Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-gvvz8 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-28T21:04:18.828Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - SDG1, eliminating poverty: improvements to health coverage design as a means to create co-benefits between health system and poverty Sustainable Development Goals

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 January 2024

Scott L. Greer
Affiliation:
University of Michigan
Michelle Falkenbach
Affiliation:
European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies
Josep Figueras
Affiliation:
European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies
Matthias Wismar
Affiliation:
European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies

Summary

The goal of SDG 1 is to end poverty in all forms everywhere. Health systems are a significant determinant of the risk of impoverishment and financial hardship. We review methods for calculating catastrophic health spending and impoverishing spending, noting a distinction between those who are impoverished by out-of-pocket (OOP) health spending and those who are further impoverished by OOP health spending. Catastrophic health spending tends to be concentrated among poor households, but there is a high level of variability between countries. In particular, countries with higher public spending on health as a share of GDP have lower OOP spending, which in turn is associated with lower catastrophic health spending and impoverishment. Policymakers can also make progress on reducing the risk of impoverishment by making reforms to coverage policies. We conceptualise progress towards universal health coverage through an analysis of the coverage of people, services, and costs. Risk of financial hardship is minimised when the entire population is covered, the right services are covered to meet the population’s health needs, and costs are financed largely through pre-payment with risk pooling to avoid high user charges. The most successful systems use user charges sparingly, design user charges as fixed copayments rather than percentage-based coinsurance, and include income-based exemptions and OOP maximums.

Type
Chapter
Information
Health for All Policies
The Co-Benefits of Intersectoral Action
, pp. 64 - 87
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2024
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

5.1 Introduction

Poverty is often defined as an inability to meet basic needs for human survival and certain normal activities (Reference RavallionRavallion, 2010). Poverty reduction is a top priority of governments around the world, with ‘Ending poverty in all its forms everywhere’ as Goal 1 of the UN Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs).

To address poverty, one must be able to measure it. This is typically done by assessing how many people are living below a poverty line representing some basic standard of living. While the international poverty line is often defined as living on $1.90 per person per day, there is no universal poverty line in use and a range of poverty lines are used in practice depending on the national setting (United Nations, 2022). A distinction is made between absolute poverty lines, defined by a fixed monetary amount, and relative poverty lines that can vary depending on the average income level of the economy in which one resides. The absolute poverty definition is most commonly used in low- and middle-income countries, while relative poverty is mostly used in high-income settings. Regardless of the poverty line used, the aim of measuring poverty is the same: identifying those who experience severe financial hardship.

To make progress on SDG Goal 1, policymakers must address a wide range of causes of poverty, including economic, social and political factors. Health and health systems also play an important role. For example, people in poor health may be unable to work, and, as we have seen in recent years, communicable diseases such as COVID-19 can lead to economic disruption.

Health systems can also influence the risk of poverty through exposure to out-of-pocket payments, which are payments for health care goods and services made at the point of use. According to global estimates from the World Bank, almost 90 million people each year fall into poverty due to out-of-pocket spending on health care (World Bank, 2021). Many others experience high levels of out-of-pocket health spending relative to their available financial resources – so-called catastrophic payments – that, while not necessarily causing impoverishment (i.e. when payments push households below or further below the poverty line wherein the most basic standard of living is no longer ensured), result in financial hardship (Reference Saksena, Hsu and EvansSaksena et al., 2014). Whether health systems contribute to or alleviate poverty is dependent on coverage policies as well as a range of other factors, such as methods of provision and reimbursement. In this chapter we will focus on the impact of out-of-pocket health spending not only on those experiencing poverty, but also on those who are not necessarily impoverished but still experience financial hardship due to out-of-pocket spending.

This chapter explores the links between health systems and SDG1. While SDG3 is already dedicated to ensuring good health and monitoring progress towards universal health coverage, it is important to explicitly consider the spillover effects of the health system on poverty and financial hardship, particularly given the importance placed on poverty in the SDGs. This chapter will highlight the connection between Target 3.8, which addresses the need to achieve universal health coverage, and SDG1. In particular, the chapter will discuss SDG Indicator 3.8.2, which addresses the proportion of the population with high spending on health as a share of household financial resources. It argues that through coverage policy decisions, health systems play an important role in reducing poverty and financial hardship.

The next section of this chapter will briefly introduce SDG1 and its relevance to this chapter. The second section introduces common measures used to monitor financial hardship in health systems. Section three explores in greater detail how health systems – in particular, coverage policies – can affect the risk of poverty and financial hardship due to out-of-pocket payments. The fourth section presents two case studies:

  • Latvia, where during the financial crisis in 2009 the government exempted people living in poverty or near poverty from copayments; and

  • Germany, which in 2004 implemented copayments for outpatient care and lifted an income-based exemption.

These case studies demonstrate further the relative importance of copayment design and exemptions in reducing poverty.

5.2 Background

The title of SDG1 is very clear in its goal – No poverty – with an official objective to end poverty in all its forms everywhere. SDG1 is broken down further into a series of targets. Targets 1.1, 1.2, 1.3 and 1.B are the most relevant for this chapter. These targets describe an international commitment to:

  • 1.1 by 2030, eradicate extreme poverty for all people everywhere, currently measured as people living on less than $1.25 a day;

  • 1.2 by 2030, reduce at least by half the proportion of men, women and children of all ages living in poverty in all its dimensions according to national definitions;

  • 1.3 implement nationally appropriate social protection systems and measures for all, including floors, and by 2030 achieve substantial coverage of the poor and the vulnerable; and

  • 1.B create sound policy frameworks at the national, regional and international levels, based on pro-poor and gender-sensitive development strategies, to support accelerated investment in poverty eradication actions.

In this chapter we will discuss how out-of-pocket health spending can cause individuals and households to experience financial hardship, to be at risk of impoverishment, to push them below poverty lines (including those in Targets 1.1 and 1.2), or further burden those who are already impoverished. Coverage policies are relevant to Target 1.3 as part of the social protection system for the poor and vulnerable, particularly mindful of how financial hardship intersects with illness. We shall see that health policy should be a leading consideration in new policy frameworks that attempt to eradicate poverty and improve incomes for poor people in accordance with Target 1.B. Fig. 5.1 demonstrates how achieving progress in SDG Indicator 3.8.2 through improved coverage design has positive spillover effects on SDG1.

Fig. 5.1 Improvements to coverage design led to benefits for both SDG1 and SDG3

5.3 How can we measure the effects of out-of-pocket payments on financial hardship and poverty?

One of the main ways health systems influence the risk of financial hardship is through households’ exposure to out-of-pocket payments. Out-of-pocket payments refer to user charges for covered health care goods and services, payments for non-covered goods and services, and informal payments. It excludes any pre-payment for health costs through public or private insurance.

A common way to measure the effect of out-of-pocket payments on the risk of financial hardship is by using two indicators: catastrophic and impoverishing expenditure incidence. These are commonly referred to under the umbrella term “financial protection indicators”. Financial protection is monitored in the SDGs through Indicator 3.8.2. Indicator 3.8.2 is a type of catastrophic expenditure indicator: the proportion of the population spending large (10%) or very large (25%) shares of their total household expenditures or income on health.Footnote 1 This is one of the main indicators used globally to monitor progress towards universal health coverage. The UN’s recommended data sources for monitoring financial protection are household budget surveys, usually conducted by national statistical offices. Household budget surveys record household spending on all goods and services, including on health, over a reporting period (United Nations, 2019).

While Indicator 3.8.2 is used for global SDG monitoring, there are numerous methods used to measure catastrophic spending incidence, all of which relate households’ health expenditure to some measure of its resources and label households as catastrophic spenders once they have crossed some predefined threshold. One of the difficulties with the approach used by the indicator is that it is blind to whether poorer or wealthier people tend to exceed a certain percentage of their income in health spending, which can have significant consequences for the level of concern policymakers attribute to health spending (Reference Wagstaff and van Doorslaer EWagstaff & van Doorslaer, 2003). In this chapter, we define the incidence of catastrophic spending based on the WHO Europe method, which is the share of households with out-of-pocket spending greater than 40% of household capacity to pay for care (Reference Cylus, Thomson and EvetovitsCylus, Thomson & Evetovits, 2018). The 40% share of household capacity to pay has been used in many studies of catastrophic spending, although with different definitions of capacity to pay (Reference Wagstaff and van Doorslaer EWagstaff & van Doorslaer, 2003; Reference XuXu et al., 2007). Capacity to pay in the WHO Europe method is calculated by taking a household’s total consumption expenditure and subtracting a normative amount that captures the costs of meeting basic needs for food, housing and utilities. This reflects a judgement that households must meet basic needs before having money available to pay for health care.

An important benefit of this approach is that the effective threshold for a household to become a catastrophic spender is lower for poor households, who must spend a higher proportion of their budget on basic needs (and thus have a very limited capacity to pay for health), and higher for wealthier households. This creates a more progressive metric for measuring which groups of people suffer the most from high out-of-pocket spending. Fig. 5.2 shows that using the WHO Europe method of calculation, the poorest quintile of households experience the majority of the catastrophic health spending in most European countries.

Fig. 5.2 Catastrophic spending using the WHO Europe method, latest year available

Impoverishing expenditures are the other main financial protection indicator and perhaps the metric most directly relevant to SDG1. Households are defined as impoverished as a result of out-of-pocket health spending if their consumption before out-of-pocket spending was above a poverty line (or in the WHO Europe method, above the cost of meeting the aforementioned basic needs), and their spending after out-of-pocket costs was below the line. Households can also be considered further impoverished if their consumption before out-of-pocket spending was already below the poverty line or basic needs line and they still spent out-of-pocket for health care. As Fig. 5.3 shows, most of the burden of impoverishing spending in Europe falls on households that are already poor rather than those who are made poor by out-of-pocket spending. Households are also at risk of impoverishment under the WHO Europe method if their consumption after out-of-pocket spending is within 120% of the basic needs line (not shown in Fig. 5.3). The nuance in these metrics allows us to identify not just those who might fall below an internationally recognized consumption level, but also those who experience financial hardship without explicitly becoming poor according to binary indicators.

Fig. 5.3 Impoverishing spending by country, latest year available

Catastrophic and impoverishing spending indicators on their own can be easily misinterpreted. For example, a country might have a low incidence of catastrophic spending not because care is affordable, but because large segments of the population face out-of-pocket costs that are beyond their means to pay. They may then use fewer services than needed, or no services at all. In this way, unmet need data gathered through self-reporting is an important complement to financial hardship measures.

5.4 How do health systems influence the risk of poverty and financial hardship?

Now that we have established indicators of financial hardship, we can say more about the links between out-of-pocket spending, catastrophic spending and impoverishment. How much a country relies on out-of-pocket payments to finance health care overall is a strong predictor of the incidence of catastrophic spending (Fig. 5.4). Catastrophic spending tends to be much higher in countries where reliance on out-of-pocket spending to finance health care is high. Within Europe, Latvia, Lithuania and Hungary all have very elevated levels of catastrophic spending, each with more than 10% of their households experiencing catastrophic spending each year. All three countries rely on significantly higher levels of out-of-pocket spending to pay for health care than the OECD average (OECD, 2021). Fig. 5.5 also illustrates the positive correlation between a health system’s reliance on out-of-pocket payments and impoverishing spending in European countries.

Fig. 5.4 Incidence of catastrophic health spending and out-of-pocket payments as a share of current spending on health, latest year available

Fig. 5.5 Incidence of impoverishing (i.e., impoverished and further impoverished) spending and out-of-pocket payments as a share of current spending on health, latest year available

What then determines the level of out-of-pocket payments? Out-of-pocket payments for health care are partly determined by the level of public spending on health care (Fig. 5.6). The incidence of financial hardship due to out-of-pocket payments is more likely to be high when public spending on health is low in relation to gross domestic product and out-of-pocket payments account for a relatively high share of total spending on health (WHO & World Bank, 2019; Reference XuXu et al., 2007).

Fig. 5.6 Public spending on health as a share of GDP and out-of-pocket payments, WHO European Region, 2020

However, increases in public spending do not necessarily lead to reductions in out-of-pocket spending (WHO, 2019a). Mandating a certain level of public spending on health has not been demonstrated to be an effective way to reduce out-of-pocket spending if not combined with other significant reforms to coverage policy design. For example, from 2004 to 2017 the government of Moldova committed to allocating 12% of its budget to health care every year, resulting in public spending on health that was significantly higher than the average lower-middle-income country in Europe (WHO, 2020). However, outpatient prescribed medicines were still subject to a percentage copayment of up to 50%. As a result, out-of-pocket spending grew over the period, as did the percent of households with catastrophic out-of-pocket spending (WHO, 2020). Indeed, many countries with similar levels of public spending on health differ in terms of their out-of-pocket spending. Public spending on health in 2019 accounted for 8% of GDP in both France and the United Kingdom, but while the former relied on out-of-pocket spending for 9% of health costs, the latter relied on it for 17% (WHO, 2022). Other aspects of health system design must account for the differences in out-of-pocket spending levels.

Coverage policy design is a crucial determinant of whether health systems contribute to or alleviate financial hardship. All health systems face budget constraints, which lead to rationing of care through coverage policy design. Budget constraints can lead to implicit rationing, such as gatekeeping and waiting times, as well as explicit rationing, such as coverage exclusions and out-of-pocket payments. This is true even in systems that purport to have achieved universal health coverage. We can conceptualize progress towards universal health coverage systems through an analysis of the coverage of people, services and cost. The goals of universal health coverage are most likely to be achieved when the entire population is covered, the right services are covered to meet the population’s health needs, and costs are financed largely through pre-payment with risk pooling to avoid exposure to financial hardship or financial barriers when people need to access care. This is commonly described through the idea of the coverage cube, shown in Fig. 5.7.

Fig. 5.7 The coverage cube demonstrates the three dimensions of health coverage

Exploring the three dimensions of UHC helps to understand why countries might rely to a greater or lesser extent on out-of-pocket payments to pay for health care. We can use the conceptualization of the coverage cube as a series of tradeoffs to show how allocating limited resources towards each of the three dimensions affects out-of-pocket payments in different ways (Reference Ochalek, Manthalu and SmithOchalek, Manthalu & Smith, 2020).

The first dimension is the level of population coverage. Many systems exclude individuals from the health system based on employment, citizenship, age or income. In some countries, publicly funded services are restricted only to a certain segment of the population, for example, dental care for adults in the English NHS. This means that excluded patients must pay privately if they need care. Population entitlement to publicly financed health care is a prerequisite for protection from financial hardship but does not guarantee it. The share of population entitled is not an intrinsically good indicator of exposure to financial hardship. Incidence of catastrophic health spending in European countries with 100% population coverage varies significantly, from 1% to 14% of households (WHO, 2019b). Reviews of health insurance reforms in nine developing countries found that expanded population coverage was linked to decreased out-of-pocket expenses in six of the countries, but to an increase in out-of-pocket expenses in three of them, partly because of increased service utilization due to coverage (Reference Lagomarsino, Garabrant and AdyasLagomarsino et al., 2012; Reference Wagstaff and LindelowWagstaff & Lindelow, 2008). In some countries, entitlement to care is linked to employment; this can lead to those in precarious or unstable working conditions being excluded from coverage. European countries that have linked health coverage to employment, such as Greece, saw a rise in catastrophic health spending among middle-class households and a rise in unmet health need among those with lower incomes in the years following the Great Recession, when unemployment rose dramatically and many people lost health care coverage (WHO, 2019b).

The second dimension considers the breadth of the benefits package as well as volume limits for treatments that are covered by statutory health care coverage, which can result in long waiting times. If the benefits package is narrow or there are long waiting times, those who can afford it may pay out-of-pocket for care, contributing to poverty and financial hardship. There is considerable variability in the types of goods and services countries cover (WHO, 2019b). Although Health Technology Assessment agencies exist in many high-income health systems to investigate the cost-effectiveness of covering a certain medical intervention, the majority do not make binding decisions and in most cases it is not clear that their recommendations are considered in coverage decisions (Reference Fontrier, Visintin and KanavosFontrier, Visintin & Kanavos, 2021). Service restrictions can also occur when people are promised benefits that are not supported by adequate funding. This can result in implicit rationing of care through informal payments, which is a significant problem in several European countries. Countries with higher levels of informal payments for health care tend to have higher rates of catastrophic spending (WHO, 2019b). Even when not the primary cause of health-related financial hardship in a country overall, informal payments make it impossible for governments to protect poor people from high out-of-pocket costs through means-tested exemptions. The highly unpredictable nature of informal payments also abrogates the consumption-smoothing benefits to health insurance, either voluntary or public.

The third, and most important, mechanism by which out-of-pocket payments lead to financial hardship is through user charges. While all European countries have some form of user charges, the systems with the strongest financial protection either apply them sparingly or make efforts to protect against financial hardship. Three of the most relevant copayment policy mechanisms are using fixed copayments rather than percentage-based coinsurance, user charge exemptions for poor people, and out-of-pocket maximums (i.e. caps).

Fixed copayments are a pre-set amount that a user pays that are not dependent on the items’ list price. Percentage-based coinsurance refers to a system in which patients will pay for a certain percentage of the list price of an item. The countries that use percentage-based coinsurance tend to have higher rates of catastrophic health spending than countries with low fixed copayments (WHO, 2019b). Poland and Slovakia, for example, have similar out-of-pocket spending as a share of current health expenditure and similar poverty rates (Reference Thomson, Cylus and EvetovitsThomson, Cylus & Evetovits, 2019), but the rate of catastrophic health spending in the former is more than twice as high than that in the latter (WHO, 2019b). One difference is that Poland uses percentage-based coinsurance while Slovakia uses fixed copayments for user charges associated with outpatient medicines. Percentage-based coinsurance shifts financial risks from the health system to the patient, which in effect creates a regressive cost policy for the poorest users of health services. Percentage-based coinsurance also exposes patients to high levels of price uncertainty, especially when prices are not known to the patient in advance.

Another set of copayment policy options that have proven particularly effective in limiting financial hardship are user charge exemptions for poor people. This is especially the case for those who are impoverished and unable to meet their basic needs even before spending out-of-pocket on health. In Germany, the switch from user charge exemptions for poor people to an annual cap on copayments led to an increase in catastrophic spending, particularly among the poorest consumption quintile (WHO, 2019b). In Latvia, the end of exemptions from copayments for poor people led to a similarly sharp rise in catastrophic spending in the poorest quintile (WHO, 2018a). We will cover these examples in more detail in our case studies.

The justification for user charges for universal health care systems includes additional revenue raising for the health system and reduction of potentially inappropriate demand (i.e. moral hazard) (King’s Reference FundFund, 2005). However, a number of counterarguments to these justifications have developed. In order for insurance to lead to inappropriate demand, provider incentives must be aligned with overtreatment and consumers must have a significant influence over their treatment choice. This may be true in systems with widespread use of fee-for-service reimbursement but is unlikely to occur in systems that use capitation, fixed salaries or pay-for-performance. Supply constraints, such as direct rationing, waiting times, gatekeeping and payer prior authorization, are often used to deal with potential moral hazard even in systems that have user charges. There is also consistent evidence that user charges reduce medically necessary and unnecessary care equally, which can have negative effects on population health (Reference Thomson, Foubiser and MossialosThomson, Foubiser & Mossialos, 2010; WHO, 2019b). Out-of-pocket user charges for certain prescription drugs and preventative treatments in the UK, for example, were found to be not efficient as they increased long-term health costs to the NHS (King’s Reference FundFund, 2005). Fixed charges not related to ability to pay disproportionately lower access to care for the poor, raising issues of equity. Furthermore, institutions such as the NHS have not traditionally asserted clear boundaries between the basic package of care and supplemental health services (King’s Reference FundFund, 2005).

It is also worth reviewing the evidence on whether encouraging individuals to take matters into their own hands by purchasing complementary health insurance would be a good way to reduce catastrophic spending. While there are a few countries where complementary health insurance covers out-of-pocket payments (such as Slovenia, France and Croatia), this is the exception rather than the norm. More often complementary health insurance is used in a limited capacity by those who can afford to pay for it to obtain preferential access to care, rather than to provide financial protection. In the European context, research suggests that expanded use of complementary insurance is not an effective solution to lack of population coverage, restrictions in the benefits package, or widespread user charges, with no strong correlation between complementary insurance levels and out-of-pocket costs (WHO, 2019b). Moreover, complementary insurance adds a layer of complexity to coverage reform and individual health management to address issues that could also be solved through changes to the main coverage. Only reform to the design of coverage policies has been shown to reduce out-of-pocket costs, and thus limit financial burdens on households.

5.5 Country case studies

To better understand how health systems and coverage policy influence the risk of poverty and financial hardship, we present two case studies: Latvia and Germany. These cases will demonstrate the co-benefits between improving health systems and decreasing financial hardship that we have discussed in a real-world environment.

5.5.1 Case 1: Latvia

To cope with the hardship caused by the recession of 2008, Latvian government ministries working in collaboration with external stakeholders improved financial protection for the poorest segments of the population through temporary user charge exemptions. In 2012, however, Latvia discontinued this exemption from copayments for all but the very poorest individuals; the end of exemptions led to an increase in financial hardship for poor people.

All Latvian citizens, as well as many immigrant groups, are guaranteed access to health care under the Latvian National Health Service (NHS). The opportunity for out-of-pocket spending derives primarily from a relatively narrow benefits package and user charges rather than explicit population exclusion from coverage.

In 2009, Latvia raised copayments across almost all services as part of fiscal restraints required by external lenders during the Great Recession. After the financial crisis that arose as a result of the 2008 recession, the Latvian government agreed to cuts to public sector expenditure, tax increases, and public administration reforms, collectively known as the Economic Stabilization and Growth Revival Programme (Reference Taube, Mitenbergs, Sagan, Maresso, Mladovsky and ThomsonTaube, Mitenbergs & Sagan, 2015). The lenders included the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the EU and the World Bank, which also provided technical support. The Latvian Cabinet of Ministers explicitly mentioned health care spending as one of the sectors to which public sector cuts would be made, giving the Ministry of Health the space to implement a copayment rise (Reference Taube, Mitenbergs, Sagan, Maresso, Mladovsky and ThomsonTaube, Mitenbergs & Sagan, 2015). Some of these increases were considerable – the daily copayment for inpatient hospital stays more than doubled. At the same time, Latvia also introduced the Social Safety Net strategy in 2009, granting exemptions from those user charges for households with incomes below €171 per person per month and substantial reductions to those with incomes below €213. The Social Safety Net strategy was financially supported by the external lenders as a way to mitigate the worst adverse effects of the recession on poorer households. In this sense, changes to the design of the health system were used to create co-benefits for the public sector financial position and for financial hardship.

The health reforms during the financial crisis, including the low-income copayment exemptions, took place with few consultations with domestic health system stakeholders (Reference Taube, Mitenbergs, Sagan, Maresso, Mladovsky and ThomsonTaube, Mitenbergs & Sagan, 2015). The driving force was a collaboration between government ministries and external lenders. Table 5.1 shows the governance tools used and actions taken during the 2009 health reforms and Social Safety Net strategy. Overall, the reforms were supported by the most important governmental stakeholders, the Ministry of Finance and the Cabinet, giving the Ministry of Health the leeway to implement the copayment rise and low-income exemption with little conflict. As summarized in Table 5.2, the issue also had high political importance given its relevance to the reforms required by the external lenders. Due to the overall burden of the recession and copayment rise on the poor in Latvia, policies to alleviate financial hardship also had intrinsically high political importance.

Table 5.1 Possible governance actions to achieve SDG1 in Latvia

ToolsPossible governance actions with these tools
Goals and targetsEvidence supportPolicy guidanceImplementation and managementCoordinationAdvocacyMonitoring and evaluationFinancial supportLegal mandate
PlanPlanxxxxx
Indicators and TargetsIndicatorsxxx
Targets
BudgetingPooled budget
Shared objectivesxxxxxx
Coordinated budgetingxxxx
OrganizationMinisterial linkagesxxx
Specific ministersx
Organizationxxxx
Legislative committees
Interdepartmental committees/units
Departmental mergers
Civic engagement
AccountabilityTransparent dataxxxxx
Regular reportingxxxxx
Independent agency/evaluatorsxxx
Support for civil society
Legal rights

Table 5.2 Political importance and conflict: eliminating poverty in Latvia

Conflict
LowHigh
Political importanceHighx
Low

The 2009 exemption that the Latvian government put into place with support from external lenders was effective at mitigating the contribution of health spending to financial hardship. The share of households in the poorest quintile reporting no out-of-pocket spending improved from 58% to 70% from 2008 to 2010 (WHO, 2018a). Over the same period, the rate of catastrophic spending for the poorest quintile declined even while overall catastrophic spending in Latvia increased, likely due to the combined effects of the copayment rise and income-based exemptions (WHO, 2018a).

However, the low-income exemption policy was pared back in 2012 after the World Bank ended financial and technical support, leaving the policy’s continuation by the Latvian government financially untenable. Only those with incomes below €128 per person per month were still eligible for any reduction, exposing many low-income people to user charges. The effects on financial hardship for the poor were significant. Among the lowest income quintile, the share of households reporting no out-of-pocket payments declined from 70% in 2010 to 57% in 2013 (WHO, 2018a). The rate of catastrophic spending for the poorest households increased significantly, and by 2016, 15% of Latvian households experienced catastrophic health spending – among the highest rates in the EU (OECD, 2021; WHO, 2018a). Inpatient hospital admissions also declined significantly from 2012 to 2013, reversing a longstanding trend and implying that much of the reduction was from unmet need due to unaffordable health costs (WHO, 2018a).

The Social Safety Net strategy was successful at reducing health costs as a source of financial hardship from 2009 to 2012. Without collaboration between the external lenders and the relevant Latvian ministries, it would have been significantly more difficult for the Latvian government to put financial resources towards the Social Safety Net strategy during a period of fiscal restraint, particularly when the rest of the population was subject to a copayment rise. Indeed, once intersectoral support for the policy in the form of World Bank assistance was withdrawn, the Latvian government was unable to continue the most important provisions of the policy on its own despite the clear benefits for financial protection.

5.5.2 Case 2: Germany

Overall financial protection in Germany is strong, in line with many other European countries with low reliance on out-of-pocket spending and high public spending on health. Population coverage is near universal, as health insurance has been mandatory for the entire population since 2009. However, Germany’s experiences over the past two decades show that coverage policy decisions have notable effects on the risk of financial hardship.

Germany introduced copayments for outpatient visits in 2004 as part of the Hartz reforms, which were aimed at reducing public spending. At the same time, Germany shifted from fixed copayments to percentage-based coinsurance for outpatient medicines and abolished exemptions from user charges for low-income people. These changes shifted some financial responsibility for care to households, coinciding with an increase in the share of out-of-pocket spending on outpatient care from 6.4% in 2003 to 13.8% in 2008. This increase was even more pronounced among the poorest quintile, leading to implications for financial protection. The share of the poorest quintile of households with catastrophic out-of-pocket payments in Germany more than doubled from 2003 to 2008 (WHO, 2018b). The share at risk of impoverishment, impoverished or further impoverished after out-of-pocket payments rose from around 2% to almost 6% (WHO, 2018b).

In 2012, an intersectoral consensus of providers, patients and parliamentarians led to the abolition of copayments for outpatient visits, although the percentage-based coinsurance for outpatient medicines remained and the low-income exemptions were not reinstated. From 2008 to 2013, the share of out-of-pocket spending on outpatient care fell from 13.8% to 6.5%. By 2013, the share of the poorest quintile experiencing catastrophic spending had fallen from 2008 levels but remained above the pre-2004 level (WHO, 2018b). The share of households at risk of impoverishment, impoverished or further impoverished after out-of-pocket payments fell to around 4%, which, while an improvement from 2008, was still twice as high as pre-2004. The fact that the incidence of households impoverished due to health costs remained higher than pre-2004 suggests income-based exemptions from out-of-pocket payments had been effective at providing financial protection.

The decision to abolish copayments for outpatient visits was made through a unanimous vote of the German Federal Parliament following intersectoral collaboration between parliamentarians of multiple parties, the health minister, and civil society groups representing providers and patients (Table 5.3). The copayment was seen by parliamentarians as providing insufficient revenue for the administrative costs it necessitated (Reference Olm, Donnachie and TauscherOlm et al., 2020). It was largely opposed by providers, who felt burdened by the effort of administering the copayment, as well as patients (Reference KilhamKilham, 2015). The issue was given high levels of coverage by the German media, amplifying its political importance (Reference Olm, Donnachie and TauscherOlm et al., 2020). Given the convergence of interests in abolishing the copayment – federal government, providers and patients – and the widespread nature of the administrative burden, we can categorize the decision as being of high political importance (Table 5.4). The political conflict, in contrast, can be categorized as low as there was widespread consensus for the measure throughout the German Federal Parliament. The key to the success of this change was intersectoral collaboration between parliamentarians, patients and providers. The co-benefits of collaboration are illustrated by the reduction in financial hardship on the population at large as well as the increased access to outpatient care and lower administrative costs on providers.

Table 5.3 Possible governance actions to achieve SDG1 in Germany

ToolsPossible governance actions with these tools
Goals and targetsEvidence supportPolicy guidanceImplementation and managementCoordinationAdvocacyMonitoring and evaluationFinancial supportLegal mandate
PlanPlanxxxxxxx
Indicators and targetsIndicatorsxxxx
Targetsxxxx
BudgetingPooled budget
Shared objectives
Coordinated budgeting
OrganizationMinisterial linkages
Specific ministersxxxxxxxx
Organizationxxx
Legislative committees
Interdepartmental committees/units
Departmental mergers
Civic engagementxxxx
AccountabilityTransparent dataxxxx
Regular reportingxxxx
Independent agency/evaluators
Support for civil societyxxxx
Legal rights

Table 5.4 Political importance and conflict: eliminating poverty in Germany

Conflict
LowHigh
Political importanceHighx
Low

5.6 Conclusion

The goal of policymakers should be to create policies that ensure that people who are financially vulnerable are not exposed to further hardship as a result of using health services. This goal will be most effectively achieved through intersectoral collaboration between stakeholders with expertise in public finance and health, who can work together to pass policies that will improve the health system while decreasing financial hardship. While not explicitly included in SDG1, people who face potential financial hardship from out-of-pocket health spending should be prioritized through health system policies along with those who face explicit impoverishment. To reduce both poverty and financial hardship in the context of limited public resources, it is advisable, despite the marginal political support, to enact policies that benefit the most disadvantaged households. To ensure these policies are effective, policymakers must have the ability to identify health services that lead to financial hardship and the people most affected by them. While increasing public investment in health overall is a first step, many countries will need to reconsider coverage policies to improve financial hardship outcomes.

Specifically, countries should ensure full population coverage, a comprehensive benefits package, and limited user charges, both for the sake of improving health outcomes as well as to help eradicate poverty. For user charge policy in particular, the countries that have had the most success have implemented policies including fixed copayments rather than percentage-based coinsurance, user charge exemptions for poor households, and out-of-pocket maximums. Of the three, especially in the context of poverty eradication, means-tested exemptions from user charges are likely most effective, though there can be administrative, logistical and measurement challenges in means-testing, in part due to a lack of information about household financial resources in real-time.

The threat from ineffective coverage policy that fails to adequately protect people from financial hardship and impoverishment is clear. Policies that shift financial responsibility for care onto patients through higher out-of-pocket costs, such as those in the Germany and Latvia case studies, have led to an increase in catastrophic health expenditures. Expanded population coverage alone does not protect individuals from financial hardship, as a full 9% of people in the United States with employer-sponsored health insurance (ESHI) have declared bankruptcy due to medical costs (KFF, 2019). Poorly designed coverage policy has led to the sickest patients simultaneously suffering from disease and the threat of ruinous costs. If countries wish to make progress on reducing poverty and financial hardship, they should focus coverage design efforts on reducing the financial burden placed on those who are most vulnerable.

Footnotes

1 There are also other methods for measuring financial protection that are not specifically mentioned in the SDGs. These include health spending as a proportion of income excluding actual food expenditure, health spending as a proportion of income excluding a standard amount representing subsistence food spending, and health spending as a proportion of income excluding subsistence-level spending on food, housing and utilities (Reference Cylus, Thomson and EvetovitsCylus, Thomson & Evetovits, 2018).

References

Cylus, J, Thomson, S, Evetovits, T (2018). Catastrophic health spending in Europe: equity and policy implications of different calculation methods. Bull World Health Organ, 96:599609. (http://dx.doi.org/10.2471/BLT.18.209031)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fontrier, A, Visintin, E, Kanavos, P (2021). Similarities and Differences in Health Technology Assessment Systems and Implications for Coverage Decisions: Evidence from 32 Countries. Pharmacoecon Open, 6(3):315328. (https://doi.org/10.1007/s41669-021-00311-5)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
KFF (2019). Kaiser Family Foundation/LA Times Survey of Adults with Employer-Sponsored Health Insurance. The Henry J. Kaiser Family Foundation. (https://files.kff.org/attachment/Report-KFF-LA-Times-Survey-of-Adults-with-Employer-Sponsored-Health-Insurance)Google Scholar
Kilham, R (2015). Is national health spending on an unaffordable trajectory? Clin Exp Optom, 98(2):105106. (https://doi-org.proxy.lib.umich.edu/10.1111/cxo.12245)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lagomarsino, G, Garabrant, A, Adyas, A et al. (2012). Moving towards universal health coverage: health insurance reforms in nine developing countries in Africa and Asia. Lancet, 380(9845):933943. (https://www-sciencedirect-com.proxy.lib.umich.edu/science/article/pii/S0140673612611477)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ochalek, J, Manthalu, G, Smith, P (2020). Squaring the cube: Towards an operational model of optimal universal health coverage. J Health Econ, 70:102282. (https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0167629619301560)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Olm, M, Donnachie, E, Tauscher, M et al. (2020). Impact of the abolition of copayments on the GP-centred coordination of care in Bavaria, Germany: analysis of routinely collected claims data. BMJ Open, 10(9):e035575. (https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC7470646/)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ravallion, M (2010). Poverty Lines across the World. The World Bank, Development Research Group. Policy Research Working Paper 5284. (https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/298951468174919253/pdf/WPS5284.pdf)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saksena, P, Hsu, J, Evans, D (2014). Financial Risk Protection and Universal Health Coverage: Evidence and Measurement Challenges. PLOS Med, 11(9). (https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC4171370/)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Taube, M, Mitenbergs, U, Sagan, A (2015). The impact of the crisis on the health system and health in Latvia. In: Maresso, A, Mladovsky, P, Thomson, S et al. (eds) Economic crisis, health systems and health in Europe. Copenhagen: European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. (https://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/books/NBK447888/)Google Scholar
Thomson, S, Cylus, J, Evetovits, T (2019). Can people afford to pay for health care? New evidence on financial protection in Europe. Eurohealth 25(3):4146.Google Scholar
Thomson, S, Foubiser, T, Mossialos, E (2010). Can user charges make health care more efficient? BMJ, 341:487489. (https://www.bmj.com/content/bmj/341/7771/Analysis.full.pdf)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
United Nations (2019). SDG indicator metadata: Indicator 3.8.2. UN Statistics Division. (https://unstats.un.org/sdgs/metadata/files/Metadata-03-08-02.pdf)Google Scholar
United Nations (2022). Goal 1: End poverty in all its forms everywhere. UN Statistics Division. (https://unstats.un.org/sdgs/report/2016/goal-01/)Google Scholar
Wagstaff, A, van Doorslaer E, (2003). Catastrophe and impoverishment in paying for health care: with applications to Vietnam 1993–1998. J Health Econ, 12(11):921933. (https://onlinelibrary-wiley-com.proxy.lib.umich.edu/doi/pdf/10.1002/hec.776)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wagstaff, A, Lindelow, M (2008). Can insurance increase financial risk? The curious case of health insurance in China. J Health Econ, 27(4):9901005. (https://doi-org.proxy.lib.umich.edu/10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.02.002)CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
WHO (2018a). Can people afford to pay for health care? New evidence on financial protection in Latvia. (https://www.euro.who.int/__data/assets/pdf_file/0008/373580/Can-people-afford-to-payLatvia-WHO-FP-006.pdf)Google Scholar
WHO (2018b). Can people afford to pay for health care? New evidence on financial protection in Germany. (https://www.euro.who.int/__data/assets/pdf_file/0004/373585/Can-people-afford-to-payGermany-WHO-FP-008-4.pdf)Google Scholar
WHO (2019a). Global spending on health: a world in transition. License: CC BY-NC-SA 3.0 IGO. (https://www.who.int/publications/i/item/WHO-HIS-HGF-HFWorkingPaper-19.4)Google Scholar
WHO (2019b). Can people afford to pay for health care? New evidence on financial protection in Europe. (https://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/handle/10665/311654/9789289054058-eng.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y)Google Scholar
WHO (2020). Can people afford to pay for health care? New evidence on financial protection in the Republic of Moldova. (https://apps.who.int/iris/bitstream/handle/10665/331667/9789289054959-eng.pdf)Google Scholar
WHO (2022). Global Health Expenditure Database [online database]. (https://apps.who.int/nha/database/ViewData/Indicators/en)Google Scholar
WHO, World Bank (2019). Global Monitoring Report on Financial Protection in Health 2019. (https://www.who.int/healthinfo/universal_health_coverage/report/fp_gmr_2019.pdf)Google Scholar
World Bank (2021). Universal Health Coverage. Understanding Poverty. (https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/universalhealthcoverage–1)Google Scholar
Xu, Ke, et al. “Protecting households from catastrophic health spending.” Health affairs 26.4 (2007): 972983.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Figure 0

Fig. 5.1 Improvements to coverage design led to benefits for both SDG1 and SDG3

Figure 1

Fig. 5.2 Catastrophic spending using the WHO Europe method, latest year available

Figure 2

Fig. 5.3 Impoverishing spending by country, latest year available

Figure 3

Fig. 5.4 Incidence of catastrophic health spending and out-of-pocket payments as a share of current spending on health, latest year available

Figure 4

Fig. 5.5 Incidence of impoverishing (i.e., impoverished and further impoverished) spending and out-of-pocket payments as a share of current spending on health, latest year available

Figure 5

Fig. 5.6 Public spending on health as a share of GDP and out-of-pocket payments, WHO European Region, 2020

Figure 6

Fig. 5.7 The coverage cube demonstrates the three dimensions of health coverage

Figure 7

Table 5.1 Possible governance actions to achieve SDG1 in Latvia

Figure 8

Table 5.2 Political importance and conflict: eliminating poverty in Latvia

Figure 9

Table 5.3 Possible governance actions to achieve SDG1 in Germany

Figure 10

Table 5.4 Political importance and conflict: eliminating poverty in Germany

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×