incomplete Contracts,” Stanford Law Rev., 42, pp 927–992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hadfield, G. K. 2000. “Privatizing Commercial Law: Lessons from the Middle and the Digital Ages,” Work paper 195, John M. Olin program in Law and Economics, Standford Law School.
Hadfield, G. K. 2005. “The Many Legal Institutions that Support Contractual Commitments,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds, Handbook of New Institutional Economics. New York, NY: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp 175–204.Google Scholar
Haggard, S. 2000. “Interest, Institutions and Policy Reform,” in Krueger, A. O., ed., Economic Policy Reform: The Second Stage. Chicago University Press, pp 21–61.Google Scholar
Håkansson, H. and Snehota, I. 1990. “No Business is an Island: The Network Concept of Business Strategy,” Scand. J. Man., 5, pp 187–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamel, G. 1991. “Competition for Competence and Inter-Partner Learning within International Strategic Alliances,” Strategic Manage. J., 12, pp 82–103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, B. H. and Nickerson, J. A. 2003. “Correcting for Endogeneity in Strategic Management Research,” Strategic Organ, 1, 1, pp. 53–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, B. H., Nickerson, J. A., and Owan, H. (2003) “Team Incentives and Worker Heterogeneity: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Teams on Productivity and Participation,” Journal of Political Economy, 111, 3, pp 465–497.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. 1963. “The Evolution of Altruistic Behavior,” Amer. Naturalist, 97, pp 354–356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, W. D. 1964. “The Genetical Evolution of Social Behaviour I and II,” J. Theoretical Biology, 7, pp 1–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannan, M. T. and Freeman, J. 1984. “Structural Inertia and Organizational Change,” Amer. Sociological Rev., 49, pp 149–164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hannan, M. T. and Freeman, J. 1989. Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hansmann, H. and Kraakman, R. 2002. “Property, Contract, and Verification: The Numerus Clausus Problem and the Divisibility of Rights,” Harvard Law School Public Law Research paper 37.
Hanssen, A. F. 2004. “Is There a Politically Optimal Level of Judicial Independence?Amer. Econ. Rev., 94, 3, pp 712–729.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, R. 1989. “Why a Constitution?” in Grofman, B. and Wittman, D., eds, The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism. New York, NY: Agathon Press, pp 100–120.Google Scholar
Harrigan, K. R. 1985. “Vertical Integration and Corporate Strategy,” Acad. Manage. J., 28, 2, pp 397–425.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. 1988. “Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 4, pp 119–141. Reprinted in Williamson O. E. and Winter S. G., eds, 1991, The Nature of the Firm. Oxford University Press, pp 138–159.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. 1990. “Is ‘Bounded Rationality’ an Important Element of a Theory of Institutions?J. Inst. Theoretical Econ., 146, pp 696–702.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. 1995. Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. and Holmström, B. 1987. “The Theory of the Contracts,” in Bewley, T., ed., Advances in Economic Theory, Fifth World Congress. Cambridge University Press, pp 71–85.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. and Holmström, B. 2002. “A Theory of Firm Scope,” Mimeo. (Available at: http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/download_pdf.php?id=514).
Hart, O. D. and Moore, J. 1988. “Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation,” Econometrica, 56, 4, pp 755–785.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. and Moore, J. 1990. “Property Rights and the Nature of the Firm,” J. Polit. Economy, 98, pp 1119–1158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. and Moore, J. 1999. “Foundations of Incomplete Contracts,” Rev. Econ. Stud., 66, 1, pp 115–138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. and Moore, J. 2004. “Agreeing Now to Agree Later: Contracts that Rule Out but do not Rule In,” Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper, 465.
Hart, O. D. and Moore, J. 2005. “On the Design of Hierarchies: Coordination Versus Specialization with John Moore,” J Political Econ., 113, 4, pp 675–702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, J. S. Jr. 2005. “Why Did You Do That? An Economic Examination of the Effect of Extrinsic Compensation on Intrinsic Motivation and Performance,” J. Econ. Psych., 26, 4, 549–566.
Hatzis, A. 2000. “The Anti-Theoretic Nature of Civil Law Contract Scholarship and the Need for an Economic Theory,” Mimeo, Chicago Law School, and University of Thessalonica.
Hatzis, A. 2006. “Civil Contract Law and Economic Reasoning: An Unlikely Pair?” in Grundmann, S. and Schauer, M., eds, The Architecture of European Codes and Contract Law. Kluwer Law International, Private Law in European Context Series, 8, pp 159–191.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y. 1998. “Introduction,” in Toward the Rural-Based Development of Commerce and Industry: Selected Experiences from East Asia, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y. and Kikuchi, M. 1981. Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads: An Economic Approach to Institutional Change. Tokyo University Press, Baltimore, MD, and London: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y. and Kikuchi, M. 2000. A Rice Village Saga –Three Decades of Green Revolution in the Philippines, Lanham. Boulder, CO, and New York, NY: Barnes & Noble.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1944. The Road to Serfdom. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1945. “The Use of Knowledge in Society,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 35, pp 519–530.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1948. Individualism and Economic Order. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1973. Law, Legislation and Liberty, Vol.1: Rules and Order. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Hayo, B. and Voigt, S. 2007. “Explaining De Facto Judicial Independence,” Int. Rev. Law Econ., 27, 3, 269–290.Google Scholar
Heiman, B. A. and Nickerson, J. A. 2002. “Towards Reconciling Transaction Cost Economics and the Knowledge-based View of the Firm: The Context of Interfirm Collaborations,” Int. J. Econ. Bus., 9, pp 97–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heiman, B. A. and Nickerson, J. A. 2004. “Empirical Evidence Regarding the Tension between Knowledge Sharing and Knowledge Expropriation in Collaborations,” Managerial Dec. Econ., 25, pp 401–420.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helland, E. and Sykuta, M. 2004. “Regulation and the Evolution of Corporate Boards: Monitoring, Advising, or Window Dressing?J. Law Econ., 47, 1, pp 167–194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heller, M. A. 1998. “The Tragedy of the Anticommons: Property in the Transition from Marx to Markets,” Harvard Law Rev., 111, 3, pp 621–688.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hellman, J. S., Jones, G., and Kaufmann, D. 2003. “Seize the State, Seize the Day: State Capture and Influence in Transition Economies,” J. Comp. Econ., 31, 4, pp 751–773.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helm, D. 2004. Energy, the State and the Market: British Energy Policy Since 1979. Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendrikse, G. W. J. and Bijman, J. 2002. “Ownership Structure in Agrifood Chains: The Marketing Cooperative,” Amer. J. Agr. Econ., 84, pp 104–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendrikse, G. W. J. and Veerman, C. P. 2001a. “Marketing Cooperatives and Financial Structure: A Transaction Cost Economics Analysis,” J. Agr. Econ., 26, pp 205–216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendrikse, G. W. J. and Bijman, J. 2001b. “Marketing Cooperatives: An Incomplete Contracting Perspective,” J. Agr. Econ., 52, pp. 53–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J. 2000a. “The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth,” Econ. Politics, 12, 1, pp 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J. 2000b. “The Institutional Environment for Multinational Investment,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 16, 2, pp 334–364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W. J. and Williamson, O. E. 1999. “Comparative Economic Organization – Within and Between Countries,” Bus. Polit, 1, 3, pp 261–276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hennart, J.-F. 1991. “The Transaction Cost Theory of Joint Ventures: An Empirical Study of Japanese Subsidiaries in the US,” Manage. Sci., pp 483–497.Google Scholar
Hennart, J.-F. 1993. “Explaining the Swollen Middle: Why Most Transactions Are a Mix of Market and Hierarchy,” Organization Sci., 4, 4, pp 529–547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., and McElreath, R. 2001. “Cooperation, Reciprocity and Punishment in Fifteen Small-Scale Societies,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 91, pp 73–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. 2005. “‘Economic Man’ in Cross-Cultural Perspective: Behavioral Experiments in fifteen Small-Scale Societies,” Behavioral and Brain Science, 28, pp 795–815.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Herbert, S. A. 1962. “The Architecture of Complexity,” Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society, 106, pp 467–482.Google Scholar
Hill, C. A. 2001. “Why Contracts are Written in Legalese,” Chicago Kent Law Rev., 77, 1, pp 59–85.Google Scholar
Hillman, A. J. and Hitt, M. A. 1999. “Corporate Political Strategy Formulation: A Model of Approach, Participation, and Strategy Decisions,” Academy Manage. Rev., 24, 4, pp 825–842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hiroux, C. 2004. “Shallow Cost and Deep Cost, An Assessment,” Work paper GRJM, Université Paris-Sud 11.
Hirschmann, A. 1970. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Ho, T.-H. and Weigelt, K. 1996. “Task Complexity, Equilibrium Selection, and Learning: An Experimental Study,” Manage. Sci., 42, pp 659–679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 1989. Economics and Institutions: A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Oxford: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 1998. “Competence and Contract in the Theory of the Firm,” J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 35, pp 179–201.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 2004a. The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism. London and New York, NY: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. 2004b. “Veblen and Darwinism,” International R. Sociology, 14, pp 343–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoetker, G. 2005. “How Much You Know versus How Will I Know You: Supplier Selection for Innovative Components,” Strategic Manage. J., 26, 1, pp 75–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hohfeld, W. N. 1919. Fundamental Legal Conceptions. New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Hojnacky, M. and Kimball, D. C. 1998. “Organized Interests and the Decision of Whom to Lobby in Congress,” Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., 92, 4, pp 775–790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holburn, G. and Spiller, P. 2002. “Institutional or Structural: Lessons from International Electricity Sector Reforms,” in Brousseau, E. and Glachant, J.-M., eds, The Economics of Contracts: Theories and Applications. Cambridge University Press, pp 463–502.Google Scholar
Holburn, G., and Burgh, R. 2004. “Influencing Agencies through Pivotal Political Institutions,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 20, 2, pp 458–483.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, B. 1999. “The Firm as a Subeconomy,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 1, pp 74–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, B. and Milgrom, P. 1991. “Multitask Principal–Agent Analysis: Incentive Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job Design,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 7, pp 24–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmström, B. and Milgrom, P. 1994. “The Firm as an Incentive System,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 84, pp 972–991.Google Scholar
Holmstrom, B. and Roberts, J. 1998. “The Boundaries of the Firm Revisited,” J. Econ. Perspect., 12, pp 73–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, H. 1938. “The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Taxation and of Railway and Utility Rates,” Econometrica, 6, 3, pp 242–269.Google Scholar
Houser, D. and Wooders, J. 2005. “Reputation in Auctions: Theory and Evidence from eBay,” J. Econ. Manage. Strategy, 15, 2, pp 353–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hovenkamp, H. 1994. Federal Antitrust Policy: The Law of Competition and its Practice. St. Paul, MN: West Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Howe, C. W., Boggs, C. S., and Butler, P. 1990. “Transaction Costs as Determinants of Water Transfers,” University of Colorado Law R., 61, pp 393–405.Google Scholar
Hubbard, G. R. and Weiner, R. J. 1991. “Efficient Contracting and Market Power: Evidence from the U.S. Natural Gas Industry,” J. Law Econ., 34, 1, pp 25–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hubbard, T. N. 2001. “Contractual Form and Market Thickness in Trucking,” RAND J. Econ., 32, 2, pp 369–386.Google Scholar
Huet, F. 2006. “Partenariats Publics–Privés et Concurrence pour le Marché: Quelles Avancées depuis Demsetz (1968)?” Work paper ATOM, Université Paris 1.
Huntington, S. 1996. The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order. New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Hurwicz, L. 1972. “On Informationally Decentralized Systems,” in McGuire, C. B. and Radner, R., eds, Decision and Organization. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp 297–336.Google Scholar
Iaryczower, M., Spiller, P. T., and Tommasi, M. 2002. “Judicial Independence in an Unstable Environment, Argentina 1935–1998,” Amer. J. Politic. Sci., 46, 4, pp 699–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iaryczower, M., Spiller, P. T., and Tommasi, M. 2006. “Judicial Lobbying: The Politics of Labor Law Constitutional Interpretation,” Amer. J. Politic. Sci., 100, 1, pp 85–97.Google Scholar
,IEA (International Energy Agency). 2001. Regulatory Institutions in Liberalised Electricity Markets. AIE OCDE.
Inman, R. P. and Rubinfeld, D. L. 1997. “Rethinking Federalism,” J. Econ. Perspect., 11, 4, pp 43–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iverson, T. and Soskice, D. 2006. “Electoral Institutions and the Politics of Coalitions: Why Some Democracies Redistribute more Than Others,” American Political Science Review, 100, pp 165–181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacquemin, A. and Slade, M. 1989 “Cartels, Collusion, and Horizontal Merger,” in Schmalensee, R. and Willigm, R. D., eds, Handbook of Industrial Organization. Amsterdam: North-Holland, pp 415–473.Google Scholar
James, H. S. Jr. and Sykuta, M. E. 2004. “Generalized and Particularized Trust in Organizations,” University of Missouri, work paper, presented at the 2004 ISNIE meetings in Tucson, AZ. (Available at: http://cori.missouri.edu/jamesh/).
James, H. S. Jr. and Sykuta, M. S. 2005. “Organizational Antecedents of Trust in Producer-Owned Firms,” Ann. Public Coop. Econ., 76, 4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, H. S. Jr. and Sykuta, M. S. 2006. “Farmer Trust in Producer- and Investor-Owned Firms: Evidence from Missouri Corn and Soybean Producers,” Agribusiness: An International Journal, 22, 1, pp 135–153.Google Scholar
Johnson, R. N. and Libecap, G. D. 1982. “Contracting Problems and Regulation: The Case of the Fishery,” Amer. Econ.Rev., 72, 5, pp 1005–1022.Google Scholar
Johnson, R. N. and Libecap, G. D. 1994. The Federal Civil Service System and the Problem of Bureaucracy: The Economics and Politics of Institutional Change. Chicago University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, R. N. and Libecap, G. D. 2001. “Information Distortion and Competitive Remedies in Government Transfer Programs: The Case of Ethanol,” Econ. Governance, 2, 2, pp 1001–1034.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, S., McMillan, J., and Woodruff, C. 2000. “Entrepreneurs and the Ordering of Institutional Reform,” Econ. Transition, 8, 1, pp 1–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, S., McMillan, J., and Woodruff, C. 2002a. “Courts and Relational Contract,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 18, 1, pp 221–277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, Simon; McMillan, J., and Woodruff, Christopher. 2002b. “Property Rights and Finance,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 92, 5, pp 1335–1356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., and Thaler, R. 1998. “A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics,” Stanford Law Rev., 50, pp 683–668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, C., Hesterly, W. S. and Borgatti, S. P. 1997. “A General Theory of Network Governance: Exchange Conditions and Social Mechanisms,” Academy of Management Review, 22, 4, pp 911–945.Google Scholar
Jones, D. C. and Mygind, N. 2000. “The Effects of Privatization upon Productive Efficiency: Evidence from the Baltic Republics,” Ann. Public Coop. Econ., 71, 3, pp 415–439.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, M. P., Saiegh, S., Spiller, P. T., and Tommasi, M. 2002. “Amateur Legislators – Professional Politicians: The Consequences of Party-Centered Electoral Rules in a Federal System,” Amer. J. Politic. Sci., 46, 3, pp 656–669.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 1985. “Vertical Integration and Long Term Contracts: The Case of Coal Burning Electric Generating Plants,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 1, 1, pp 33–80.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 1987. “Contract Duration and Relationship-Specific Investment: Empirical Evidence from Coal Markets,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 77, 1, pp 168–185.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 1988. “Asset Specificity and the Structure of Vertical Relationships: Empirical Evidence,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 4, 95–117.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 1991. “The Role of Transaction Cost Economics in Antitrust and Public Utility Regulation,” J. Law Econ. Organ., 7, pp 53–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 1996. “Introducing Competition into Regulated Network Industries: From Hierarchies to Markets in Electricity,” Ind. Corp. Change, 5, 2, pp 341–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. 2002. “Transaction Costs Economics, Antitrust Rules and Remedies,” J. Law, Econ. Organ., 18, 1, pp 95–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 2003. “New Institutional Economics: A Report Card,” ISNIE Presidential Address: Budapest, Hungary.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. 2004. “Vertical Integration,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds, Handbook of New Institutional Economics. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic Publishers, pp 319–348.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. and Schmalensee, R. 1983. Markets for Power, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. and Tirole, J. 2000. “Transmission Rights and Market Power on Electric Power Network I: Financial Rights,” RAND J. Econ., 31, 3, pp 450–487.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kagel, J. and Roth, A. 1995. The Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kahn, A. 1970–1971. The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions. Chichester: Wiley.Google Scholar
Kahneman, D. and Tversky, A. 1979. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decisions Under Risk,” Econometrica, 47, pp 263–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kale, P., Singh, H., and Perlmutter, H. 2000. “Learning and Protection of Proprietary Assets in Strategic Alliances: Building Relational Capital,” Strategic. Manage. J., 21, pp 217–237.3.0.CO;2-Y>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kale, P., Dyer, J. H., and Singh, H. 2002. “Alliance Capability, Stock Market Response, and Long-Term Alliance Success: The Role of the Alliance Function,” Strategic. Manage. J., 23, pp 747–767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalnins, A. and Lafontaine, F. 2004. “Multi-Unit Ownership in Franchising: Evidence from the Texan Fast-Food Industry,” RAND J. Econ., 35, 4, pp 747–761.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalnins, A. and Mayer, J. K. 2004. “Relationships and Hybrid Contracts: An Analysis of Contract Choice in Information Technology,” J. Law Econ.Organ., 20, 1, pp 207–229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, H. and Hill, K. 1985. “Food Sharing among Ache Foragers: Test of Explanatory Hypotheses,” Current Anthropology, 26, pp 223–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaufmann, P. J. and Lafontaine, F. 1994. “Costs of Control: The Source of Economic Rents for McDonald's Franchisees,” J Law Econ., 37, pp 417–454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, P. and Knack, S. 1997. “Why Don't Poor Countries Catch Up? A Cross-National Test of an Institutional Environment,” Econ. Inquiry, 35, pp 590–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keeley, L. 1996. War Before Civilization: The Myth of the Peaceful Savage. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kelsen, H. 1992. Introduction to the Problems of Legal Theory. A translation of the first edition of the Reine Rechtlehere. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Kessides, L. 2004. “Reforming Infrastructure: Privatization, Regulation, and Competition,” World Bank Policy Research Report. Washington, DC: World Bank and Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khanna, T., Gulati, R., and Nitin, N. 1998. “The Dynamics of Learning Alliances: Competition, Cooperation and Relative Scope,” Strategic. Manage. J., 19, 3, pp 193–210.3.0.CO;2-C>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Killing, P. 1983. Strategies for Joint Venture Success. London: Croom Helm.Google Scholar
Killing, P. 1988. “Understanding Alliances: The Role of Task and Organizational Complexity,” in Contractor, F. and Lorange, P., eds, Cooperative Strategies in International Business. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Kim, C. W. and Hwang, P. 1992. “Global Strategy and Multinationals' Entry Mode Choice,” J. Int. Bus. Stud., 23, 1, pp 29–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchgässner, G. and Frey, B. 1990. “Volksabstimmung und direkte Demokratie: Ein Beitrag zur Verfassungsdiskussion,” in Klingmann, H. D. and Kaase, M., eds, Wahlen und Wähler – Analysen aus Anlaß der Bundestagswahl. Westdeutscher Verlag: Opladen, pp 42–69.Google Scholar
Kirstein, R. and Voigt, S. 2006. “The Violent and the Weak: When Dictators Care About Social Contracts,” Amer. J. Econ. Sociology, 65, 4, pp 863–889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirzner, I. 1973. Competition and Entrepreneurship. Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Kiwit, D. and Voigt, S. 1998. “The Role and Evolution of Beliefs, Habits, Moral Norms, and Institutions,” in Giersch, H., ed., Merits and Limits of Markets. Berlin: Springer, pp 83–108.Google Scholar
Klein, B. 1980. “Transaction Cost Determinants of Unfair Contractual Arrangements,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 70, pp 356–362.Google Scholar
Klein, B. 1988. “Vertical Integration as Organizational Ownership: The Fisher Body–General Motors Relationship Revisited,” J. Law, Econ., Organ., 4, 1, pp 199–213.Google Scholar
Klein, B. 1995. “The Economics of Franchise Contracts,” J. Corp. Finan., 2, 1/2, pp 9–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B. 1996. “Why Hold-Ups Occur? The Self Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships,” Econ. Inquiry, 34, pp 444–463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B. and Leffler, K. B. 1981. “The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance,” J. Polit. Economy, 89, 41, pp 615–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B. and Murphy, K. 1997. “Vertical Integration as a Self-Enforcing Contractual Arrangement,” Amer. Econ. Rev., 87, 2, pp 415–420.Google Scholar
Klein, B. and Saft, L. F. 1985. “The Law and Economics of Franchise Tying Contracts,” J. Law Econ., 27, pp 345–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., and Alchian, A. A. 1978. “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process,” J. Law Econ., 21, 2, pp 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, P. G. 2005. “The Make-or-Buy Decision: Lessons from Empirical Studies,” in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. M., eds, Handbook on New Institutional Economics. New York, NY: Springer, pp 435–464.Google Scholar
Kleither, G. D., Krebs, M., Doherty, M. E., Garavan, H., Chadwick, R., and Brake, G. 1997. “Do Subjects Understand Base Rates,” Orga. Behav. Human Dec. Process., 72, pp 25–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klemperer, P. 2002. “What Really Matters in Auction Design,” J. Econ. Perspect., 16, 1, pp 169–190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. 1997. “Does Social Capital Have an Economic Payoff? A Cross-Country Investigation,” Quart. J. Econ., 112, 4, pp 1251–1288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, F. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. 1964 reprint. New York, NY: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knoeber, C. R. 1989. “A Real Game of Chicken: Contracts, Tournaments, and the Production of Broilers,” J. Law Econ. Organ., 5, pp 271–292.Google Scholar
Knoeber, C. R. 2000. “Land and Livestock Contracting in Agriculture: A Principal–Agent Perspective,” in Bouckaert, B. and Geest, G., eds, Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. Aldershot, Edward Elgar, pp 1133–1153.Google Scholar
Kogut, B. 1988. “Joint Ventures: Theoretical and Empirical Perspectives,” Strategic. Manage. J., 9, pp 319–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. 1992. “Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology,” Organ. Sci., 3, pp 383–397.Google Scholar
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. 1996. “What Firms Do? Coordination, Identity, and Learning,” Organ. Sci., 7, pp 502–518.Google Scholar
Koh, J. and Venkatraman, N. 1991. “Joint Venture Formations and Stock Market Reactions: An Assessment in the Information Technology Sector,” Academy Manag. J., 34, pp 869–892.Google Scholar