Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-dnltx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T15:17:40.877Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Customary rule-following behaviour in the work of John Stuart Mill and Alfred Marshall1

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 October 2014

MICHEL S. ZOUBOULAKIS*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, University of Thessaly, 43, Koraïs Str., 38333 Volos, Greece

Abstract

The informal institutional structure embraces the social norms and moral values of a particular society and together with the formal institutional frame, they compose the social environment. Social norms and values, congealed into customary rules of behaviour, provide a stable and enduring context to economic life that acts positively or negatively on economic activity. Despite their methodological and theoretical differences, Mill and Marshall have both suggested that individual economic decisions are fully embedded in their social environment. Thus, in order to explain the economic phenomena, from simple transaction processes to long term development, they adopted a broader perspective by including the social frame inside which economic choices are made, divulging the role of custom, yet in a quite distinctive way.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

1

Earlier and partial versions of this work were presented to the 14th ESHET Conference, Amsterdam, March 2010 and the 15th ESHET Conference, Istanbul, May 2011. The author is very grateful to the editor and the two anonymous referees of this journal for their very constructive criticisms, and recognises responsibility for the remaining deficiencies.

References

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. (2005), ‘Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth’, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Akerlof, G. A. and Shiller, J. (2009), Animal Spirits, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Arrow, K. (1974), The Limits of Organization, New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Arthur, B. (1989), ‘Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-in by Historical Events’, Economic Journal, 99 (1): 116131.Google Scholar
Beenham, L. (2005), ‘Licit and Illicit Responses to Regulation’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
Blaug, M. (1997), Economic Theory in Retrospect, 5th edn., Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. (2004), ‘Alfred Marshall's Idea of Progress and Sustainable Development’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 26 (4): 519537.Google Scholar
Caldari, K. (2007), ‘Alfred Marshall's Critical Analysis of Scientific Management’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 14 (1): 5578.Google Scholar
Casson, M. (1993), ‘Cultural Determinants of Economic Performance’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 17: 418442.Google Scholar
Coleman, J. (1990), Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Cook, S. (2013), ‘From Ancients and Moderns to Geography and Anthropology: The meaning of History in the thought of Adam Smith, Karl Marx and Alfred Marshall’, History of Political Economy, 45 (2): 311343.Google Scholar
David, P. (1985), ‘Clio and the Economics of QWERTY’, American Economic Review, 75 (2): 332337.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1989), ‘Social Norms and Economic Theory’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 3 (4): 99117.Google Scholar
Foss, N. J. (1994), ‘The Biological Analogy and the Theory of the Firm: Marshall and Monopolistic Competition’, Journal of Economic Issues, 28 (4): 11151136.Google Scholar
Foster, J. (2002), ‘Competition, Competitive Selection and Economic Evolution’, in Garrouste, P. and Ioannides, S. (eds.), Evolution and Path Dependence in Economic Ideas, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Gordon, S. (1991), The History and Philosophy of Social Science, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (1997), ‘On the Interrelations and Economic Implications of Economic, Social, Political, and Normative Factors: Reflections from Two Late Medieval Societies’, in Drobak, J. N. and Nye, J. V. (eds.), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, San Diego: Academic Press.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D. (1995), A Soaring Eagle: Alfred Marshall 1842–1924, Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Groenewegen, P. D. (2010), ‘Marshall's Treatment of Technological Change in Industry and Trade’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17 (5): 12531269.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. (1992), The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, D. and McPherson, M. (1993), ‘Taking Ethics Seriously: Economics and contemporary Moral Philosophy’, Journal of Economic Literature, 31 (3): 671731.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1993), Economics and Evolution: Bringing life back into Economics, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1997), ‘The Ubiquity of Habits and Rules’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 21 (6): 663684.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1998), ‘The approach of Institutional Economics’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36 (1): 166192.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (2001), How Economics Forgot History. The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hollander, S. (1985), The Economics of John Stuart Mill, Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Jensen, H. (1996), ‘John Stuart Mill. A Herald of Social Economics’, in O’Boyle, E. J. (ed.), Social Economics: Premises, Findings and Policies, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Jensen, H. (2001), ‘John Stuart Mill's Theories of Wealth and income distribution’, Review of Social Economy, 59 (4): 491507.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. (1924), ‘Alfred Marshall 1842–1924’, Economic Journal, 34 (135): 311372.Google Scholar
Klaes, M. (2002), ‘Some Remarks on the Place of Psychological and Social Elements in A Theory of Custom’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 61 (2): 519530.Google Scholar
Koppl, R. (2002), ‘Custom and Rules’, American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 61 (2): 531537.Google Scholar
Landes, D. (1998), The Wealth and Poverty of Nations, London: Little, Brown & Co.Google Scholar
Legé, P. (2005), ‘Les causes de la formation des “prix de marché” dans la théorie économique de J. S. Mill. Le rôle de la concurrence et de la coutume’, in Bensimon, G. (ed.), Histoire des Représentations du Marché, Paris: Michel Houdiard éditeur.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1885), Present Position of Political Economy, London: MacMillan Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1890), Principles of Economics, 8th edn 1920, London: MacMillan Press, 1985.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1897), ‘The Old Generation of Economists and the New’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 11 (2): 115135.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1898), ‘Distribution and Exchange’, Economic Journal, 8 (29): 3759.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1919), Industry and Trade, 3rd edn 1920, London: MacMillan Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1933), ‘The Mathematician as Seen by Himself’, Econometrica, 1 (1): 221222.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1836), On the Definition of Political Economy and on the Method of Investigation Proper to it, in Collected Works of J.S. Mill, vol. IV Robson, J. M. (ed.), Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1967.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1843), A System of Logic Ratiocinative and Inductive, in Collected Works of J.S. Mill, vols. VII-VIII Robson, J.M. (ed.), Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1973.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1848), Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy, Ashley, W. J. (ed.), New York: A. Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1861), Utilitarianism, in Collected Works of J.S. Mill, vol. X, Robson, J. M. (ed.), Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1865), Auguste Comte and Positivism, in Collected Works of J.S. Mill, vol. X, Robson, J. M., Toronto: Toronto University Press, 1969.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1871), Maine on Village Communities , in Collected Works of J.S. Mill, vol. XXX, Writings on India, Robson, J. M., Moir, M. and Moir, Z. (eds.), Toronto, London: University of Toronto Press and Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1990.Google Scholar
Nakano, T. (2007), ‘Alfred Marshall's Economic Nationalism’, Nations and Nationalism, 13 (1): 5776.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (2005a), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (2005b), ‘Institutions and performance of economies over time’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht: Springer.Google Scholar
Opocher, A. (2010), ‘The Future of the Working Classes: A Comparison between J.S. Mill and A. Marshall’, European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 17 (2): 229253.Google Scholar
Radner, R. (1992), ‘Hierarchy: The Economics of Managing’, Journal of Economic Literature, 30 (5): 13821415.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, T. (2003), Marshall's Evolutionary Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Raffaelli, T., Becattini, G. and Dardi, M. (2006), The Elgar Companion to Alfred Marshall, Cheltenham: E. Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlicht, E. (1998), On Custom in the Economy, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Sherman, J. H. (1928), ‘Some Observations on Custom in Price Phenomena’, American Economic Review, 18 (4): 663669.Google Scholar
Smith, A. (1776), An Inquiry into the Causes and Nature of the Wealth of Nations, Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press, 1976.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, B. (1991), ‘Alfred Marshall on Economic Biology’, Review of Political Economy, 3 (1): 114.Google Scholar
Vanberg, V. (1993), ‘Rational Choice, Rule-following and Institutions’, in Maki, U., Gustafsson, B. and Knudsen, T. (eds.), Rationality, Institutions and Economic Methodology, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1904), ‘L’objectivité de la Connaissance dans les Sciences et la Politique Sociales’, in Freund, J. (ed.), Essais sur la Théorie de la Science, Paris: Plon, 1965.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1922), Economy and Society, vol. Roth, I. G. and Wittich, C. (eds.), Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1978.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Zouboulakis, M. S. (1993), La Science économique à la Recherche de ses Fondements. La tradition épistémologique Ricardienne, 1826–1891, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France.Google Scholar
Zouboulakis, M. S. (2014), Varieties of Economic Rationality. From Adam Smith to Contemporary Behavioural and Evolutionary Economics, London: Routledge.Google Scholar