Hostname: page-component-788cddb947-nxk7g Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-10-15T04:34:23.464Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

We Must Always Pursue Economic Growth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 October 2022

Brian Kogelmann*
Affiliation:
West Virginia University, John Chambers College of Business and Economics, Morgantown, West Virginia, USA

Abstract

Why pursue economic growth? For poor countries this is an easy question to answer, but it is more difficult for rich ones. Some of the world's greatest philosophers and economists – such as John Stuart Mill, John Maynard Keynes, and John Rawls – thought that, once a certain material standard of well-being has been achieved, economic growth should stop. I argue the opposite in this article. We always have reason to pursue economic growth. My argument is indirect. I shall not argue that economic growth itself is always better. Rather, I shall argue that stopping growth requires morally objectionable actions. Economic growth tends to occur naturally if certain underlying conditions are in place. We have moral reasons to insist on these conditions independent their effect on growth, however. Halting growth requires that we alter these conditions, but we ought not do this.

Type
Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James A.. 2012. Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty (New York: Crown Business).Google Scholar
American Association of University Professors. 1915. 1915 Declaration of Principles on Academic Freedom and Academic Tenure. Available at: https://www.aaup.org/NR/rdonlyres/A6520A9D-0A9A-47B3-B550-C006B5B224E7/0/1915Declaration.pdf.Google Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth. 2009. Democracy: Instrumental vs. Non-Instrumental Value. In Contemporary Debates in Political Philosophy, edited by Christiano, Thomas and Christman, John (Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell), 213–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S., and Rayo, Luis. 2010. Why Keynes Underestimated Consumption and Overestimated Leisure for the Long Run. In Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, edited by Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 179–84.Google Scholar
Brennan, Jason. 2021. Why it's OK to Want to be Rich (New York: Routledge).Google Scholar
Christiano, Thomas. 1996. The Rule of the Many: Fundamental Issues in Democratic Theory (Boulder: Westview Press).Google Scholar
Christiano, Thomas. 2008. The Constitution of Equality: Democratic Authority and its Limits (Oxford: Oxford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cowen, Tyler. 2018. Stubborn Attachments: A Vision for a Society of Free Prosperous, and Responsible Individuals (San Francisco: Stripe Press).Google Scholar
Davis, Lance E., and Huttenback, Robert A.. 1988. Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Economics of British Imperialism (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Deaton, Angus. 2013. The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Di Tella, Rafael, and MacCulloch, Robert. 2010. Happiness Adaptation to Income Beyond “Basic Needs.” In International Differences in Well-Being, edited by Diener, Ed, Kahneman, Daniel, and Helliwell, John (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 217–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diener, Ed, and Seligman, Martin E.P.. 2004. Beyond Money: Toward an Economy of Well-Being. Psychology Science in the Public Interest 5: 131.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Easterlin, Richard A. 1974. Does Economic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some Empirical Evidence. In Nations and Households in Economic Growth: Essays in Honor of Moses Abramovitz, edited by David, Paul A. and Reder, Melvin W. (New York: Academic Press), 89125.Google Scholar
Easterlin, Richard A. 1995. Will Raising the Income of All Increase the Happiness of All? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 27: 3547.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Estlund, David. 2008. Democratic Authority: A Philosophical Framework (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Ferguson, James R. 1978. Scientific Inquiry and the First Amendment. Cornell Law Review 64: 639–65.Google Scholar
Freeman, Richard B. 2010. Why Do We Work More Than Keynes Expected? In Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, edited by Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 135–42.Google Scholar
Frey, Bruno S., and Stutzer, Alois. 2002. What Can Economists Learn from Happiness Research? Journal of Economic Literature 40: 402–35.Google Scholar
Friedman, Benjamin M. 2005. The Moral Consequences of Economic Growth (New York: Vintage Books).Google Scholar
Gheaus, Anca, and Herzog, Lisa. 2016. The Goods of Work (Other Than Money!). Journal of Social Philosophy 47: 7089.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haan, Jakob de, and Sturm, Jan-Egbert. 2003. Does More Democracy Lead to Greater Economic Freedom? New Evidence for Developing Countries. European Journal of Political Economy 19: 547–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, Dana Remus. 2005. Freedom of Thought: The First Amendment and the Scientific Method. Wisconsin Law Review 6: 14791534.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard. 2010. Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren. In Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, edited by Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo (Cambridge: MIT Press), 1726.Google Scholar
Kolodny, Niko. 2014. Rule Over None II: Social Equality and the Justification of Democracy. Philosophy and Public Affairs 42: 287336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koyama, Mark, and Rubin, Jared. 2022. How the World Became Rich: The Historical Origins of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Polity Press).Google Scholar
Landemore, Hélène. 2013. Democratic Reason: Politics, Collective Intelligence, and the Rule of the Many (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Lundström, Susana. 2005. The Effect of Democracy on Different Categories of Economic Freedom. European Journal of Political Economy 21: 967–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre. 2016. Bourgeois Equality: How Ideas, Not Capital or Institutions, Enriched the World (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 2008. Principles of Political Economy and Chapters on Socialism (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 2015. On Liberty, Utilitarianism and Other Essays (Oxford: Oxford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2002. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Mokyr, Joel. 2018. A Culture of Growth: The Origins of the Modern Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Moller, Dan. 2011. Wealth, Disability, and Happiness. Philosophy and Public Affairs 39: 177206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moore, Barrington Jr. 1993. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World (Boston: Beacon Press).Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C., Wallis, John Joseph, and Weingast, Barry R.. 2013. Violence and Social Order: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
North, Douglass C., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England. Journal of Economic History 49: 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, Nathan. 2008. Slavery, Inequality, and Economic Development in the Americas: An Examination of the Engerman-Sokoloff Hypothesis. In Institutions and Economic Performance, edited by Helpman, Elhanan (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press), 148–80.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 2019. Crises of Democracy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, and Limongi, Fernando. 1997. Modernization: Theories and Facts. World Politics 49: 155183.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ratner, Ronnie Steinberg. 1980. The Paradox of Protection: Maximum Hours Legislation in the United States. International Labor Review 119: 185–98.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice (Cambridge: Harvard University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sacks, Daniel W., Stevenson, Betsey, and Wolfers, Justin. 2012. The New Stylized Facts About Income and Subjective Well-Being. Emotion 12: 1181–87.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Scanlon, Thomas. 1972. A Theory of Freedom of Expression. Philosophy and Public Affairs 1: 204–26.Google Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert. 2005. John Maynard Keynes, 1883–1946: Economist, Philosopher, Statesman (New York: Penguin Books).Google Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert, and Skidelsky, Edward. 2012. How Much is Enough? Money and the Good Life (New York: Other Press).Google Scholar
Stevenson, Betsey, and Wolfers, Justin. 2013. Subjective Well-Being and Income: Is There Any Evidence of Satiation? American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings 103: 598604.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2010. Toward a General Theory of Consumerism: Reflections on Keynes's Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren. In Revisiting Keynes: Economic Possibilities for our Grandchildren, edited by Pecchi, Lorenzo and Piga, Gustavo (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press), 4186.Google Scholar
Viehoff, Daniel. 2014. Democratic Equality and Political Authority. Philosophy and Public Affairs 42: 337–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Valentini, Laura. 2012. Ideal vs. Non-Ideal Theory: A Conceptual Map. Philosophy Compass 7: 654–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy. 1999. The Dignity of Legislation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy. 2012. Dignity, Rank, and Rights (Oxford: Oxford University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Gavin. 2022. Slavery and the Rise of the Nineteenth-Century American Economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives 36: 123–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar