Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-x4r87 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T14:23:05.405Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Timing Their Positions: Cosponsorship in the State Legislature

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 May 2023

Emily U. Schilling*
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN, USA
Abigail A. Matthews
Affiliation:
Department of Political Science, University at Buffalo, SUNY, Buffalo, NY, USA
Rebecca J. Kreitzer
Affiliation:
Department of Public Policy, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, NC, USA
*
Corresponding author: Emily U. Schilling; Email: eschill2@utk.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Legislators must decide when, if ever, to cosponsor legislation. Scholars have shown legislators strategically time their positions on salient issues of national importance, but we know little about the timing of position-taking for routine bills or what this activity looks like in state legislatures. We argue that legislators’ cosponsorship decision-making depends on the type of legislation and the partisan dynamics among the current cosponsors. Members treat everyday legislation as generalized position-taking motivated by reelection, yet for key legislation, legislators are policy-oriented. With a new dataset of over 73,000 bills introduced in both chambers of the Texas state legislature in the 75th to 86th regular sessions (1997–2020), we use pooled Cox proportional hazard models to evaluate the dynamics of when legislators legislate, comparing all bills introduced with a subset of key bills. The results show that legislators time their cosponsorship activity in response to electoral vulnerability, partisanship, and the dynamics of the chamber in which they serve.

Type
Original Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press and State Politics & Policy Quarterly

Introduction

On Monday, February 25, 2019, Senator Joan Huffman, a Republican lawyer from Houston, Texas, representing the 17th district, introduced SB21, a bill raising the minimum age to purchase tobacco products from 18 to 21 years old. The very next day, four Republicans and four Democrats joined her as cosponsors on the bill. On Wednesday of that week, Eddie Lucio, Jr., a Democrat representing the Rio Grande Valley, became the ninth cosponsor of the bill. On Tuesday of the following week, José Rodríguez (D-29) announced his cosponsorship of the bill, and Borris Miles (D-13) joined him the next day. Six days later, Beverly Powell (D-10) reported that she, too, would cosponsor. Twenty-two days after Powell’s announcement, and 37 days after Huffman introduced the bill, two more Democrats cosponsored SB21, and the following week, José Menéndez (D-26) joined the list of supporters as the final cosponsor. After a successful vote in both chambers, Republican Governor Greg Abbott signed the bill on June 7, 2019 (see Figure 3 for a graph of the timing of this bill). What explains the decision of four fellow Republican legislators to sign onto the bill so quickly and seven Democratic members to move individually, and sometimes more slowly, to declare their support?

Of their many legislative activities, roll-call voting is the most common form of position-taking, in part because legislators must take a position when a bill is up for a vote.Footnote 1 While roll-call voting forces legislators to go on the record, cosponsoring legislation is powerful because it is both voluntary and electorally meaningful. It is also a collaborative process through which legislators shape and promote policy (Bratton and Rouse Reference Bratton and Rouse2011; Holman and Mahoney Reference Holman and Mahoney2018).

Most previous research on cosponsorship focuses on why legislators cosponsor. But for legislators, when to cosponsor legislation is also a critical decision. In this article, we ask why legislators take positions when they do. When legislators cosponsor is important for several reasons, “some of which have to do with policy implications, others of which have to do with political implications” and all of which motivate legislators (Shipan and Shannon Reference Shipan and Shannon2003, 656, emphasis in original). What we know about the timing of position-taking comes from Congress, and those studies are exceedingly narrow. Most often, this research examines an individual high-profile piece of legislation in one chamber of Congress at a single moment in time (Boehmke Reference Boehmke2006; Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997; Caldeira and Zorn Reference Caldeira and Zorn2004; Glazer et al. Reference Glazer, Griffin, Grofman and Wattenberg1995; Huang and Theriault Reference Huang and Theriault2012). While important contributions, these analyses may not be generalizable beyond the unique characteristics of the individual bills.Footnote 2 The time is past due for a more generalizable analysis of when legislators legislate. State legislatures offer a new venue to test our strategic legislating hypotheses.

In this article, we ask “why do legislators cosponsor some bills quickly but wait days or months to cosponsor others?” We take a big picture view of strategic policymaking by examining the universe of bills, and compare that with key legislation introduced in both chambers of one legislature over 20 years. We argue that a crucial aspect of the cosponsorship decision is the choice of when to cosponsor. Our theory asserts that legislators are intentional about timing their legislative activities.

Using an original dataset on the timing of cosponsorship for over 73,000 bills introduced in the Texas state legislature from the 75th to 86th regular sessions (1997–2020), we evaluate the dynamics of when legislators legislate. Texas is a useful state to examine for several reasons. As the third most populous state, it has a semiprofessional legislature, common among several states, and is diverse in terms of geography, race, and socioeconomic status. Over the past decade, it has become more partisan, and is currently one of 38 states dominated by a single party. Texas also offers incredible transparency in its legislative actions, making comprehensive data about when legislators cosponsor bills available to citizens and researchers that other states do not. The insights from our study shed light on how electoral and partisan context, as well as the policy context, influence cosponsorship decision-making.

The results of our analyses demonstrate that legislators strategically time their cosponsorship activity in response to electoral, institutional, and partisan cross-pressures. The earliest cosponsors shape if, and when, later legislators cosponsor, but the type of legislation matters. For everyday bills, legislators cosponsor earlier when there is already meaningful bipartisan cosponsorship. However, for major legislation, legislators cosponsor earlier when more of their fellow partisans have already done so. These results highlight the importance of shifting analyses away from focusing solely on the legislative dynamics of major legislation.

Why legislators cosponsor

Scholars have long studied why legislators sponsor legislation. Many find that electoral incentives influence legislators’ behavior, including observable measures of productivity, such as roll-call votes, committee work, and cosponsorship (Fouirnaies and Hall Reference Fouirnaies and Hall2022). Most legislators’ primary and proximate goal is reelection because it “must be achieved over and over if other ends are to be entertained” (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974, 16). Even policymakers driven to shape public policy must first gain or retain elected office (Fenno Reference Fenno1977).

While much of the cosponsorship and electoral connection literature begins with Congress, there is some reason to believe that elections may affect legislators’ behavior differently in state legislatures. For example, Rogers (Reference Rogers2017) looks at whether voters hold state legislators accountable for their roll-call votes and finds no evidence of electoral accountability. Fouirnaies and Hall (Reference Fouirnaies and Hall2022) reach the opposite conclusion, finding that elections do influence how state legislators allocate their time. From the perspective of effectiveness, Miquel and Snyder (Reference Miquel and Snyder2006) establish that effective legislators have higher reelection rates and are less likely to be challenged. And, Garcia and Sadhwani (Reference Garcia and Sadhwani2022) find that some state legislators are responsive to undocumented immigrants, even without electoral incentives.

Legislators’ activities may not be directed only toward constituents. Interest groups also carefully monitor cosponsorship to inform decisions on allocating endorsements, donations, and volunteers (Arnold Reference Arnold1990; Bianco Reference Bianco1994; Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974). Interest groups and the political parties pay attention to the amount of committee work legislators do, which may affect fundraising efforts and voter support (Fouirnaies and Hall Reference Fouirnaies and Hall2018). During state legislative races, opponents highlight high absenteeism rates from roll-call votes, especially on close or high-profile votes; Brown and Goodliffe (Reference Brown and Goodliffe2017) conclude that legislators are more electoral than policy-minded.

An election’s competitiveness may also affect legislators’ activity. A series of articles examined the rise in incumbents’ electoral advantage in US congressional races (see, e.g., Ferejohn Reference Ferejohn1977; Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974), yet others dispute that accounts arguing these so-called “vanishing margins” have not made incumbents feel safer (Jacobson Reference Jacobson1987). Regardless of how objectively competitive an election is, candidates treat each election as if it is competitive (Lazarus and Steigerwalt Reference Lazarus and Steigerwalt2018; Mann Reference Mann1978). Comparing state legislators who seek reelection and those who do not, Fouirnaies and Hall (Reference Fouirnaies and Hall2022) conclude that the mere threat of reelection affects legislators’ actions, even in low-salience environments such as state legislative races.

Given the importance of reelection, legislators take positions on important issues in their district to build trust among their constituents (Fenno Reference Fenno1978; Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974). As Kessler and Krehbiel (Reference Kessler and Krehbiel1996, 555) explain, “a legislator seeking reelection could not hope for a more efficient way to strengthen his or her electoral connection than to cosponsor constituency-prized legislative initiatives.” Members only cosponsor between 3% and 5% of bills in Congress, suggesting that policymakers are selective and that it is not a “costless” activity (Bernhard and Sulkin Reference Bernhard and Sulkin2013; Krehbiel Reference Krehbiel1995).

Vulnerable legislators may also cosponsor more often to gain favor with their reelection constituency (Campbell Reference Campbell1982; Koger Reference Koger2003; Rocca and Sanchez Reference Rocca and Sanchez2008), although cosponsoring legislation can have drawbacks if the legislators’ constituents do not approve (Mayhew Reference Mayhew1974). Challengers or the media may amplify when a member cosponsors the “wrong” legislation (Desposato, Kearney, and Crisp Reference Desposato, Kearney and Crisp2011). Overall, legislators would “prefer to have more rather than less legislation bearing their name” (Franzitch Reference Franzitch1979, 420).

Cosponsorship is especially important for institutionally disadvantaged legislators — such as those in the minority party or representing minority communities—who have fewer opportunities to claim credit for favorable roll-call votes (Rocca and Sanchez Reference Rocca and Sanchez2008). As one member of Congress explained, “When you’re in the minority, the bills that you introduce and cosponsor define your philosophy … If you want to show your constituents who you are and what you really want to do to move the country forward, you’ve got to cosponsor bills” (Koger Reference Koger2003, 232).

Beyond signaling, cosponsoring legislation can help legislators achieve their policy aims even if the bill fails (Koger Reference Koger2003). Sponsoring and cosponsoring may increase the likelihood that their bill is incorporated into subsequent legislation (Bernhard and Sulkin Reference Bernhard and Sulkin2013; Kingdon Reference Kingdon1984; Koger Reference Koger2003). Legislators may also cosponsor bills with the primary goal of stopping another bill (Koger Reference Koger2003).

In short, the cosponsorship scholarship focuses on why legislators cosponsor legislation, that is, to achieve reelection and policy goals. What is left unanswered is when those legislators cosponsor. This leaves an important gap in the literature because cosponsorship does not happen randomly.

When legislators cosponsor

The research on when legislators take policy positions is far more limited. Most of what we know about the timing of position-taking comes from only a handful of studies, most of which evaluate timing on very notable pieces of legislation in Congress: position-taking announcements in the US House on support for the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) (Boehmke Reference Boehmke2006; Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997), the impeachment of President Clinton in the House (Caldeira and Zorn Reference Caldeira and Zorn2004), House veto overrides (Glazer et al. Reference Glazer, Griffin, Grofman and Wattenberg1995), and immigration policy in Congress (Huang and Theriault Reference Huang and Theriault2012). Extending this logic to state legislatures is not straightforward, and we must piece together expectations from multiple sources.

First, many of the key findings are based on analyses of salient, national policy issues. For instance, Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher’s (Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997) study of NAFTA and Huang and Theriault’s (Reference Huang and Theriault2012) examination of the Comprehensive Immigration Reform Act find that members of Congress announce early positions based on constituency factors. Kessler and Krehbiel (Reference Kessler and Krehbiel1996) take a different approach and study cosponsorship timing on 51 bills with at least 50 cosponsors in the 103rd session of the US House. They find that ideological extremism shapes early position-taking more than electoral vulnerability or tenure in office. There is good reason to believe that these studies, which focus on major legislation, may not be generalizable beyond the unique characteristics of the individual bills and a snapshot in time.

Second, legislators balance several factors while considering when to announce their position (Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997; Kingdon Reference Kingdon1989). As Caldeira and Zorn (Reference Caldeira and Zorn2004, 526) explain, “To the extent that position-taking represents a very public act on the part of a legislator, the decision of when to engage in such behavior assumes strategic importance.” If position-taking was not strategic, legislators would join on as cosponsors en masse. Instead, we assert that legislators carefully weigh the costs and benefits of when to cosponsor. And, each choice—to delay or to act—is part of a member’s legislative calculus. Announcing a position too early may carry political risk, but delaying may also have potential costs. Based on these electoral, institutional, and partisan cross-pressures, we expect legislators to be strategic about when they choose to cosponsor legislation.

Legislators may cosponsor early to shape the future debate, to establish issue ownership or expertise, or to signal strong support for, or opposition to, an issue. For example, taking a position early establishes a legislator as a policy entrepreneur and signals to colleagues, especially to copartisans, the position to take (Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997; Lohmann Reference Lohmann1993). Legislators must also evaluate potential reactions to each bill—miscalculating may mobilize a challenger in the next legislative race (Schiller Reference Schiller1995)—so a member may take extra time before announcing a position (Lazarus and Steigerwalt Reference Lazarus and Steigerwalt2018). They may also wait until outside political actors, such as interest groups or the executive branch, become involved in the issue, or to entice a concession from party leadership (Boehmke Reference Boehmke2006). Late position takers may also respond to colleagues’ earlier positions and cues (Krehbiel Reference Krehbiel1991; Lohmann Reference Lohmann1993).

Given the thousands of bills introduced in a legislative chamber in a session, policymakers use heuristics, or information shortcuts (Kingdon Reference Kingdon1989; Matthews and Stimson Reference Matthews and Stimson1975), to inform their decisions about what and when to cosponsor legislation. Many legislators take cues from experts (Fong Reference Fong2020), and may have to wait for or seek their advice. Legislators may delay taking a position on an issue, even until the presiding officer announces a roll-call vote, to avoid constraint and tension from various constituents, to receive more information, or to increase the probability that their vote is vital to the outcome of a bill (Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997; Glazer et al. Reference Glazer, Griffin, Grofman and Wattenberg1995; Zelizer Reference Zelizer2019).

The number and distribution of cosponsors on a bill can say a lot about the bill’s content, popularity, and the ease with which it will sail through the chamber. Thus, legislators spend considerable energy recruiting cosponsors and building coalitions, sometimes compromising on key provisions or trading votes (Bernhard and Sulkin Reference Bernhard and Sulkin2013; Koger Reference Koger2003). Having many cosponsors signals to colleagues the broad appeal of the proposed legislation (Bernhard and Sulkin Reference Bernhard and Sulkin2013).Footnote 3 As the number of cosponsors increases, policymakers may be reasonably assured that the bill has wide popularity and decide to cosponsor earlier (but see Zelizer Reference Zelizer2019, finding that cue-taking occurs late in the policymaking process). Legislators perceive bills with many cosponsors as more likely to pass and may want their name on “winning legislation” for the potential electoral gain (Franzitch Reference Franzitch1979). As legislators establish the appeal of the bill, legislators may find “safety in numbers” and feel comfortable making an earlier cosponsorship decision. Thus, we expect legislators use the number of cosponsors as an indicator that the bill has broad appeal and is not controversial. As a result, we expect:

Bandwagon Hypothesis: As the total number of cosponsors increases, legislators will cosponsor earlier relative to other bills.

Legislators look to their copartisans for guidance on their cosponsorship decision-making calculus (Kessler and Krehbiel Reference Kessler and Krehbiel1996; Kingdon Reference Kingdon1989). Members with a similar ideology and partisanship are likely to hold similar policy preferences. Legislators collaborate with the legislators with whom they are in policy agreement (Swift and VanderMolen Reference Swift and VanderMolen2016). As Trubowitz and Mellow (Reference Trubowitz and Mellow2005, 435) note, legislators “avoid taking policy positions that might antagonize party activists, campaign contributors, and core supporters.” Legislators’ partisanship and the need to gain and maintain support from partisan voters structures their policymaking activity (Aldrich Reference Aldrich1995; Cox and McCubbins Reference Cox and McCubbins1993), who see bipartisanship as a policy loss for their own party (Harbridge, Malhotra, and Harrison Reference Harbridge, Malhotra and Harrison2014) and reward roll-call vote extremism (Birkhead Reference Birkhead2015). The nature of polarization matters; as polarization between Democratic and Republican women in the chamber increases, members are more likely to introduce restrictive abortion bills (Matthews, Kreitzer, and Schilling Reference Matthews, Kreitzer and Schilling2020). Bipartisan cosponsorship might marginalize a legislator if constituents perceived them to be a party traitor (Holman and Mahoney Reference Holman and Mahoney2018). Bills with many cosponsors from one party indicate the popularity and significance of the bill within the party, also signaling it will be favorable to party donors. A cosponsorship coalition of members primarily from one party may encourage members from that party to cosponsor earlier. We expect:

Copartisan Hypothesis: As the number of cosponsors from within their political party increases, legislators will cosponsor earlier than bills with fewer copartisan cosponsors.

While some view partisan loyalty in cosponsorship as positive, others praise bipartisanship, and there is some evidence of bipartisanship in state legislatures (Kirkland Reference Kirkland2014; Makse Reference Makse, Moreno, Gamarra, Murphy and Jolly2020). Having bipartisan cosponsorship can suggest that the framing and content of the bill is amenable to both parties (Crisp, Kanthak, and Leijonhufvud Reference Crisp, Kanthak and Leijonhufvud2004; Koger Reference Koger2003). Party leaders use the number and diversity of cosponsors in their calculations of the time and effort needed to pass legislation; when legislators who typically disagree come together to support a bill, it suggests that the bill is uncontroversial and thus relatively low cost (Koger Reference Koger2003). Thus, a slate of bipartisan cosponsors may reveal broad support and increase the chances of passage (Holman and Mahoney Reference Holman and Mahoney2018; Kanthak and Krause Reference Kanthak and Krause2012; Kirkland Reference Kirkland2011). When the cosponsors of a bill come from both parties, legislators may find that there is less electoral risk in supporting the legislation, and thus be eager to sign on as a cosponsor earlier.

However, not all bipartisanship represents meaningful collaboration across parties. A bill with 60 cosponsors but with 59 from the same party may technically be bipartisan, but not in the genuine spirit of bipartisanship. Being the sole cosponsor from one party may put one at great electoral risk of being labeled a party defector (Holman and Mahoney Reference Holman and Mahoney2018). However, when bipartisanship moves beyond token status, legislators may be more likely to see little risk in joining and thus cosponsor earlier. We expect:

Bipartisan Hypothesis: When there is substantial bipartisanship (each party has at least 20% of the total cosponsors), legislators will cosponsor earlier than bills with fewer bipartisan cosponsors.

Legislators who are electorally vulnerable cosponsor more than their colleagues, as it provides a venue for taking more policy positions (Burkett and Skvoretz Reference Burkett and Skvoretz2005; Garand and Burke Reference Garand and Burke2006; Rocca and Sanchez Reference Rocca and Sanchez2008). But these electorally vulnerable legislators may not cosponsor earlier. Legislators take early political or policy positions when it is less electorally risky for them (Caldeira and Zorn Reference Caldeira and Zorn2004; Glazer et al. Reference Glazer, Griffin, Grofman and Wattenberg1995). If position-taking is an activity undertaken by legislators in pursuit of reelection, then legislators who ran uncontested in their previous general election likely feel less pressure to sponsor legislation that will gain them favor with their constituents. State legislative elections have long exhibited low rates of contested elections, particularly in states with a dominant party (Burden and Snyder Reference Burden and Snyder2021; Myers Reference Myers2020). When legislators do not face electoral challengers, they may be slower to cosponsor. In contrast, legislators who face competitive elections may cosponsor earlier in their haste to take many positions. Thus, we expect:

Election Hypothesis: Legislators who had a challenger in the general election will cosponsor earlier than legislators who did not face a challenger.

Scholars have long focused on major legislation, anomalous by definition,Footnote 4 relative to average or symbolic bills (but see notable exceptions, including Dodd and Schraufnagel Reference Dodd and Schraufnagel2009; Durr, Gilmour, and Wolbrecht Reference Durr, Gilmour and Wolbrecht1997; Howell et al. Reference Howell, Adler, Cameron and Riemann2000). With the watchful eyes of the media on debates over key pieces of legislation, it is reasonable to assume that high stakes and public attention shape cosponsorship. In contrast, the vast majority of legislation exists in a low-information environment, gets negligible or no media coverage, and is not a critical issue in electoral campaigns. In low-information environments, partisan cues prevail (Peterson Reference Peterson2017). As such, we expect that legislators will time cosponsorship differently based on whether it is a major piece of legislation.

Everyday and Key Legislation Hypothesis: Partisan cosponsors will have a stronger influence on the timing of cosponsorship decisions of “everyday” bills, while substantial bipartisanship will more strongly influence the timing of “key” legislation.

Finally, we expect there to be meaningful differences between the upper and lower chambers of the legislature. Institutional factors shape cosponsorship, such as chamber size, term limits, and electoral considerations associated with shorter terms in office (Kirkland and Williams Reference Kirkland and Williams2014; Rippere Reference Rippere2016; Sarbaugh-Thompson et al. Reference Sarbaugh-Thompson, Thompson, Elder, Comins, Elling and Strate2006). Shorter terms in office, term limits, and chamber size in the lower chamber influence opportunities to foster collaborative relationships across the aisle, making partisan cosponsorship less likely. Institutional mechanisms in the upper chamber, namely the filibuster (through which individual senators wield significant influence), may induce more bipartisanship than the lower chamber (which is more majoritarian in nature).

Cosponsorship in the Texas state legislature

We examine position-taking in the Texas state legislature for many reasons. First, Texas has a semi-professional or hybrid legislature, where legislators meet for regular sessions beginning in January of odd-numbered years and meet for 140 days. Because the legislature is part-time and legislators earn a salary of approximately $45,000 for a two-year term,Footnote 5 most legislators work elsewhere with careers as varied as an orthopedic surgeon, accountant, banker, and owner of an insurance agency (Sandoval, Montgomery, and Fernandez Reference Sandoval, Montgomery and Fernandez2021).

The Texas legislature is a relatively large legislature with 150 House and 31 Senate members.Footnote 6 It follows a similar process to ones used in many legislatures across the country. For example, like Texas, most state legislatures have the filibuster (in the Senate), they list one author as the “primary author,” and there can be an unlimited number of cosponsors. Like many other states, there are no term limits. The institutional differences between the chambers are like most state legislatures: longer terms for Senate members than House members (four-year versus two-year terms), staggered elections in the Senate, and a significantly smaller number of members in the Senate.

