Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-mp689 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T11:55:54.369Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

ENTREPRENEURS, FINANCIERS, AND BOOM–BUST CYCLES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 April 2016

Takuma Kunieda*
Affiliation:
Kwansei Gakuin University
Akihisa Shibata
Affiliation:
Kyoto University
*
Address correspondence to: Takuma Kunieda, School of Economics, Kwansei Gakuin University, 1-155 Uegahara Ichiban-Cho, Nishinomiya, Hyogo 662-8501, Japan; e-mail: tkunieda@kwansei.ac.jp.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

In this paper, a dynamic general equilibrium model with infinitely lived entrepreneurs and financiers is developed to investigate a possible mechanism that explains business cycles and financial crises. The highest growth rate is achievable only if financiers coexist with entrepreneurs, given a certain extent of financial market imperfections. However, if financiers coexist with entrepreneurs, the economy is highly likely to face a financial crisis at certain parameter values. These two-sided implications of the coexistence of entrepreneurs and financiers explain why both instability and high growth are frequently observed in modern economies. Furthermore, our model can obtain countercyclical movements in total factor productivity growth that cannot be explained by the standard real business cycle theory but were observed in the Great Recession of 2007–2008.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2016 

Footnotes

The authors would like to express special thanks to an anonymous referee and an associate editor for their invaluable comments and suggestions. The authors would like to thank Shinsuke Ikeda, Yoshiyasu Ono, seminar participants at Osaka University, and session participants of “Development Economics: Macroeconomic Issues” at the 2013 Annual Conference of the Royal Economic Society and of “Macroeconomics of Liquidity” at the 2014 SWET for their helpful comments. This study has received financial support from a Grant-in-Aid for Specially Promoted Research (No. 23000001), City University of Hong Kong (No. 7004283) and the Joint Research Program of KIER, Kyoto University.

