Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vfjqv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T15:17:06.446Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HES Presidential Address Hayek: Right for the Wrong Reasons?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Bruce Caldwell
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, P.O. Box 26165, University of North Carolina at Greensboro, Greensboro, NC 27402-6165

Extract

The controversial question of whether the millennium began on January 1, 2000 or on January 1, 2001 weighed heavily on my mind as I composed my talk. The dilemma is, I should think, evident: Should a historian of thought want to give the last address of the old millennium, or the first address of the new one? I couldn't make up my mind about this, so I decided to consult my friends, particularly those whom I felt had given the question their considered attention. I asked David Colander, and he assured me that my preferences didn't matter, since he in fact had certainly given the final presidential address of the last millennium when he spoke in Greensboro the previous June. I then asked John Davis, and he assured me that my preferences didn't matter since he, in fact, was certainly going to give the first one of the new millennium, in 2001. Now being not nearly so stupid as I look, it occurred to me that if I listened to both of these individuals, there was a chance that I was going to give neither the last address of the old nor the first address of the new millennium. Feeling that this was, to put it mildly, an unacceptable outcome, I decided to disregard the ill-considered advice of my so-called friends and take firm control of the situation. Ladies and gentleman, I am very proud to be before you here today, delivering both the last presidential address of the old millennium and the first of the new one.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2001

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Backhouse, Roger. 1997. Truth and Progress in Economic Knowledge. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1980. The Methodology of Economics: Or How Economists Explain, 2nd edition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Boettke, Peter. 1998. “Economic Calculation: The Austrian Contribution to Political Economy.” Advances in Austrian Economics 5: 131–58.Google Scholar
Caldwell, Bruce 2000. “The Emergence of Hayek's Ideas on Cultural Evolution.” The Review of Austrian Economics 13 (02): 522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cassidy, John. 2000. “The Price Prophet.” The New Yorker 02 7: 4451.Google Scholar
Colander, David. 2000. “The Death of Neoclassica Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22 (06): 127–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David and Brenner, Reuven, eds. 1992. Educating Economists. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Goldfarb, Robert. 1997. “Now You See It, Now You Don't: Emerging Contrary Results in Economics.” The Journal of Economic Methodology 4 (12): 221–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Daniel. 1992. The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1940. “Socialist Calculation: The Competitive ‘Solution’.” Economica N.S. 7 (05): 125–49.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1952. The Sensory Order: An Inquiry into the Foundations of Theoretical Psychology. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1967. “The Theory of Complex Phenomena.” In F.A. Hayek, Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 2242.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1978. “Competition as a Discovery Procedure.” In F.A. Hayek, New Studies in Philosphy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 179–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1983. “Nobel Prize-Winning Economist.” Transcript of an oral history interview conducted in 1978 under the auspices of the Oral History Program, University Library, UCLA. Copyright 1983, Regents of the University of California.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. 1994. Hayek on Hayek: An Autobiographical Dialogue, edited by Kresge, Stephen and Wenar, Leif. London: RoutledgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, F A., ed. 1935. Collectivist Economic Planning. Clifton, NJ: Kelley, 1975.Google Scholar
Heilbroner, Robert. 1990. “Analysis and Vision in the History of Modern Economic Thought.” Journal of Economic Literature 28 (09): 10971114.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence. 1977. Knowledge and Ignorance in Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hutchison, Terence. 1988. “The Case for Falsification”. In De Marchi, Neil, ed., The Popperian Legacy in Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 169–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornai, Jànos. 1993. “Market Socialism Revisited.” In Bardhan, Pranab and Roemer, John, eds., Market Socialism. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 4268.Google Scholar
Lange, Oskar. 1938. “On the Economic Theory of Socialism.” In Lippincott, Benjamin, ed., On the Economic Theory of Socialism New York: McGraw Hill, 1966, pp. 57143.Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali. 1998. “Aspects of Realism about Economics.” Theoria 13: 301–19.Google Scholar
Mayer, Thomas. 1993. Truth versus Precision in Economics. Aldershot, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Reder, Melvin. 1999. Economics: The Culture of a Controversial Science. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Rosenberg, Alexander. 1992. Economics: Mathematical Politics or Science of Diminishing Returns? Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar