Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-mp689 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T21:39:14.781Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Putting the public back in behavioral public policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 August 2018

PATRICIA DE JONGE
Affiliation:
Dutch Authority for the Financial Markets (AFM), Amsterdam, The Netherlands and Department of Marketing, VU Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
MARCEL ZEELENBERG*
Affiliation:
Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Economics Research, Tilburg, The Netherlands and Department of Marketing, VU Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
PEETER W.J. VERLEGH
Affiliation:
Department of Marketing, VU Amsterdam, Amsterdam, The Netherlands
*
*Correspondence to: Tilburg Institute for Behavioral Economics Research, Tilburg University, 5000 LE Tilburg, The Netherlands. Email: Marcel@uvt.nl
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Behavioral public policies are aimed at influencing the behavior of the public in a way that is advantageous for the public itself and within the law. Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth (2018, this issue) summarize the state of the art of this new field of study and introduce a number of challenges and opportunities for the time to come. We address an additional challenge that is present and central in all attempts to influence behavior, namely the public – the people that are the target of behavioral public policies. We review evidence revealing that people do not passively accept those influence attempts, but often show reactant responses. We propose that the Persuasion Knowledge Model provides a framework both to understand the reactions of the public and to facilitate communication between academic researchers and practitioners.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

Public policy may be conceptualized as the actions by which a government addresses the needs of its citizens. This includes the implementation of rules and regulations to ensure that the public does not engage in undesirable behaviors. Recent developments, primarily based on findings from the field of behavioral economics, take into account the fact that behavioral interventions might sometimes be more efficient than such traditional policy tools in achieving policy-makers’ goals (Benartzi et al., Reference Benartzi, Beshears, Milkman, Sunstein, Thaler, Shankar and Galing2017), hence the popularity of behavioral public policy. The goal of behavioral public policy is influencing the behavior of the public in a way that is within the law and advantageous for the public itself. Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth (Reference Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth2018) nicely summarize the state of the art of this new field of study and introduce a number of challenges and opportunities for the time to come. We would like to address another challenge that is present in all attempts to influence behavior; namely, the public that is the target of these interventions. Taking into account the public – the people that are going to be influenced by these policies – is crucial, as is evident from the fact that some interventions have proven to be less effective than expected beforehand. We will illustrate this later on using the recent proposed change of default in the organ donor laws in The Netherlands (Krijnen et al., Reference Krijnen, Tannenbaum and Fox2018).

Our point is actually quite simple and straightforward. When one attempts to influence people's behavior, one should take into account that the people one is targeting have an opinion about this. In the fields of social psychology and marketing, theories have been developed to understand the reactions of people that are subjected to such influence attempts. We would like to briefly review these theories here, as we believe that people's reactions to influence attempts is an overlooked issue in behavioral public policy. In particular, attempts to influence behavior can trigger so-called ‘reactance’ in the person targeted. Reactance is the counter-response that can occur when people feel their freedom to behave, choose or think in a particular way is being threatened (Brehm, Reference Brehm1966). But as of now, very little is known about when and how behavioral public policy interventions trigger reactance. As the popularity of these interventions increases and their use spreads through governments, regulators and other agencies worldwide, improving our understanding of public responses is both important and timely.

Here, we make the case for putting the public back in behavioral public policy. We first look at reactance and what is known about reactance in relation to behavioral public policy interventions. We then propose that a well-known theory from marketing research – the Persuasion Knowledge Model – has great potential for improving our understanding of public responses to behavioral policy interventions. We conclude by articulating several research questions that, in our opinion, should be high on the field's list of research priorities.

Reactance theory

Reactance is the well-known social psychological theory about how people react to threats of loss of freedom (Brehm, Reference Brehm1966; Brehm & Brehm, Reference Brehm and Brehm1981). When people expect freedom and they perceive that this freedom is being restricted, reactance can occur. In this context, threats to freedom should be interpreted broadly. They include flat-out restrictions and prohibitions, but also the pressure to behave, choose or think in a particular way. Think, for example, of a government trying to implement new consumer protection regulations (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980), an insurance provider limiting the number of product options available to a particular consumer or a parent pressuring his or her child to eat more vegetables. In the literature, reactance is treated both as a motivational state (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980), to be measured by looking at the outcome of a choice process or a combination of anger and negative cognitions (Rains, Reference Rains2013), and as a trait (Jung & Mellers, Reference Jung and Mellers2016) that can be measured directly.

As parents who have attempted to increase the vegetable intake of their offspring will be able to confirm, pressure to behave in a particular way does not necessarily increase enthusiasm about the desired behavior in the person being pressured. In fact, threats to freedom can lead a person to do the opposite of what was intended – the so-called boomerang effect (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980). The behavior shown by a person experiencing reactance is not primarily intended to be in line with this person's own preferences, but it is intended to regain a sense of control (Jachimowicz et al., Reference Jachimowicz, Duncan and Weber2017). This can even lead to people choosing options that are objectively worse than available alternatives (Jung & Mellers, Reference Jung and Mellers2016).

Reactance and behavioral public policy

Several studies have looked at support for behavioral public policy interventions, particularly various types of nudges, in the USA and a number of European countries (Jung & Mellers, Reference Jung and Mellers2016; Reisch & Sunstein, Reference Reisch and Sunstein2016). These studies find that support for many nudges is fairly high, often higher than support for more traditional policy tools like taxes and prohibitions. Reisch and Sunstein (Reference Reisch and Sunstein2016) found substantial differences between countries in terms of average levels of support. The same authors found no clear link between support for nudges and demographic variables and political orientation (with the exception of the USA). Jung and Mellers (Reference Jung and Mellers2016) found that attitudes toward nudging are partly driven by individual dispositions. They found that empathetic people generally support nudges, while individualists and conservatives generally oppose them. Reactant people also expressed less support for nudges because they perceived them as autonomy threatening.

Crucially, due to their research design, Jung and Mellers (Reference Jung and Mellers2016) were unable to disentangle attitudes toward nudging from attitudes toward underlying policy goals. Using a research design developed to do just this, Tannenbaum et al. (Reference Tannenbaum, Fox and Rogers2017, p. 1) found a large partisan nudge bias in a series of experiments: they described this as “an instance of attribution substitution, where individuals evaluate the acceptability of a policy nudge by instead assessing how they feel about the associated policy objective or policy sponsor.”

Reisch and Sunstein (Reference Reisch and Sunstein2016) also concluded that people seem to have stronger opinions about the underlying policy goals than about the policy instruments. One puzzling example of this is their finding of significant support for subliminal advertising to discourage smoking and overeating – a nudge judged to be extremely inappropriate by the authors themselves – in many European countries.

While Tannenbaum et al.’s (Reference Tannenbaum, Fox and Rogers2017) partisan nudge bias disappears when partisan cues are removed from the nudge description, the authors emphasized that removing all political context in real-world cases is simply impossible. Moreover, both experiences in the field and in the lab have shown that attempts to nudge can in fact lead to reactance. Let us provide some examples.

In late 2016, one of the chambers of the Dutch parliament passed a bill to change the system for organ donation in The Netherlands from opt in (you are not a donor until you register yourself as one) to opt out (presumed consent unless you explicitly indicate you do not want to be a donor). Even though the bill still needs to be approved by the other chamber before it becomes law, Krijnen et al. (Reference Krijnen, Tannenbaum and Fox2018, emphasis added) described how the bill and corresponding media attention led to reactance, even among people that had previously consented by explicitly opting in on a governmental website.

Remarkably, however, the month the bill passed the number of residents who explicitly registered as non-donors spiked to roughly 40 times the number found in previous months. This dramatic (albeit temporary) jump in active rejections was observed not only among newly registering residents, but also among those who had previously consented to donation and then went to the trouble of revoking their consent.

Reiter et al. (Reference Reiter, McRee, Pepper and Brewer2012) examined consent for human papillomavirus (HPV) vaccines in the lab. The HPV vaccine for adolescents is controversial for many parents, and uptake of the vaccine has remained far below the levels recommended by health experts. Contrary to their own hypothesis, the researchers found that parents were more likely to agree to vaccination in the opt-in scenario than in the opt-out or neutral scenarios. Also in the lab, Hedlin and Sunstein (Reference Hedlin and Sunstein2016) found reactance to a green energy default when this option was more costly than ‘regular’ energy. And Arad and Rubinstein (Reference Arad and Rubinstein2017) found that even when people support the underlying policy goals (e.g., saving more and eating more healthy foods), a significant proportion objected to the nudges used to achieve those policy goals. Concern about manipulation (in other words, reactance) seems to be an important driver of objection.

That government regulations, even those with the best interests of the public at heart, could cause reactance was foreseen by reactance theorists (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980). Of course, one of the reasons nudges are so popular is that they are alternatives to more traditional policy tools like conventional regulation (e.g., rules on information disclosure) and they preserve nominal (although not necessarily effective) freedom of choice (Rebonato, Reference Rebonato2014). In fact, Sunstein (Reference Sunstein2017) argued that reactance is rare and probably not a big issue in the case of nudges (in this particular case: defaults) because defaults preserve autonomy. But, as also argued by others (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980; Pavey & Sparks, Reference Pavey and Sparks2009; Jachimowicz et al., Reference Jachimowicz, Duncan and Weber2017), it is perceived autonomy that matters.

In other words, for reactance to occur, it is not necessary that freedom is actually limited. What is necessary, however, is that people experience some pressure to change (Clee & Wicklund, Reference Clee and Wicklund1980). Thus, for reactance to occur in the case of behavioral public policy interventions, people need only have the impression that someone is trying to influence their behavior. At present, the number of studies looking at the effect of transparency on nudging is still limited, particularly in field settings and for topics with relevance for public policy-makers. Moreover, the results so far have been inconclusive, probably as a result of various types of transparency being tested. Loewenstein et al. (Reference Loewenstein, Bryce, Hagmann and Rajpal2014), for example, found that transparency about the presence of defaults did not impact decision-making. Steffel et al. (Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016) found that disclosing the intent of a nudge had no effect on the effectiveness of a default. Studies on the effect of disclosing the unconscious character of nudges on support show conflicting results (e.g., Felsen et al., Reference Felsen, Castelo and Reiner2013; Petrescu et al., Reference Petrescu, Hollands, Couturier, Ng and Marteau2016). And, as described previously, when Tannenbaum et al. (Reference Tannenbaum, Fox and Rogers2017) disclosed the policy-maker doing the nudging, this had a large effect on nudge acceptance.

Putting the public back in behavioral public policy

Together, these observations demonstrate that it is important to keep in mind that behavioral public policy not only contains the word ‘behavioral’, but also the word ‘public’. Put differently, when designing interventions, we should not forget the psychology of the people being influenced (for related arguments, see Jachimowicz et al., Reference Jachimowicz, Duncan and Weber2017; Krijnen et al., Reference Krijnen, Tannenbaum and Fox2018).

Our observations in the previous sections also demonstrate that our understanding of the psychological reactions to behavioral public policy interventions is still limited, fragmented and lacking a coherent theoretical framework. This makes it very hard for policy-makers to distill practically relevant lessons. Additionally, it contributes to the gap between policy-makers and academia as identified by Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth (Reference Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth2018).

It may not be remarkable that in marketing and communication science, the importance of the psychology of the people being influenced has received ample attention. This has resulted in theoretical approaches that could help improve our understanding of when and why behavioral public policy interventions trigger reactance. In particular, the Persuasion Knowledge Model (PKM; Friestad & Wright, Reference Friestad and Wright1994) offers a lot of potential, both for increasing our understanding of public reactions to influence attempts and for unifying insights that stem from various hitherto unrelated research programs.

The potential of the Persuasion Knowledge Model

The PKM states that how a person responds to a persuasion attempt is not only influenced by that person's knowledge about the topic at hand and the persuasion agent, but also by what Friestad and Wright (Reference Friestad and Wright1994) refer to as that person's persuasion knowledge. Persuasion knowledge includes a person's beliefs about strategies and tactics used by a persuasion agent, the effectiveness and appropriateness of these tactics and the available response strategies. Topic, agent and persuasion knowledge interact to influence how someone copes with a persuasion attempt – although this interaction is in fact rarely studied (Campbell & Kirmani, Reference Campbell, Kirmani, Haugtvedt, Herr and Kardes2008).

The PKM is by no means a novel theory. Peter Wright coined the idea as far back as 1986 in his presidential address at the Association for Consumer Research conference (Reference Wright and Lutz1986, p. 1):

Isn't it very plausible that people have intuitive theories about the tactics that are used in the game of marketplace selling-and-buying? They surely must have personal insights that are pertinent for realizing, “Aha! Somebody's scheming to sell me something! Somebody's trying to mind-screw me!”, and for interpreting and evaluating and dealing with whatever influence tactics are being used. I'll call such an intuitive theory about marketers’ influence tactics a “schemer schema.”

In the same speech, Wright advocated shifting the research focus from persuasion agent to persuasion target; that is, the consumer. It does not require a great deal of imagination to see the relevance of Wright's intuitions, and their subsequent theoretical elaboration in the PKM, to the study of behavioral public policy and public reactions to interventions. Yet to the best of our knowledge, only one paper on nudges, by Steffel et al. (Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016), explicitly refers to persuasion theory.

Steffel et al. (Reference Steffel, Williams and Pogacar2016) use persuasion theory mainly to make the case for more transparency about the use of defaults. We think the usefulness of the PKM in the context of behavioral public policy is actually much greater. For example, applying the PKM to the work by Tannenbaum and colleagues (Reference Tannenbaum, Fox and Rogers2017) clarifies that, when asked for their attitude toward an instrument of persuasion, people primarily apply their topic knowledge (or rather, beliefs) and agent knowledge (beliefs) in forming a judgment, rather than their knowledge of the persuasion strategies and tactics involved. To the extent that people do apply their persuasion knowledge – for example, when perceived effectiveness is an important driver of attitude to nudges (cf. Petrescu et al., Reference Petrescu, Hollands, Couturier, Ng and Marteau2016) – persuasion knowledge about behavioral public policy interventions seems limited and is often wrong. For example, many people seem to think that educational campaigns are more effective than changing defaults (Diepeveen et al., Reference Diepeveen, Ling, Suhrcke, Roland and Marteau2013; Jung & Mellers, Reference Jung and Mellers2016).

These findings raise a number of interesting empirical questions for the study of reactions to behavioral public policy interventions that, as of now, remain unanswered. For example, is it possible to trigger accurate persuasion knowledge about behavioral public policy interventions? And if so, what is the most effective way of doing so? How does activated persuasion knowledge impact attitudes toward nudges and other interventions, and how does it impact their effectiveness?

Conclusion

We have argued that, as the application of behavioral public policy is gaining popularity, it is both important and timely to improve our understanding of public responses to behavioral interventions. We know that policy interventions, including behavioral ones like nudges, can trigger reactance, but we know very little about how, why and when this happens. To further our understanding of reactance and to unify existing insights into a coherent theoretical model, we propose the use of the PKM. Using the PKM allows us to move beyond studying nudges in isolation and to include the policy context. Using the PKM will also allow researchers to connect currently unconnected strands of scholarship from marketing, communication psychology and behavioral economics – thereby contributing to a field that has the potential to be truly interdisciplinary. A more coherent theoretical framework will also make it easier for policy-makers to distill practical lessons. In this way, we hope to contribute to closing the gap identified by Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth (Reference Sanders, Snijders and Hallsworth2018) between academic research on the one hand and practitioners’ need for more and more systematic knowledge about effective and acceptable behavioral public policy interventions on the other.

Disclosure

The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Dutch Authority for the Financial Markets (AFM).

References

Arad, A. and Rubinstein, A. (2017), The people's perspective on libertarian-paternalistic policies. Retrieved from http://www.tau.ac.il/~aradayal/LP.pdf.Google Scholar
Benartzi, S., Beshears, J., Milkman, K. L., Sunstein, C. R., Thaler, R. H., Shankar, M. and Galing, S. (2017), ‘Should governments invest more in nudging?Psychological Science, 28(8): 10411055. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797617702501.Google Scholar
Brehm, J. W. (1966), A theory of psychological reactance. Oxford, England: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Brehm, J. and Brehm, S. (1981), Psychological reactance. A theory of freedom and control. New York: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Campbell, M. C. and Kirmani, A. (2008), ‘I know what you're doing and why you're doing it: The use of persuasion knowledge model in consumer research’, In Haugtvedt, C. P., Herr, P. M. and Kardes, F. R. (Eds.), Handbook of consumer psychology (pp. 549574). New York: Taylor & Francis GroupGoogle Scholar
Clee, M. A. and Wicklund, R. A. (1980), ‘Consumer Behavior and Psychological Reactance’, Journal of Consumer Research, 6(4): 389405.Google Scholar
Diepeveen, S., Ling, T., Suhrcke, M., Roland, M. and Marteau, T. M. (2013), ‘Public acceptability of government intervention to change health-related behaviours: a systematic review and narrative synthesis’, BMC Public Health, 13(1): 756. https://doi.org/10.1186/1471-2458-13-756.Google Scholar
Felsen, G., Castelo, N. and Reiner, P. B. (2013), ‘Decisional enhancement and autonomy: public attitudes towards overt and covert nudges’, Judgment and Decision Making, 8(3): 202213. https://doi.org/10.1177/2332858416674007.Google Scholar
Friestad, M. and Wright, P. (1994), ‘The Persuasion Knowledge Model: How people cope with persuasion attempts’, Journal of Consumer Research, 21(1): 131. https://doi.org/10.1086/209380.Google Scholar
Hedlin, S. and Sunstein, C. R. (2016), ‘Does active choosing promote green energy use? Experimental Evidence’, Ecology Law Quarterly, 43(1): 107141. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2624359.Google Scholar
Jachimowicz, J. M., Duncan, S. and Weber, E. U. (2017), When and why defaults influence decisions: A meta-analysis of default effects. Retrieved from https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2727301.Google Scholar
Jung, J. Y. and Mellers, B. A. (2016), ‘American attitudes toward nudges’, Judgment and Decision Making, 11(1): 6274. Retrieved from http://ideas.repec.org/a/jdm/journl/v11y2016i1p62-74.html.Google Scholar
Krijnen, J., Tannenbaum, D. and Fox, C. R. (2018), ‘Choice Architecture 2.0: Behavioral policy as a social interaction’, Behavioral Science & Policy. In press.Google Scholar
Loewenstein, G., Bryce, C., Hagmann, D. and Rajpal, S. (2014), ‘Warning: You are about to be nudged’. SSRN Electronic Journal. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2417383.Google Scholar
Pavey, L. and Sparks, P. (2009), ‘Reactance, autonomy and paths to persuasion: Examining perceptions of threats to freedom and informational value’, Motivation and Emotion, 33(3): 277290. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11031-009-9137-1.Google Scholar
Petrescu, D. C., Hollands, G. J., Couturier, D. L., Ng, Y. L. and Marteau, T. M. (2016), ‘Public acceptability in the UK and USA of nudging to reduce obesity: The example of reducing sugar-sweetened beverages consumption’, PLoS ONE, 11(6): 118. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0155995.Google Scholar
Rains, S. A. (2013), ‘The nature of psychological reactance revisited: A meta-analytic review’, Human Communication Research, 39(1): 4773. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2958.2012.01443.x.Google Scholar
Rebonato, R. (2014), ‘A critical assessment of libertarian paternalism’, Journal of Consumer Policy, 37(3): 357396. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-014-9265-1.Google Scholar
Reisch, L. A. and Sunstein, C. (2016), ‘Do Europeans like nudges’? Judgment and Decision Making, 11(4): 310325. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107415324.004.Google Scholar
Reiter, P. L., McRee, A. L., Pepper, J. K. and Brewer, N. T. (2012), ‘Default policies and parents’ consent for school-located HPV vaccination’, Journal of Behavioral Medicine, 35(6): 651657. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10865-012-9397-1.Google Scholar
Sanders, M., Snijders, V. and Hallsworth, M. (2018), ‘Behavioural science and policy: where are we now and where are we going?Behavioural Public Policy, 2(2): 144167.Google Scholar
Steffel, M., Williams, E. F. and Pogacar, R. (2016), ‘Ethically deployed defaults: Transparency and consumer protection through disclosure and preference articulation’, Journal of Marketing Research, 53(5): 865880. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmr.14.0421.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. R. (2017), ‘Nudges that fail’, Behavioural Public Policy, 1(1): 425. https://doi.org/10.1017/bpp.2016.3.Google Scholar
Tannenbaum, D., Fox, C. R. and Rogers, T. (2017), ‘On the misplaced politics of behavioural policy interventions’, Nature Human Behaviour, 1(7): 130. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-017-0130.Google Scholar
Wright, P. (1986), ‘Presidential Address Schemer schema: consumers’ intuitive theories about marketers’ influence tactics’. In Lutz, R. J. (Ed.), Advances in Consumer Research, 13 (pp. 13). Provo, UT: ACR. Retrieved from http://www.acrwebsite.org/volumes/5947/volumes/v13/NA-13.Google Scholar