Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T17:01:49.961Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Confidence, Fear, and a Propensity to Gamble: The Puzzle of War and Economics in an Age of Catastrophe 1914–45

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 November 2016

Abstract

This paper uses the notion of animal spirits introduced by John Maynard Keynes in the General Theory, and more recently employed by George Akerloff and Robert Shiller in their book Animal Spirits, to explain the speculative bubbles and decisions for war from 1914 to 1945. Animal spirits are a spontaneous urge to action rather than inaction that produces decisions that are not bounded by rational calculations. My analysis shows how confidence, fear, and a propensity to gamble can encourage aggressive behavior that leads to speculative “bubbles” in financial markets and military or political crises. Elements of prospect theory are added to demonstrate how the presence of risk in crises tend to produce a very strong bias toward taking gambles to avoid economic or military loses. A basic premise of the paper is that war and economics were inexorably joined together by 1914 to a point where economic strength was as important as military might in determining the outcome of a war. The final section of the paper deals with the problem of measuring military and economic strength by using the Composite Index of National Capability created by the Correlates of War Project to evaluate the riskiness of the Schlieffen Plan in 1914 and the changes in military capability of major powers between 1914 and 1919.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Social Science History Association, 2016 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, George A., and Shiller, Robert J. (2009) Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Barnett, Correlli (1963) The Swordbearers: Supreme Command in the First World War. London: Cassell and Co.Google Scholar
Bismarck, Otto von (1968) Reflections and Reminiscences, edited with an introduction by Theodore S. Hamerow. New York: Harper Torchbooks.Google Scholar
Breit, William, and Ransom, Roger L. (1998) The Academic Scribblers, 3rd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Calomiris, Charles, and Haber, Stephen (2014) Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises and Scarce Credit. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Clausewitz, Carl Von (2008 [1832]) On War, trans. Michael Howard and Peter Paret. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Clodfelter, Micheal (2002) Warfare and Armed Conflicts: A Statistical Reference to Casualty and Other Figures, 1500–2000, 2nd ed. Jefferson, NC: McFarland and Company.Google Scholar
Copeland, Dale C. (2000) The Origins of Major War. Cornell Studies in Security Affairs. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Correlates of War Project (2014) “Project history.” http://correlatesofwar.org/COWhistory.htm, accessed September 20, 2016.Google Scholar
Eigen, Lewis D., and Siegel, Jonathan Paul (1993) The Macmillan Dictionary of Political Quotations. Toronto: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Niall (1999) The Pity of War: Explaining World War I. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Findlay, Ronald, and O'Rourke, Kevin H. (2007) Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galbraith, John Kenneth (1954) The Great Crash, 1929. New York: Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Martin (1994) The First World War: A Complete History. New York: Henry Holt.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Martin (1997) A History of the Twentieth Century. Vol. 1, 1900–1933. New York: William Morrow.Google Scholar
Henning, Ruth (1989) The Origins of the First World War, 2nd ed. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hobsbawm, Eric (1994) The Age of Extremes: A History of the World, 1914–1990. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Johnson, Dominic D. P. (2004) Overconfidence and War: The Havoc and Glory of Positive Ilusions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kagan, Donald (1995) On the Origins of War and the Preservation of Peace. New York: Doubleday.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos (1979) “Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.” Econometrica 47 (2): 263–91.Google Scholar
Keynes, John Maynard (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. New York: Harcourt Brace and World.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles, and Aliber, Robert (2005) Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, 5th ed. Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles, and Laffargue, Jean Pierre, eds. (1982) Financial Crises: Theory, History, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P. (1986) The World in Depression, 1929–1939, rev. and enlarged ed. New York: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles Poor (1978) Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962) The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Levy, Jack S., and Thompson, William (2010) The Causes of War. Chichester, UK: John Wiley/Blackwell Kindle edition.Google Scholar
Minsky, Hyman (1982) “The financial instability hypothesis: Capitalist processes and the behavior of the economy,” in Kindleberger, Charles (ed.) Financial Crises: Theory, History, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press: 1347.Google Scholar
Mombauer, Annika (2005) “Of war plans and war guilt: The debate surrounding the Schlieffen plan.” Journal of Strategic Studies 28 (5): 857–85.Google Scholar
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Rogoff, Kenneth S. (2008) “This time is different: A panoramic view of eight centuries of financial crises.” NBER Working Paper No. 13882, March: 1–123.Google Scholar
Reinhart, Carmen M., and Rogoff, Kenneth S. (2009) This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ritschl, Albrecht (2005) “The pity of peace: Germany's economy at war, 1914–1918 and beyond,” in Broadberry, Stepthen and Harrison, Mark (eds.) The Economics of World War I. New York: Cambridge University Press: 7176.Google Scholar
Ritter, Gerhard (1958) The Schlieffen Plan: Critique of a Myth. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Royle, Trevor (2000) Crimea: The Great Crimean War, 1854–1856. New York: Palgrave MacMillan.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert (2003) “Rational and irrational bubbles,” in Hunter, William C, Kaufman, George G., and Pomerleano, Michael (eds.) Diverse Views on Asset Bubbles. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press: 3540.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J. (2000) Irrational Exuberance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Spender, John A. (1927) Life, Journalism and Politics. New York: Frederick A. Stokes Comany.Google Scholar
Stoessinger, John (2001) Why Nations Go to War, 8th ed. New York: Beford/St. Martin's.Google Scholar
Tuchman, Barbara (1962) The Guns of August. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Van Evera, Stephen (1999) Causes of War: Power and the Roots of Conflict. Ithaca: Cornell Universty Press.Google Scholar
Vasquez, John A. (1993) The War Puzzle. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Vasquez, John A. (2009) The War Puzzle Revisited. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Zuber, Terence (2002) Inventing the Schlieffen Plan: German War Planning, 1871–1914. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar