Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T21:47:01.841Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Can animal spirits explain the dynamics of European unemployment?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 August 2016

Patrick Fève
Affiliation:
Université de Nantes, LEN-C3E and CEPREMAP
François Langot
Affiliation:
Université du Maine, GAINS and CEPREMAP
Get access

Summary

We estimate a model with equilibrium unemployment explained by a search process on the labor market. We find that the matching function has increasing returns to scale and we show that this model may display fluctuations at business cycle frequencies even when there are no shocks to the fundamentals of the economy. In particular, self-fulfilling beliefs, or “animal spirits”, can explain the fluctuations around the Beveridge curve observed in the French, German and U.K. economies.

Résumé

Résumé

Nous estimons un modèle où le chômage d’équilibre est expliqué par un processus de recherche. Nous trouvons que la fonction d’appariement a des rendements croissants et montrons que ce modäle peut engendrer des fluctuations sans que l’économie ne soit perturbée par des chocs sur les fondamentaux. Ainsi, des croyances auto-réalisatrices, ou des “esprits animaux”, peuvent expliquer les fluctuations autour de la courbe de Beveridge, observées en Allemagne, en France ou au Royaume-Uni.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Université catholique de Louvain, Institut de recherches économiques et sociales 1996 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

(*)

We thank G. Demange, J. Gali, C. Gourieroux, R. Guesnerie, P.Y. Hénin, J.P. Laffargue, G. Laroque, O. Licandro, D. Mortensen, G. Pfann, J.M. Tallon and C. Wyplosz for fruitful comments. This version has also benefited from discussions during presentation at the Society of Economic Dynamics and Control 1995 congress in Barcelona, at the “Human Capital Mobility” workshop 1995 in Maastricht, at the Winter Meeting of the Econometric Society 1996 in Copenhagen, at the T2M conference 1996 in Paris and at MAD, DELTA and CREST seminars. Suggestions by anonymous referees were extremely helpful. All remaining mistakes are our own.

References

Anderson, P. and Burgess, S., [1995], Empirical matching functions: estimation and interpretation using disaggregate data, Working Paper 95/389, Univerity of Bristol.Google Scholar
Andrews, D. [1991], Heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimation, Econometrica, 59(3), pp. 817858.Google Scholar
Azariadis, C. [1981], Self-fulfilling prophecies, Journal of Economic Theory, 25(3), pp. 380396.Google Scholar
Benhabib, J. and Rustichini, A. [1994], Introduction to the symposium on Growth, fluctuations and sunspots; confronting the data, Journal of Economic Theory, 63(1), pp. 118.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. [1993], Consumption and the recession of 1990–1991, The American Economic Review, 83(2), pp. 270274.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O.J. and Diamond, P. [1989], The beveridge curve, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, I, pp. 176.Google Scholar
Burda, M. and Wyplosz, C. [1994], Gross worker and job lows in Europe, The European Economic Review, 38(6), pp. 12571276.Google Scholar
Burnside, C., Eichenbaum, M. and Rebelo, S. [1993], Labor hoarding and the business cycle, Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), pp. 245273.Google Scholar
Cass, D. and Shell, K. [1983], Do sunspots matter?, The Journal of Political Economy, 91(2), pp. 193227.Google Scholar
Chiappori, P.A. and Guesnerie, R. [1991], Sunspot equilibria in sequential markets models, in Hildenbrand, W. and Sonnenschein, H. (eds.), Handbook of Mathemetical Economics, Amsterdam, North-Holland, pp. 16831762.Google Scholar
Christiano, L. and Eichenbaum, M. [1992], Current real business cycle theories and aggregate labor-market fluctuations, American Economic Review, 82(3), pp. 430450.Google Scholar
Cochrane, J. [1994], Shocks, NBER Working paper n 4698.Google Scholar
Eichenbaum, M. [1991], Real business cycle theory: Wisdom or whimsy?, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 15(4), pp. 607626.Google Scholar
Farmer, R. [1994], The macroeconomics of self-fulfilling prophecies, Cambridge, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Farmer, R. and Guo, J.T. [1994], Real business cycles and the animal spirits hypothesis, Journal of Economic Theory, 63(1), pp. 4272.Google Scholar
Fève, P. and Langot, F. [1994], The RBC models through statistical inference, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 9(Supplement), pp. S11-S37.Google Scholar
Fève, P. and Langot, F. [1995], La méthode des moments généralisés et ses extensions, Economic et Prévision, 119(3), pp. 139170.Google Scholar
Fève, P. and Langot, F. [1996], Unemployment and the business cycle in a small open economy, Journal of Economic, Dynamics and Control, 20(910), pp. 16091639.Google Scholar
Gali, J. [1994], Monopolistic competition, business cycles and the composition of aggregate demand, Journal of Economic Theory, 1(68), pp. 7396.Google Scholar
Hall, R. [1993], Macro theory and the recession 1990–1991, The American Economic Review, 83(2), pp. 275279.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. [1982], Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators, Econometrica, 50(4), pp. 10291054.Google Scholar
Hansen, L. and Singleton, K. [1982], Generalized instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear rational expectations models, Econometrica, 50(5), pp. 12691286.Google Scholar
Hodrick, R. and Prescott, E. [1980], Post-war U.S. Business cycles: An empirical investigation, Mimeo, Carnegie-Mellon University.Google Scholar
Jacques, J.F. and Langot, F. [1993], Persistance du chômage et marché du travail: la dynamique de la courbe de Beveridge, in Hénin, P.Y. (ed.), La Persistance du Chômage, Paris, Economica, chapter 4, pp. 115158.Google Scholar
Kydland, F. and Prescott, E. [1982], Time to build and aggregate fluctuations, Econometrica, 50(6), pp. 13451370.Google Scholar
Langot, F. [1995], Unemployement and business cycle: a general equilibrium matching model, in Hénin, P.Y. (ed.), Advances in Business Cycle Theory, Heidelberg, Springer-Verlag, chapter 8, pp, 287325.Google Scholar
Layard, R., Nickell, S., and Jackman, R. [1991], Unemployment, Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market, Oxford, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. [1986], Job search and labor market analysis, in Ashenfelter, O. and Layard, R. (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam, North-Holland, pp. 849919.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. [1989], Persistance and indeterminacy of unemployment in search equilibrium, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 91(2), pp. 347370.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. [1990], Search equilibrium and real business cycles, Working Paper, Northwestern University.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. [1994], The cyclical behavior of job and workers flows, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 18(6), pp. 11211142.Google Scholar
Newey, W. and West, K. [1987], A simple, positive definite, heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix, Econometrica, 55(3), pp. 703708.Google Scholar
Ogaki, M. [1993], Generalized method of moments: Econometric applications, in Maddala, G. Rao, C., and Vinod, H. (eds.), Handbook of Statistics, Amsterdam, Elsevier Sciences Publisher, vol. 11, chapter 17.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. [1986], Unemployment and vacancies in Britain, Economic Policy, 3, pp. 498559.Google Scholar
Pissarides, C. [1990], Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, Oxford, Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. [1986], Stationary sunspot equilibria: the case of small fluctuations around the dterministic steady state, manuscript, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Woodford, M. [1991], Self-fulfilling expectations and fluctuations in aggregate demand, in Mankiw, N.G. and Romer, D. (eds), New Keynesian Economics, Cambridge, MIT Press, vol. 2, pp. 77110.Google Scholar