As the third most populous state in the nation, Texas is diverse in terms of geography, race, and the socioeconomic status of its districts. Like many state legislatures, Texas has a one-party regime in which the Republican Party dominates state politics. Texas has been a “state government trifecta” or single-party government with Republican control of both legislative chambers and the governorship since 2003. State trifectas are common. In 2021, there were 38 states with trifectas: 15 states with Democratic trifectas and 23 with Republican trifectas.Footnote 7

We also examine cosponsorship in Texas for pragmatic reasons. The state provides significant transparency regarding each step of its legislative process, including the dates that legislators sign on to the bill. It is extremely rare to find the dates of cosponsorship, much less for all legislation over time. The comprehensive and longitudinal nature of the Texas legislative data opens the door to unique analyses that simply are not possible in other legislatures.

To test our expectations about the strategic legislating hypotheses, we require data on all bills introduced and legislators’ cosponsorship activity.Footnote 8 The Texas legislature identifies one legislator as the primary author, and up to four additional joint authors. Members can cosponsor bills in the other chamber, but we do not use that information for this analysis (for cross chamber cosponsorship in the 81st session, see Kirkland and Williams Reference Kirkland and Williams2014). What most scholars would think of as “cosponsoring,” Texas calls “coauthoring.Footnote 9 To be consistent with state legislative literature, we use the language of cosponsoring.

To construct the dataset, we scraped all regular bills introduced in both chambers of the Texas state legislature from the Texas Legislature Online website.Footnote 10 The data starts at the beginning of the 75th regular session in 1997, the first year that complete cosponsorship data is available, through the 86th regular session that ended in 2020. This process produced 73,458 bills.

We retrieved several pieces of useful information for each bill. First, we collected the roster of what Texas refers to as primary bill authors, joint authors, and cosponsors and the dates on which legislators announced their position. We also collected key information, such as the bill number, a bill description, committee assignments for both chambers, and the last legislative action for each bill.

Figure 1 reports the total number of bills introduced and the total number of cosponsors in each regular session by chamber. Total cosponsorship in both chambers experienced an increase in the later years. Figure 2a presents the average number of bills each legislator cosponsors in a session. Mean cosponsorship follows a similar pattern to total cosponsorship, with both the Senate and House’s mean cosponsorship increasing. Figure 2b shows the average number of cosponsors per bill, which remains relatively low given the total number of bills introduced each session. These averages do not tell the full story. Some legislators do not cosponsor any legislation, and others cosponsor a significant number of bills. For example, Senator Judith Zaffirini, a Democrat who has served in the Texas Senate since 1987, cosponsored at least 100 bills in each legislative session, despite serving in the minority almost the entire time of her service.

Figure 1. Total cosponsorship in each regular session.

Figure 2a. Mean number of bills cosponsored.

Figure 2b. Mean number of cosponsors.

In order to test the differences between all legislation and major legislation, we collected information on Texas’s major legislation. We do this by looking at those bills considered a “key vote” by the experts at Vote Smart.Footnote 11 Vote Smart recruits experts from each state (a community of political scientists and journalists) to evaluate which proposed bills were important that year. The experts evaluate the votes based on a variety of criteria, including whether it was a salient issue, a close vote, simple to understand, or definitive in establishing a legislator’s position on a particular issue.

Vote Smart data is not available for the entire period; however, it covers a robust time span, from 2009 to 2020. There are 133 key vote bills, with 63 bills in the House and 70 bills in the Senate.Footnote 12 Notably, not every key vote bill becomes law. The legislation covers a wide range of topics, including health care, environment, immigration, voting rights, and the budget.

Methodological approach and dependent variable

Since we are interested in estimating the timing at which legislators announce their positions, we use duration analysis. Specifically, we use a pooled proportional hazards Cox model (Cox Reference Cox1972), which is a flexible duration model that leaves the distribution of the baseline hazard unspecified (Box-Steffensmeier and Jones Reference Box-Steffensmeier and Jones2004).

Our dependent variable is the number of days it takes for a legislator to cosponsor each bill per session. We operationalize it as a count of the number of days it takes for a legislator to cosponsor a bill after the first person sponsors the bill.Footnote 13 In event history analysis language, the legislator “survives” until the date she cosponsors a bill, the bill is passed, or the session ends, whichever comes first. She “fails” when she signs on as a cosponsor of that bill. We can use the anecdote at the beginning of this article as an example to illustrate our dependent variable: the 2019 Senate bill SB21 about raising the minimum age to purchase tobacco products. As shown in Figure 3, a Republican senator introduced the bill. This is day 0. For SB21, day 0 is February 25, 2019. On February 26, eight legislators cosponsored the bill. For each of these eight legislators, their clock stopped on day 1. When Borris Miles cosponsored the bill on March 6, his clock ended after 9 days. The final senator to cosponsor SB21, José Menéndez, cosponsored on April 9, the 43rd day. For the remaining senators who have not cosponsored the bill, their clock ends either when the bill passes the chamber or when the session ends, whichever occurs first. The timing for SB21 and all other bills that are in that session are independent of one another in this type of analysis.

Figure 3. 2019 Senate bill SB21 cosponsorship timing.

The Cox duration model has several advantages. First, the dependent variable calculates not only if a legislator cosponsors, but when they do. Second, the Cox model explicitly analyzes legislators’ dynamic deliberative process. For example, the models do not have a constant term because it is absorbed into the baseline hazard rate.

Finally, duration models are particularly well suited to handle censored data. In our analysis, observations are right-censored, which occurs when the session ends if a legislator never cosponsors. To account for this, duration models create a variable to specify whether a legislator never cosponsored (data is right-censored) or cosponsored legislation (data is not censored). Including the censored data is important to ensure that we account for all legislators’ actions and their timing. Excluding the right-censored data produces selection bias and loss of information (Box-Steffensmeier Reference Box-Steffensmeier1996). Including censored data does not cause parameter estimate bias because the censored observations contribute to the likelihood function, which indicates the probability of surviving, that is, not cosponsoring until time t (Yamaguchi Reference Yamaguchi1991).

The “pooled” component of the model means that we place all legislators and bills per session together in one dataset. In our first set of models, we pool across all bills and all sessions for each chamber. This means that we have an observation for every legislator, for every bill introduced in their respective chamber, from the 75th session in 1997 to the end of the 86th session in 2020. For the second set of models, we still pool across sessions (81st to 86th) but only focus on the key vote bills identified by Vote Smart.

Because we pool the data, it is important to be clear about what we are modeling. The unit of analysis is the legislator, per bill and session. That means that for each bill per session, every legislator is “at risk” of cosponsoring that specific bill. If she does not cosponsor the bill, the clock ends on the last day of the session and the case becomes right-censored. In Texas, legislators introduce a considerable number of bills that never attract cosponsors, meaning that all legislators are at risk for those bills for the entire session. For every bill introduced, there is an observation for each individual legislator, since they are all at “risk” of signing on as a cosponsor for each bill. In the 85th session in the House, for example, 152 members introduced 4,333 bills. For this session, there are 668,901 total observations.Footnote 14

Independent variables: Cosponsor characteristics

Using the Legislative Reference Library of Texas website,Footnote 15 we retrieved the name, partisanship, district, chamber, and incumbency status of every legislator from 1997 to 2020, from which we generate many of our independent variables. First, we focus on the variables of interest for this analysis—the size and partisanship of the cosponsors of the bill. We first construct a variable that keeps a running tally of the number of cosponsors a bill has at the time each legislator signs onto the bill. The second variable of interest we include is the number of co-partisans that have signed onto a particular bill. If the legislator is Republican, this variable will be the number of Republicans who had already joined the bill at the time of the signing. If the legislator is a Democrat, it will be the number of Democrats.

The final variable centered on the partisan makeup of the cosponsors considers the amount of bipartisan support there is for a bill. In our theory, we argue that as cosponsorship moves from trivial bipartisanship to substantial, other legislators will be more likely to cosponsor. We create an indicator variable where the variable equals 1 if at least 20% of the cosponsors are from both parties, and 0 if not.Footnote 16 We chose 20% because it represents a meaningful proportion of bipartisanship according to the data. We include a variable to indicate whether the legislator had a challenger in their previous general election (Klarner Reference Klarner2018; Klarner et al. Reference Klarner, Berry, Carsey, Jewell, Niemi, Powell and Snyder2013, supplemented by our own data collection). In the House, 40% of the legislators, on average, did not have a challenger in their previous election. Senators experienced low levels of competition (sometimes reaching 50% of the senators) in the early years of the data, but in more recent years, the average has dipped to about 20%.

To account for a legislator’s ideology, we use the American Legislatures project NPAT scores (Shor and McCarty Reference Shor and McCarty2011). NPAT scores are individual-level ideal point estimates that place all legislators on a common ideological space, so the scores are comparable across time and between and within state legislative chambers. The larger the positive value in these scores, the more conservative a legislator is. A large negative number reveals that a legislator is very liberal. To control for how extreme a legislator is, we take the absolute value of the NPAT ideology measure.

Independent variables: Constituent characteristics

Legislators also time their positions based on constituent factors (Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold, and Christopher Reference Box-Steffensmeier, Arnold and Christopher1997). There is a relationship between cosponsorship and constituent issue preferences (Bromley-Trujillo, Holman, and Sandoval Reference Bromley-Trujillo, Holman and Sandoval2019; Waggoner Reference Waggoner2018) A legislator whose ideology closely matches the preferences of her constituents will have little concern for taking an early stance on an issue compared with a member whose district is more ideologically heterogeneous or less ideologically proximate. To account for citizen ideology, we use Tausanovitch and Warshaw’s (Reference Tausanovitch and Warshaw2013) district-level ideology measure.Footnote 17 We use citizen and legislator ideology to categorize the similarity between the representative and their district.

To do that, we split each of the ideology measures into three sections—the most liberal third, the moderate third, and the most conservative third. We then calculate the absolute difference between the legislator’s position and their district’s position. If a legislator’s ideology was in the most conservative third of the chamber and their district was one of the more liberal districts, the difference would be 2. These scores range from 0 to 2; in both chambers and across all sessions, we find that the mean is 0.45. Although not perfect, there is no current state politics measure that places citizens and legislators in the same space. This gives us a general sense of how similar legislators are to their constituents.Footnote 18

Independent variables: Additional control variables

Using the data scraped from the Texas Legislature website, we construct several additional variables to control for bill characteristics. Since we know the primary sponsor of each bill, we include the ideology of the bill using a proxy: the primary sponsor’s NPAT score, offering a measure of the bill’s conservativism. To control for the substantive focus of the legislation, we break down the committee assignments into 13 categories, which often include multiple committees. The categories are Agriculture, Business, Defense, Education, Energy, Environment, Health, Justice, Parks and Recreation, Taxation and Revenue, State and Local Government, Welfare, and Transportation. Transportation is the omitted base category from all models. In both chambers, there are several bills that are never assigned to a committee, although the number is much larger in the Senate than in the House.

Results

We present two series of models.Footnote 19 In the first, we analyze every bill introduced in the House and the Senate from 1997 to 2020. Next, we limit our analysis to key pieces of legislation. For all results, we report hazard ratios; a coefficient greater than 1 means that a legislator cosponsors earlier and a coefficient that is less than 1 indicates that a legislator delays cosponsorship. We run all models with robust standard errors, stratified by legislative session. Finally, Cox models assume that the covariates’ effects are constant over time, known as the “proportionality assumption.” We test whether the models violate this proportionality assumption using Schoenfeld residuals. Overall, most of the covariates meet the assumption.Footnote 20

In Table 1, we present the results for the House and the Senate for all bills. The results support our strategic legislating hypotheses, although there are some chamber differences. As discussed above, differences in chamber size, length of terms, and institutional rules (like the presence of the filibuster) may shape how and when legislators collaborate. As the number of cosponsors increase in the House, legislators cosponsor earlier. For example, as the number of cosponsors grows from 1 to 3, other legislators in this House are over five times more likely to cosponsor earlier. But the results are in the opposite direction in the Senate. As the number of overall cosponsors grows in the Senate, legislators delay cosponsorship. For a similar change in the number of cosponsors (from 1 to 3), there is a comparable decrease with the decision to cosponsor—they are almost five times less likely to sign on to the bill.

Table 1. Cosponsorship timing for all legislation, 1997–2020

Note. Coefficients are hazard ratios, a coefficient greater than 1 means that a legislator cosponsors early, and anything less than 1 means that a legislator cosponsors later. Outcome is the number of days until a member cosponsors each bill.

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

The next two variables look at the party of the cosponsor. First, in both chambers, as the number of copartisans increases, legislators cosponsor much earlier. As the total number of copartisan cosponsors changes from one to three copartisans, legislators are 8 times more likely in the House and 10 times more likely in the Senate to cosponsor earlier.

Second, bipartisanship is a significant predictor of cosponsoring earlier. The very large, positive, and statistically significant hazard ratios indicate that as bipartisanship exceeds 20%, legislators cosponsor earlier. This means that the probability of cosponsoring legislation with significant bipartisan support is over 15 times that of bills without meaningful bipartisan support. Bipartisanship is by far the most effective factor in changing the likelihood that a legislator will sign onto a bill.

Finally, electoral vulnerability affects the likelihood of cosponsoring a bill. Having a challenger in the previous elections makes a legislator cosponsor earlier in the House, but has the opposite effect in the Senate. This may be because of the senators’ longer terms. In the Senate, having a challenger in the previous election decreases a legislator’s hazard ratio by over 100% versus not having a challenger. In the House, having a challenger increases the hazard ratio by almost the same amount. The relationship between electoral pressure and the use of cosponsorship is stronger in the House versus the Senate.

Our first analysis examined every bill introduced. While that analysis offers insight into general trends for the universe of legislation, legislators may time their cosponsorship differently on especially salient issues. To analyze whether there is a distinction between types of legislation, we next turn to the Vote Smart key vote legislation.

Table 2 illustrates that legislators time their cosponsorship a bit differently for major legislation. As the total number of cosponsors increases, legislators delay their cosponsorship of key vote bills. The substantive effects are similar in the House and the Senate; as the overall number of cosponsors increases from 1 to 3, legislators will be five times more likely to delay cosponsoring the bill.

Table 2. Cosponsorship timing for key vote legislation, 2009–20

Note. Coefficients are hazard ratios, a coefficient greater than 1 means that a legislator cosponsors early, and anything less than 1 means that a legislator cosponsors later. Outcome is the number of days until a member cosponsors each bill.

* p < 0.05.

** p < 0.01.

*** p < 0.001.

The copartisan effect remains the same. As the number of copartisan cosponsors increases, legislators will cosponsor earlier. This effect is stronger in the Senate than it is in the House for both key vote and everyday legislation. In the House, increasing the number of copartisan cosponsors on the bill by one increases the likelihood of announcing one’s cosponsor by over 1,000%, whereas in the Senate, a similar increase increases the hazard ratio by over 7,000%. Interestingly, the powerful effect of bipartisanship on the universe of legislation disappears for key vote bills, but only in the Senate. Meaningful bipartisan cosponsorship is statistically significant in the House model. Finally, electoral vulnerability does not influence when legislators cosponsor key votes bills.

Discussion

One of the most surprising results from the models—the universe of bills and key vote bills—is that more cosponsors on a bill does not mean legislators cosponsor earlier. As the total number of cosponsors increases, legislators delay cosponsorship. We expected a general bandwagon effect in which legislators jump on early because everyone else is cosponsoring. Instead, legislators’ timing is more nuanced than that. For major legislation, a partisan bandwagon effect emerges. As the number of cosponsors from within their own political party increases, legislators cosponsor earlier. The effect is strongest in the Senate. However, for typical or everyday legislation, legislators cosponsor earlier when existing cosponsorship is bipartisan.

Legislators’ ideology sometimes affects cosponsorship decision-making. Across all models and in both chambers, ideologically extreme legislators are more likely to cosponsor early. This is as expected because these members often represent more ideologically extreme districts and can cosponsor early without fear of being out of step with their constituents.

In addition, electoral vulnerability only influences cosponsorship decision-making for everyday bills. The typical legislation may provide legislators more opportunities to stake their claims in policy areas, whereas major legislation may make it harder for legislators to do the same. We also find that there is a difference between how electoral vulnerability changes the decision-making process across chambers. In the lower chamber, legislators are much more likely to sign on early when they have faced a recent electoral challenger, but that legislators in the upper chamber who faced a recent challenger delay cosponsorship activity.

There are mixed results when we account for the ideology of the bill author. In the House, members cosponsor earlier when the bill’s author is more conservative, especially when the bill is a major piece of legislation. But the effect is not the same in the Senate; members only cosponsor earlier in the Senate on major legislation. Perhaps because it is Texas, using the ideology of the primary author as a proxy, the key vote bills are more conservative on average than the everyday bills. In the House, the average ideology score is 0.1488, a fairly moderate score, whereas the key vote bills have an average of 0.574, better reflecting the Republican majority’s policy agenda. The differences in the Senate are much more drastic and may explain why there are no statistically significant findings in the everyday legislation. For the Senate, the average ideology score is only 0.096, a nearly perfect moderate position, whereas their key vote bills are strongly conservative at 1.072. As the bill author becomes more conservative, Senate legislators delay cosponsoring on key votes. Finally, the ideology of the district does not affect cosponsorship timing; it is not statistically significant in most models.

Partisanship affects cosponsorship decision-making in other ways. Copartisanship is a reliable predictor of cosponsoring early for key votes and for the universe of bills. Bipartisanship, however, does not reach statistical significance for key votes. Democratic legislators have mixed results based on the type of legislation. Among all bills, Democrats will cosponsor earlier. However, for key votes, it depends on the chamber. In the House, Democrats delay their cosponsorship, but there is not a statistically significant effect in the Senate. This difference is likely because of institutional differences. There are nearly five times as many members in the House as the Senate, so more bills originate in the House and members have more opportunities to cosponsor. Together, the partisan variables reveal the majority party’s control of the agenda. For the most important legislation, Republicans do not need to rely on Democrats to advance their agenda, and Democrats will probably not receive much benefit in cosponsoring Republican bills, and so delay their cosponsorship activity.

Conclusion

Our work offers several key contributions. First, moving the analysis from the US Congress to the state level, while also including all bills introduced, allows us to identify different timing strategies for key and everyday legislation. Our findings reveal that legislators strategically time their cosponsorship in response to electoral vulnerability, partisanship, and the dynamics of the chamber in which they serve. In response to the previous work on US congressional position-taking, we add legislators are strategic in state legislatures, even with non-contentious, regular policymaking.

Together, the results reveal that there are two types of cosponsorship: generalized and policy-focused. Legislators treat most bills introduced as generalized position-taking, in which reelection is their primary objective, and thus cosponsorship serves as a relatively costless, but nontrivial, signal to their constituents. But not all legislation is the same. For key votes, legislators employ a different cosponsorship decision-making calculus. Given the high-profile and influential nature of these bills, members look beyond reelection toward actual policymaking. Here, Republicans do not need to gather bipartisan cosponsors, or even to accumulate many cosponsors, because they are in the majority in both chambers. Instead, they focus their efforts on fellow partisans to ensure that they have the votes to pass the legislation they want. Electoral vulnerability has no influence over the decision to sign onto a key bill, but has important effects on this calculus for all bills.

A final important contribution involves the data. First, our analysis examines all bills, providing a more generalizable picture of position-taking. Second, the universe of legislation examined includes bills in which there was no cosponsorship. This is equally important because the absence of cosponsorship also affects cosponsorship. In looking at routine policymaking, we show that many legislators do not take a position at all. In fact, some legislators cosponsor only a few bills and some never do. As a result, cosponsorship is a relatively rare phenomenon in the data.

While the Texas legislature is not unique in having an abundance of bills with few cosponsors, analyzing data with many zeroes can by challenging. Despite this, our results are robust to different model specifications, including using Democrats as the base category instead of Republicans, using split sample based on legislator partisanship, alternative measures for variables such as ideology, the inclusion or exclusion of committees, and controlling for chamber leadership in the second set of pooled models. We also ran models specifying certain covariates as time-varying and tested other methods for handling tied failures.

As a first look at the timing of regular, non-salient position-taking, these analyses resolve some questions but raise additional avenues for future research. In this paper, we took a direct approach to studying policymaking by looking at all proposed legislation, regardless of many potentially relevant factors, such as the bill’s content, technicality, or salience, which future research should explore. Yet another avenue to pursue would be examining legislatures with more party competition as well as how factions within the dominant party inform strategic cosponsorship decisions. Future work may also explore to what degree legislators cosponsor certain bills based on the intersection of their race, gender, and partisanship.

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/spq.2023.7.

Data availability statement

Replication materials are available in the SPPQ Dataverse at https://doi.org/10.15139/S3/VRZZDP (Matthews, Schilling, and Kreitzer Reference Matthews, Schilling and Kreitzer2023).

Acknowledgements

Many thanks to Jim Battista, Fred Boehmke, Whitney Manzo, Antoine Yoshinaka, and the University of Tennessee, Knoxville Department of Political Science workshop participants for their helpful comments, as well as Mirya Holman and her students at Tulane University for their insights and questions on an earlier draft. We also thank the editors and anonymous reviewers for their comments and suggestions. We are grateful for the assistance of Aklesia Maereg and Shay Deen, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill undergraduates, for their help coding the Texas bill and legislator data. We also thank David Kreitzer for helping retrieve the bill data from the Texas Legislature Online website.

Funding statement

The authors received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Competing interest

The authors declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Author Biographies

Emily U. Schilling is an assistant professor of political science at the University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN, USA. Her research focuses on representation in state legislatures.

Abigail A. Matthews is an assistant professor of political science at the University at Buffalo, SUNY, Buffalo, NY, USA, where she studies law and courts and state politics.

Rebecca J. Kreitzer is an associate professor of public policy at the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill, Chapel Hill, NC, USA. Her research focuses on policy inequality, gendered political representation, and state politics.

Footnotes

Authorship is listed in reverse alphabetical order.

1 Legislators may abstain from voting to avoid taking a position, but it is extremely rare. For example, senators intentionally avoid taking positions in fewer than 5% of all bills (Jones Reference Jones2003; Thomas Reference Thomas1991).

2 The critical vote on NAFTA, for instance, was once described as “the most important vote on Capitol Hill since the Berlin Wall came down” (Frenzel Reference Frenzel1994, 3).

3 Party leaders also use the number, diversity, and quality of cosponsors to evaluate the costs and benefits of bills, as well as to estimate the effort needed to pass them (Koger Reference Koger2003). With more cosponsors, party leadership may need to do less to whip sufficient votes for passage. The number of cosponsors is associated with a bill receiving committee consideration though not necessarily bill passage (Krutz Reference Krutz2005; Wilson and Young Reference Wilson and Young1997; Woon Reference Woon2008). Bills with more cosponsors contain more effective public policy and are more likely to pass (Adler and Wilkerson Reference Adler and Wilkerson2013; Kirkland and Gross Reference Kirkland and Gross2014).

4 Mayhew (Reference Mayhew1991, 37) defined major or important legislation merely as “both innovative and consequential.”

5 Texas legislators make $600/month plus $221/diem for the ~140 days of the regular session.

6 This number fluctuates because of resignations and deaths.

8 We focus on regular bills and do not include resolutions in this analysis.

9 “Cosponsoring” in Texas refers only to cross-chamber cosponsorship.

12 See Table 1 for a full list of key vote bills.

13 The model counts calendar days, not session days. Because there are more calendar days than session days, our model likely underestimates the effects.

14 For further insight into the data, we randomly selected bills with 10 cosponsors and plot the cosponsorship of those bills. See Figures 13 and the accompanying text in the Supplementary Material for more information.

16 We have also analyzed models with a variable measuring the percentage of bipartisanship, but it did not change the effect.

17 We also ran models with the Democratic vote share in each state legislative district from the State Elections Returns (SLER) dataset to estimate citizen ideology in the subsequent year (doi:10.7910/DVN/3WZFK9). The findings are very similar.

18 We also run the model with more finely grained ideological measures (for both legislators and constituents), broken down into quintiles and deciles. The findings remain the same.

19 For simplicity, we do not include the committee categories in the main tables. The full results are available in Supplementary Tables S1 and S2.

20 The House Key Votes Legislation model violates the proportionality assumption. As a robustness check, we ran Weibull and Exponential models. The coefficients remain in the same direction; however, the bipartisanship variable becomes statistically significant in the alternative models.

References

Adler, E. Scott, and Wilkerson, John D.. 2013. Congress and the Politics of Problem Solving. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aldrich, John H. 1995. Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Political Parties in America. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, R. Douglas. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Bernhard, William, and Sulkin, Tracy. 2013. “Commitment and Consequences: Reneging on Cosponsorship Pledges in the U.S. House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 38 (4): 461–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bianco, William. 1994. Trust: Representatives and Constituents. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birkhead, Nathaniel A. 2015. “The Role of Ideology in State Legislative Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 40 (1): 5582.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boehmke, Frederick J. 2006. “The Influence of Unobserved Factors on Position Timing and Content in the NAFTA Vote.” Political Analysis 14 (4): 421–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M. 1996. “A Dynamic Analysis of the Role of War Chests in Campaign Strategy.” American Journal of Political Science 40 (2): 352–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., Arnold, Laura W., and Christopher, J. W. Zorn. 1997. “The Strategic Timing of Position Taking in Congress: A Study of the North American Free Trade Agreement.” American Political Science Review 91 (2): 324–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M., and Jones, Bradford S. 2004. Event History Modeling: A Guide for Social Scientists. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bratton, Kathleen A., and Rouse, Stella M.. 2011. “Networks in the Legislative Arena: How Group Dynamics Affect Cosponsorship.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36 (3): 423–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bromley-Trujillo, Rebecca, Holman, Mirya, and Sandoval, Andres. 2019. “Hot Districts, Cool Legislation: Evaluating Agenda Setting in Climate Change Bill Sponsorship in U.S. States.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 19 (3): 375–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Adam, and Goodliffe, Jay. 2017. “Why Do Legislators Skip Votes? Position Taking Versus Policy Influence.” Political Behavior 39 (2): 425–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burden, Barry C., and Snyder, Rochelle. 2021. “Explaining Uncontested Seats in Congress and State Legislatures.” American Politics Research 49 (3): 247–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burkett, Tracy, and Skvoretz, John. 2005. “Political Support Networks Among US Senators: Stability and Change from 1973 to 1990.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Caldeira, Gregory A., and Zorn, Christopher. 2004. “Strategic Timing, Position-Taking, and Impeachment in the House of Representatives.” Political Research Quarterly 57 (4): 517–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, James E. 1982. “Cosponsoring Legislation in the U. S. Congress.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 7 (3): 415–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, D. R. 1972. “Regression Models and Life-Tables.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series B (Methodological) 34 (2): 187202.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W., and McCubbins, Matthew D.. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Crisp, Brian F., Kanthak, Kristin, and Leijonhufvud, Jenny. 2004. “The Reputations Legislators Build: With Whom Should Representatives Collaborate?The American Political Science Review 98 (4): 703–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desposato, Scott W., Kearney, Matthew C., and Crisp, Brian F.. 2011. “Using Cosponsorship to Estimate Ideal Points.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36 (4): 531–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dodd, Lawrence C., and Schraufnagel, Scot. 2009. “Re-Thinking Legislative Productivity: Commemorative Legislation and Policy Gridlock.” In Congress & the Presidency, 132–47. Milton: Taylor & Francis.Google Scholar
Durr, Robert H., Gilmour, John B., and Wolbrecht, Christina. 1997. “Explaining Congressional Approval.” American Journal of Political Science 41: 175207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. 1977. “US House Members in Their Constituencies: An Exploration.” American Political Science Review 71 (3): 883917.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fenno, Richard F. 1978. Home Style: House Members in Their Districts. Boston, MA: Little, Brown.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. 1977. “On the Decline of Competition in Congressional Elections.” American Political Science Review 71 (1): 166–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fong, Christian. 2020. “Expertise, Networks, and Interpersonal Influence in Congress.” Journal of Politics 82 (1): 269–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fouirnaies, Alexander, and Hall, Andrew B.. 2018. “How Do Interest Groups Seek Access to Committees?American Journal of Political Science 62 (1): 132–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fouirnaies, Alexander, and Hall, Andrew B.. 2022. “How Do Electoral Incentives Affect Legislator Behavior? Evidence from U.S. State Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 116 (2): 662–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzitch, Stephen. 1979. “Who Makes Our Laws? The Legislative Effectiveness of Members of Congress.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 5 (3): 409–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frenzel, Bill. 1994. “GATT: Where the Real Money Is.” Brookings Review 12 (3): 33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garand, James C., and Burke, Kelly M.. 2006. “Legislative Activity and the 1994 Republican Takeover: Exploring Changing Patterns of Sponsorship and Cosponsorship in the U.S. House.” American Politics Research 34 (2): 159–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia, Matthew Mendez, and Sadhwani, Sara. 2022. “¿Quién Importa? State Legislators and Their Responsiveness to Undocumented Immigrants.” Political Research Quarterly. https://doi.org/10.1177/10659129221137825.Google Scholar
Glazer, Amihai, Griffin, Robert, Grofman, Bernard, and Wattenberg, Martin. 1995. “Strategic Vote Delay in the U.S. House of Representatives.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 20 (1): 3745.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbridge, Laurel, Malhotra, Neil, and Harrison, Brian F.. 2014. “Public Preferences for Bipartisanship in the Policymaking Process.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 39 (3): 327–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holman, Mirya R., and Mahoney, Anna. 2018. “Stop, Collaborate, and Listen: Women’s Collaboration in US.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 43 (2): 179206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Howell, William, Adler, Scott, Cameron, Charles, and Riemann, Charles. 2000. “Divided Government and the Legislative Productivity of Congress, 1945–94.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 25 (2): 285312.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, Taofang, and Theriault, Sean M.. 2012. “The Strategic Timing Behind Position-Taking in the US Congress: A Study of the Comprehensive Immigration Reform Act.” Journal of Legislative Studies 18 (1): 4162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, David R. 2003. “Position Taking and Position Avoidance in the U.S. Senate.” The Journal of Politics 65(3): 851–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobson, Gary C. 1987. “The Marginals Never Vanished: Incumbency and Competition in Elections to the U.S. House of Representatives, 1952-82.” American Journal of Political Science 31(1): 126–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanthak, Kristin, and Krause, George. 2012. The Diversity Paradox: Parties, Legislatures, and the Organizational Foundations of Representation in America. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Kessler, Daniel, and Krehbiel, Keith. 1996. “Dynamics of Cosponsorship.” American Political Science Review 90 (3): 555–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1984. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. Boston, MA: Little-Brown.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1989. Congressmen’s Voting Decisions, 3rd edition. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H. 2011. “The Relational Determinants of Legislative Outcomes: Strong and Weak Ties Between Legislators.” Journal of Politics 73 (3): 887–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H. 2014. “Chamber Size Effects on the Collaborative Structure of Legislatures.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 39 (2): 169–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H., and Gross, Justin H.. 2014. “Measurement and Theory in Legislative Networks: The Evolving Topology of Congressional Collaboration.” Social Networks 36 (1): 97109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkland, Justin H., and Williams, R. Lucas. 2014. “Partisanship and Reciprocity in Cross-Chamber Legislative Interactions.” Journal of Politics 76 (3): 754–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klarner, Carl, Berry, Williams, Carsey, Thomas, Jewell, Malcolm, Niemi, Richard, Powell, Lynda, and Snyder, James. 2013. “State Legislative Election Returns Data, 1967–2010.” https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/LIHUAA (June 17, 2022).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klarner, Carl. 2018. “State Legislative Election Returns, 1967–2016.” https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/3WZFK9 (June 17, 2022).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koger, Gregory. 2003. “Position Taking and Cosponsorship in the U.S. House.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 28 (2): 225–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1991. Information and Legislative Organization. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1995. “Cosponsors and Wafflers from A to Z.” American Journal of Political Science 39 (4): 906–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krutz, Glen S. 2005. “Issues and Institutions:‘Winnowing’ in the US Congress.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (2): 313–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lazarus, Jeffrey, and Steigerwalt, Amy. 2018. Gendered Vulnerability: How Women Work Harder to Stay in Office. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1993. “A Signaling Model of Informative and Manipulative Political Action.” American Political Science Review 87 (2): 319–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Makse, Todd. 2020. “The Disappearance of Bipartisan Representation.” In A Divided Union: Structural Challenges to Bipartisanship in America, eds. Moreno, Dario, Gamarra, Eduardo, Murphy, Patrick and Jolly, David. Milton: Taylor & Francis Group.Google Scholar
Mann, Thomas E. 1978. Unsafe at Any Margin: Interpreting Congressional Elections. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Matthews, Abigail A., Kreitzer, Rebecca J., and Schilling, Emily U.. 2020. “Gendered Polarization and Abortion Policymaking in the States.” Forum 18 (1): 5169.Google Scholar
Matthews, Abigail A., Schilling, Emily U., and Kreitzer, Rebecca J.. 2023 “Replication Data for: Timing Their Positions: Cosponsorship in the State Legislature, UNC Dataverse, V1.” doi:10.15139/S3/VRZZDP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, Donald R, and Stimson, James A.. 1975. Yeas and Nays: Normal Decision-Making in the U.S. House of Representatives. New York: Wiley InterScience.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Mayhew, David. 1991. Divided We Govern: Party Control, Lawmaking, and Investigations, 1946-1990. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Miquel, Gerard Padró I, and Snyder, James M. Jr. 2006. “Legislative Effectiveness and Legislative Careers.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 31 (3): 347–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myers, Adam S. 2020. “Explaining Increased Contestation in the 2018 State Legislative Elections.” PS: Political Science & Politics 53 (3): 429–34.Google Scholar
Peterson, Erik. 2017. “The Role of the Information Environment in Partisan Voting.” Journal of Politics 79 (4): 11911204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rippere, Paulina S. 2016. “Polarization Reconsidered: Bipartisan Cooperation Through Bill Cosponsorship.” Polity 48 (2): 243–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocca, Michael S., and Sanchez, Gabriel R.. 2008. “The Effect of Race and Ethnicity on Bill Sponsorship and Cosponsorship in Congress.” American Politics Research 36 (1): 130–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rogers, Steven. 2017. “Electoral Accountability for State Legislative Roll Calls and Ideological Representation.” American Political Science Review 111 (3): 555–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandoval, Edgar, Montgomery, David, and Fernandez, Manny. 2021. “‘Contested, Heated Culture Wars’ Mark Ultraconservative Texas Session.” New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/06/01/us/texas-republicans.html (June 2, 2021).Google Scholar
Sarbaugh-Thompson, Marjorie, Thompson, Lyke, Elder, Charles D., Comins, Meg, Elling, Richard C., and Strate, John. 2006. “Democracy Among Strangers: Term Limits’ Effects on Relationships Between State Legislators in Michigan.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 6 (4): 384409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schiller, Wendy J. 1995. “Senators as Political Entrepreneurs: Using Bill Sponsorship to Shape Legislative Agendas.” American Journal of Political Science 39 (1): 186203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shipan, Charles R., and Shannon, Megan L.. 2003. “Delaying Justice(s): A Duration Analysis of Supreme Court Confirmations.” American Journal of Political Science 47 (4): 654–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shor, Boris, and McCarty, Nolan. 2011. “The Ideological Mapping of American Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 105 (3): 530–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swift, Clint S., and VanderMolen, Kathryn A.. 2016. “Term Limits and Collaboration Across the Aisle: An Analysis of Bipartisan Cosponsorship in Term Limited and Non-Term Limited State Legislatures.” State Politics & Policy Quarterly 16 (2): 198226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tausanovitch, Chris, and Warshaw, Christopher. 2013. “Measuring Constituent Policy Preferences in Congress, State Legislatures, and Cities.” Journal of Politics 75 (2): 330–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, Martin. 1991. “Issue Avoidance: Evidence from the U.S. Senate.” Political Behavior 13 (1): 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trubowitz, Peter, and Mellow, Nicole. 2005. “‘Going Bipartisan’: Politics by Other Means.” Political Science Quarterly 120 (3): 433–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Waggoner, Philip D. 2018. “Exploring Responsiveness in the U.S. House of Representatives.” American Review of Politics 36 (2): 5885.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Rick K., and Young, Cheryl D.. 1997. “Cosponsorship in the US Congress.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 22 (1): 2543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woon, Jonathan. 2008. “Bill Sponsorship in Congress: The Moderating Effect of Agenda Positions on Legislative Proposals.” Journal of Politics 70 (1): 201–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yamaguchi, Kazuo. 1991. Event History Analysis. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Zelizer, Adam. 2019. “Is Position-Taking Contagious? Evidence of Cue-Taking from Two Field Experiments in a State Legislature.” American Political Science Review 113 (2): 340–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Total cosponsorship in each regular session.

Figure 1

Figure 2a.Figure 2a. Mean number of bills cosponsored.

Figure 2

Figure 2a.Figure 2b. Mean number of cosponsors.

Figure 3

Figure 3. 2019 Senate bill SB21 cosponsorship timing.

Figure 4

Table 1. Cosponsorship timing for all legislation, 1997–2020

Figure 5

Table 2. Cosponsorship timing for key vote legislation, 2009–20

Supplementary material: File

Schilling et al. supplementary material

Schilling et al. supplementary material

Download Schilling et al. supplementary material(File)
File 408.6 KB
Supplementary material: Link

Schilling et al. Dataset

Link