References

REFERENCES

Aghion, Philippe, Bacchetta, Philippe, and Banerjee, Abhijit (2004) Financial development and the instability of open economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (6), 10771106.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Banerjee, Abhijit (2005) Volatility and Growth. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Banerjee, Abhijit, and Piketty, Thomas (1999) Dualism and macroeconomic volatility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4), 13591397.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Howitt, Peter, and Mayer-Foulkes, David (2005) The effect of financial development on convergence: Theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120 (1), 173222.Google Scholar
Aghion, Philippe and Saint-Paul, Gilles (1998) Uncovering some causal relationships between productivity growth and the structure of economic fluctuations: A tentative survey. Labour 12 (2), 279303.Google Scholar
Angeletos, George-Marios (2007) Uninsured idiosyncratic investment risk and aggregate saving. Review of Economic Dynamics 10 (1), 130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antràs, Pol and Caballero, Ricardo J. (2009) Trade and capital flows: A financial frictions perspective. Journal of Political Economy 117 (4), 701744.Google Scholar
Antràs, Pol and Caballero, Ricardo J. (2010) On the role of financial frictions and the saving rate during trade liberalizations. Journal of the European Economic Association 8 (2–3), 442455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aoki, Kosuke, Proudman, James, and Vlieghe, Gertjan (2004) House prices, consumption, and monetary policy: A financial accelerator approach. Journal of Financial Intermediation 13 (4), 414435.Google Scholar
Azariadis, Costas and Kaas, Leo (2008) Credit and growth under limited commitment. Macroeconomic Dynamics 12 (S1), 2030.Google Scholar
Azariadis, Costas, Kaas, Leo, and Wen, Yi (2015) Self-Fulfilling Credit Cycles. No. 5289, Center for Economic Studies and Ifo Institute (CESifo).Google Scholar
Azariadis, Costas and Smith, Bruce D. (1998) Financial intermediation and regime switching in business cycles. American Economic Review 88 (3), 516536.Google Scholar
Basu, Susanto, Fernald, John G., and Kimball, Miles S. (2006) Are technology improvements contractionary? American Economic Review 96 (5), 14181448.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Day, Richard H. (1982) A characteristic of erratic dynamics in the overlapping generations model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 4 (1), 3755.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess. and Farmer, Roger E.A. (1994) Indeterminacy and increasing returns. Journal of Economic Theory 63 (1), 1941.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess. and Farmer, Roger E.A. (1996) Indeterminacy and sector-specific externalities. Journal of Monetary Economics 37 (3), 421443.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Laroque, Guy (1988) On competitive cycles in productive economies. Journal of Economic Theory 45 (1), 145170.Google Scholar
Benhabib, Jess and Nishimura, Kazuo (1985) Competitive equilibrium cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 35 (2), 284306.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben and Gertler, Mark (1989) Agency costs, net worth, and business fluctuations. American Economic Review 79 (1), 1431.Google Scholar
Boissay, Frédéric, Collard, Fabrice, and Smets, Frank (in press) Booms and banking crises. Journal of Political Economy.Google Scholar
Boldrin, Michele and Deneckere, Raymond J. (1990) Sources of complex dynamics in two-sector growth models. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 14 (3–4), 627653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boldrin, Michele and Rustichini, Aldo (1994) Growth and indeterminacy in dynamic models with externalities. Econometrica 62 (2), 323342.Google Scholar
Caballero, Ricardo J. and Hammour, Mohamad L. (1994) The cleansing effect of recessions. American Economic Review 84 (5), 1350–68.Google Scholar
Cordoba, Juan-Carlos and Ripoll, Marla (2004a) Collateral constraints in a monetary economy. Journal of the European Economic Association 2 (6), 11721205.Google Scholar
Cordoba, Juan-Carlos and Ripoll, Marla (2004b), Credit cycles redux. International Economic Review 45 (4), 10111046.Google Scholar
Farmer, Roger E.A. (1986) Deficits and cycles. Journal of Economic Theory 40 (1), 7788.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Favara, Giovanni (2012) Agency problems and endogenous investment fluctuations. Review of Financial Studies 25 (7), 23012342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernald, John and Matoba, Kyle (2009) Growth accounting, potential output, and the current recession. FRBSF Economic Letter 26(August 17).Google Scholar
Field, Alexander J. (2010) The procyclical behavior of total factor productivity in the United States, 1890–2004. Journal of Economic History 70 (2), 326350.Google Scholar
Futagami, Koichi and Mino, Kazuo (1993) Threshold externalities and cyclical growth in a stylized model of capital accumulation. Economics Letters 41 (1), 99105.Google Scholar
Gali, Jordi (1994) Monopolistic competition, business cycles, and the composition of aggregate demand. Journal of Economic Theory 63 (1), 7396.Google Scholar
Galor, Oded and Zeira, Joseph (1993) Income distribution and macroeconomics. Review of Economic Studies 60 (1), 3552.Google Scholar
Gokan, Yoichi (2011) Poverty traps, the money growth rule, and the stage of financial development. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 35 (8), 12731287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandmont, Jean-Michel (1985) On endogenous competitive cycles. Econometrica 53 (5), 9951046.Google Scholar
Gu, Chao, Mattesini, Fabrizio, Monnet, Fabrizio, and Wright, Randall (2013). Endogenous credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 121 (5), 940965.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ho, Wai-Hong and Yong, Wang (2005) Public capital, asymmetric information, and economic growth. Canadian Journal of Economics 38 (1), 5780.Google Scholar
Ho, Wai-Hong and Yong, Wang (2013) Asymmetric information, auditing commitment and economic growth. Canadian Journal of Economics 46 (2), 611633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iacoviello, Matteo (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review 95 (3), 739764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaas, Leo (2014) Public Debt and Total Factor Productivity. No. 2014–22, Department of Economics, University of Konstanz.Google Scholar
Kalecki, Michal (1937) A theory of the business cycles. Review of Economic Studies 4 (2), 7797.Google Scholar
Khan, Aubhik (2001) Financial development and economic growth. Macroeconomic Dynamics 5 (3), 413433.Google Scholar
Kikuchi, Tomoo (2008) International asset market, nonconvergence, and endogenous fluctuations. Journal of Economic Theory 139 (1), 310334.Google Scholar
Kikuchi, Tomoo and Stachurski, John (2009) Endogenous inequality and fluctuations in a two-country model. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (4), 15601571.Google Scholar
Kitagawa, Akiomi and Shibata, Akihisa (2001) Long gestation in an overlapping generations economy: Endogenous cycles and indeterminacy of equilibria. Journal of Mathematical Economics 35 (1), 99127.Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and Moore, John (1997) Credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 105 (2), 211248.Google Scholar
Kunieda, Takuma, Okada, Keisuke, and Shibata, Akihisa (2014) Finance and inequality: How does globalization change their relationship? Macroeconomic Dynamics 18 (5), 10911128.Google Scholar
Kunieda, Takuma and Shibata, Akihisa (2011) Endogenous growth and fluctuations in an overlapping generations economy with credit market imperfections. Asia–Pacific Journal of Accounting and Economics 18 (3), 333357.Google Scholar
Kunieda, Takuma and Shibata, Akihisa (2012) Asset Bubbles, Economic Growth, and a Self-Fulfilling Financial Crisis. City University of Hong Kong.Google Scholar
Kunieda, Takuma and Shibata, Akihisa (2014) Credit market imperfections and macroeconomic instability. Pacific Economic Review 19 (5), 592611.Google Scholar
Laeven, Luc, Levine, Ross, and Michalopoulos, Stelios (2014) Financial innovation and endogenous growth. Journal of Financial Intermediation 24 (1), 124.Google Scholar
Malley, Jim and Muscatelli, Vito A. (1999) Business cycles and productivity growth: Are temporary downturns productive or wasteful? Research in Economics 53 (4), 337364.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (2004) Financial market globalization, symmetry-breaking, and endogenous inequality of nations. Econometrica 72 (3), 853884.Google Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (2007) Credit traps and credit cycles. American Economic Review 97 (1), 503516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsuyama, Kiminori (2013) The good, the bad, and the ugly: An inquiry into the causes and nature of credit cycles. Theoretical Economics 8 (3), 623651.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. (2012) A model of moral-hazard credit cycles. Journal of Political Economy 120 (5), 847878.Google Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. (2014) Moral-hazard credit cycles with risk-averse agents. Journal of Economic Theory 153, 74102.Google Scholar
Nishimura, Kazuo and Yano, Makoto (1995) Nonlinear dynamics and chaos in optimal growth: An example. Econometrica 63 (4), 9811001.Google Scholar
Nourry, Carine and Venditti, Alain (2012) Endogenous business cycles in overlapping-generations economies with multiple consumption goods. Macroeconomic Dynamics 16 (S1), 86102.Google Scholar
Orgiazzi, Elsa (2008) Financial development and instability: The role of the labour share. Research in Economics 62 (4), 215236.Google Scholar
Petrosky-Nadeau, Nicolas (2013) TFP during a credit crunch. Journal of Economic Theory 148 (3), 11501178.Google Scholar
Pintus, Patrick A. (2011) International capital flows, debt overhang and volatility. International Journal of Economic Theory 7 (4), 301315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pintus, Patrick A. and Wen, Yi (2013) Leveraged borrowing and boom–bust cycles. Review of Economic Dynamics 16 (4), 617633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reichlin, Pietro (1986) Equilibrium cycles in an overlapping generations economy with production. Journal of Economic Theory 40 (1), 89102.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan (1956) The Accumulation of Capital. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Rochon, Céline and Polemarchakis, Herakles M. (2006) Debt, liquidity and dynamics. Economic Theory 27 (1), 179211.Google Scholar
Saint-Paul, Gilles (1993) Productivity growth and the structure of the business cycle. European Economic Review 37 (4), 861883.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1939) Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical, and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Suarez, Javier and Sussman, Oren (1997) Endogenous cycles in a Stiglitz–Weiss economy. Journal of Economic Theory 76 (1), 4771.Google Scholar
Takalo, Tuomas and Toivanen, Otto (2012) Entrepreneurship, financiership, and selection. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114 (2), 601628.Google Scholar
Tomura, Hajime (2013) Heterogeneous beliefs and housing-market boom–bust cycles. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37 (4), 735755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Townsend, Robert M. (1979) Optimal contracts and competitive markets with costly state verification Journal of Economic Theory 21 (2), 265293.Google Scholar
Williamson, Stephen D. (1986) Costly monitoring, financial intermediation, and equilibrium credit rationing. Journal of Monetary Economics 18 (2), 159179.Google Scholar
Williamson, Stephen D. (1987) Costly monitoring, loan contracts, and equilibrium credit rationing. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (1), 135–45.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (1986) Stationary sunspot equilibria in a finance constrained economy. Journal of Economic Theory 40 (1), 128137.Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (1988) Imperfect financial intermediation and complex dynamics. In Barnett, William A., Geweke, John, and Shell, Karl (eds.), Economic Complexity: Chaos, Bubbles, and Nonlinearity, pp. 309334. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar