Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-42gr6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T04:23:23.027Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Tracking the growth of government securities investing in early modern England and Wales

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 March 2020

Carole Shammas*
Affiliation:
University of Southern California, Los Angeles
*
C. Shammas, Department of History, University of Southern California, Los AngelesCA90089, USA; shammas@usc.edu; https://dornsife.usc.edu/tools/mytools/PersonnelInfoSystem/DOC/Faculty/ALI/vita_1003699.pdf.

Abstract

Interest in the growth of tradeable securities in early modern Britain, especially its relationship to economic development and the funding of government debt, has centered mainly on the borrower – whether it be trading company, industrial enterprise, or the state. This article directs attention to the investor, using Charity Commission Reports for England and Wales that document a dramatic mid-eighteenth-century shift by donors and trustees from investments in real estate and rent charges to perpetual government annuities, mainly 3 percent Consols. The heavy investment in this public debt product is what ultimately prompted the creation of the London Stock Exchange in 1801.

In analyzing this shift, which occurred among the propertied in all regions of the nation, not just the metropolis or among corporate entities and the mercantile community, I consider both what made the annuities increasingly attractive for charitable trusts and the alternatives – real estate and private loans secured by mortgage or other means – more problematic. Legal changes, I argue, played a role in the transformation, especially the Charitable Uses Act of 1736, which made charitable devises of real estate very difficult and probably resulted in reduced investment in human capital and less wealth redistribution. Regions varied, however, in the degree to which they switched from real estate in the latter part of the eighteenth century; they also differed in the extent to which the switch resulted in more gifts of interest-bearing loans as well.

Admittedly, the changes documented in this article concern only one type of depository for assets, charitable trusts. The appeal of these annuities, however, could extend to investments needed for other purposes such as postmortem payments to dependents. Moreover, the fall-off in demand for real estate in trusts correlates with GDP estimates showing a steady decline in income from real assets after 1755 and what some have noted in this period as a puzzle – the lack of an increased rate of return on rents and private loans at a time of robust investment in government debt. Most importantly, though, the transition demonstrates the ability of the government to induce a broad spectrum of the propertied population to invest in securities, if the vehicle they offered had the right characteristics, which were not necessarily highest yield or liquidity without loss in value.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © European Association for Banking and Financial History e.V. 2020

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

I would like to thank the referee who provided several very useful references.

References

Allen, R. C. (2019). Class structure and inequality during the Industrial Revolution: lessons from England's social tables 1688–1867. Economic History Review, 2nd ser. 72, pp. 88125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, B. L. (1969). Provincial aspects of the financial revolution of the eighteenth century. Business History, 11, pp. 1122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bogart, D. (2005). Did turnpike trusts increase transportation investment in eighteenth-century England? Journal of Economic History, 65, pp. 439–65.Google Scholar
Bowen, H. V. (1989). Investment and empire in the later eighteenth century: East India stockholding, 1756–1791. Economic History Review, 2nd ser. 42, pp. 186206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, J. (1989). The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Briggs, C. and Zuiderjuijn, J. (eds.) (2017). Land and Credit: Mortgages in the Medieval and Early Modern European Countryside. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Buchinsky, M. and Polak, B. (1993). The emergence of a national capital market in England, 1710–1880. Journal of Economic History, 53, pp. 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlos, A. M., Key, J. and Dupree, J. (1998). Learning and the creation of stock-market institutions: evidence from the Royal African and Hudson's Bay Companies, 1670–1700. Journal of Economic History, 58, pp. 318–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlos, A. M. and Neal, L. (2006). The micro-foundations of the early London capital market: Bank of England shareholders during and after the South Sea Bubble, 1720–25. Economic History Review, 59, pp. 498538.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlos, A. M. and Quinn, S. (2018). Early capital markets. In Diebolt, C. and Haupert, M. (eds.), Handbook of Cliometrics. Berlin: Springer-Verlag.Google Scholar
Carter, A. C. (1975). Getting, Spending, and Investing in Early Modern Times. Assen, Netherlands: Van Gorcum.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (1996). The political foundations of modern economic growth: England 1540–1800. Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 26, pp. 563–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, G. (1998). The Charity Commission as a source in English economic history. http://faculty.econ.ucdavis.edu/faculty/gclark/papers/reh.pdfGoogle Scholar
Clark, G. (2001). Debt, deficits, and crowding out: England, 1727–1840. European Review of Economic History, 5, pp. 403–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, G. (2002). Land rental values and the agrarian economy: England and Wales, 1500–1914. European Review of Economic History, 6, pp. 281308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickson, P. G. M. (1967). The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit 1688–1750. New York: St Martin's Press.Google Scholar
Earle, P. (1989). The Making of the English Middle Class: Business, Society and Family Life in London, 1660–1730. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Froide, A. M. (2017). Silent Partners: Women as Public Investors during Britain's Financial Revolution, 1690–1750. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Gayton, J. D. (2013). Tenants, tenures and transfers: the landholding experience of rural customary tenants in some Hampshire downland manors, 1645–1705. PhD dissertation, University of Exeter.Google Scholar
Gelderblom, O. and Jonker, J. (2011). Public finance and economic growth: the case of Holland in the seventeenth century. Journal of Economic History, 71, pp. 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorton, G. (2017). The history and economics of safe assets. Annual Review of Economics, 9, pp. 547–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graham, A. (2019). Credit, confidence, and the circulation of exchequer bills in the early financial revolution. Financial History Review, 26, pp. 6380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
GREAT BRITAIN (1819–40). Parliamentary Papers. Charity Commissioners Reports, vols. 1–32. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
GREAT BRITAIN (1842). Parliamentary Papers. Public Charities: Analytical Digest of the Reports. London: HMSO.Google Scholar
HANSARD'S (1846). Parliamentary Debates, 3rd series, 84(2), pp. 578–619.Google Scholar
Heim, C. E. and Mirowski, P. (1987). Interest rates and crowding-out during Britain's Industrial Revolution. Journal of Economic History, 47, pp. 117–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, P., Postel-Vinay, G. and Rosenthal, J.-L. (2000). Priceless Markets: The Political Economy of Credit in Paris, 1660–1870. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hoffman, P., Postel-Vinay, G. and Rosenthal, J.-L. (2018). Dark Matter Credit: The Development of Peer to Peer Lending and Banking in France. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Jones, G. (1969). History of the Law of Charity 1532–1827. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, M. G. (1938). The Charity School Movement. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Li, L.-F. (2019). The stop of the Exchequer and the secondary market for English sovereign debt, 1677–1705. Journal of Economic History, 79, pp. 176200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melton, F. T. (1986). Sir Robert Clayton and the Origins of English Deposit Banking, 1658–1685. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Michie, R. C. (1999). The London Stock Exchange: A History. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Muldrew, C. (1998). The Economy of Obligation: The Culture of Credit and Social Relations in early Modern England. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, A. L. (2009). The Origins of the English Financial Markets: Investment and Speculation before the South Sea Bubble. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Murphy, A. L. (2019). Performing public credit at the eighteenth-century Bank of England. Journal of British Studies, 58, pp. 5878.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neal, L. (1990). The Rise of Financial Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, pp. 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odlyzko, A. (2017). Economically irrational pricing of nineteenth-century British government bonds. Financial History Review, 23, pp. 277302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perlo, V. (1958). ‘People's capitalism’ and stock-ownership. American Economic Review, 48, pp. 333–47.Google Scholar
Petram, L. O. (2011). The world's first stock exchange: how the Amsterdam market for Dutch East India Company shares became a modern securities market, 1602–1700. PhD dissertation, University of Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Pincus, S. (2009). 1688: The First Modern Revolution. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pressnell, L. S. (1956). Country Banking in the Industrial Revolution. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Shammas, C. (1990). The Pre-Industrial Consumer in England and America. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Smail, D. L. (2016). Legal Plunder: Households and Debt Collection in Late Medieval Europe. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stasavage, D. (2016). What we can learn from the early history of sovereign debt. Explorations in Economic History, 59, pp. 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stebbings, C. (1991). Charity land: a mortmain confusion. Journal of Legal History, 12, pp. 719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
’t Hart, M., Brandon, P. and Torres-Sanchez, R. (2018). Introduction: maximizing revenues, minimizing political costs – challenges in the history of public finance of the early modern period. Financial History Review, 25, pp. 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Temin, P. and Voth, H.-J. (2013). Prometheus Shackled: Goldsmith Banks and England's Financial Revolution after 1700. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tompson, R. (1979). The Charity Commission and the Age of Reform. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Turner, G. D. (2015). English banking in the eighteenth century: bankers, merchants and the creation of the English financial system. Master's thesis, Durham University.Google Scholar
Waddilove, D. P. (2017). Why the equity of redemption? In Briggs and Zuiderduijn (eds.), pp. 117–48.Google Scholar
Walsh, P. (2014). The South Sea Bubble and Ireland: Money, Banking and Investment, 1690–1721. Woodbridge, Suffolk: Boydell Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. G. (1984). Why was British growth so slow during the Industrial Revolution? Journal of Economic History, 44, pp. 687712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, J. F. (1999). British government borrowing in wartime, 1750–1815. Economic History Review, 52, pp. 355–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar