Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-t5pn6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T02:49:32.208Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

On the convergence of evolution processes with time-varying mutations and local interaction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 July 2016

Hsiao-Chi Chen*
Affiliation:
National Taipei University
Yunshyoung Chow*
Affiliation:
Academia Sinica
*
Postal address: Department of Economics, National Taipei University, 67, Section 3, Ming-Shen E. Road, Taipei 104, Taiwan, ROC. Email address: hchen@mail.ntpu.edu.tw
∗∗ Postal address: Institute of Mathematics, Academia Sinica, Taipei 115, Taiwan, ROC.

Abstract

This paper analyzes players’ long-run behavior in an evolutionary model with time-varying mutations under both uniform and local interaction rules. It is shown that a risk-dominant Nash equilibrium in a 2 × 2 coordination game would emerge as the long-run equilibrium if and only if mutation rates do not decrease to zero too fast under both interaction methods. The convergence rates of the dynamic system under both interaction rules are also derived. We find that the dynamic system with local matching may not converge faster than that with uniform matching.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
Copyright © Applied Probability Trust 2001 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Anderlini, L., and Ianni, A. (1996). Path dependence and learning from neighbors. Games Econ. Behavior 13, 141177.Google Scholar
Bergin, J., and Lipman, B. L. (1996). Evolution with state-dependent mutations. Econometrica 64, 943956.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K., and Samuelson, L. (1997). Muddling through: noisy equilibrium selection. J. Econ. Theory 74, 235265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, L. (1995). How noise matters. Preprint, Cornell University.Google Scholar
Chiang, T. S., and Chow, Y. (1989). A limit theorem for a class of inhomogeneous Markov processes. Ann. Prob. 17, 14831502.Google Scholar
Chiang, T. S., and Chow, Y. (1998). Asymptotic behavior of some linear differential systems. J. Differential Eqns 144, 321352.Google Scholar
Connors, D. P., and Kumar, P. R. (1988). Balance of recurrence order in time-inhomogeneous Markov chains with applications to simulated annealing. Prob. Eng. Inf. Sci. 2, 157184.Google Scholar
Ellison, G. (1993). Learning, local interaction, and coordination. Econometrica 61, 10471071.Google Scholar
Foster, D., and Young, P. (1990). Stochastic evolutionary game dynamics. Theoret. Popn Biol. 38, 219232.Google Scholar
Freidlin, M. I., and Wentzell, A. D. (1984). Random Perturbations of Dynamical Systems. Springer, New York.Google Scholar
Geman, D., and Geman, S. (1984). Stochastic relaxation, Gibbs distributions, and the Bayesian restoration of images. IEEE Trans. Pattern Anal. Mach. Intelligence 6, 721741.Google Scholar
Gidas, B. (1985). Global optimization via the Langevin equation. In Proc. 24th IEEE Conf. Decision and Control, Fort Lauderdale, Florida, pp. 774778.Google Scholar
Hajek, B. (1988). Cooling schedules for optimal annealing. Math. Operat. Res. 13, 311329.Google Scholar
Hwang, C. R., and Sheu, S. J. (1992). Singular perturbed Markov chains and exact behaviors of simulated annealing processes. J. Theoret. Prob. 5, 223249.Google Scholar
Kandori, M. G., Mailath, G., and Rob, R. (1993). Learning, mutation, and long-run equilibria in games. Econometrica 61, 2956.Google Scholar
Kirkpatrick, S., Gelatt, C., and Vecchi, M. (1983). Optimization by simulated annealing. Science 220, 671680.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Robles, J. (1998). Evolution with changing mutation rates. J. Econ. Theory 79, 207223.Google Scholar
Sandholm, W. H., and Pauzner, A. (1998). Evolution, population growth, and history dependence. Games Econ. Behavior 22, 84120.Google Scholar
Young, P. (1993). The evolution of conventions. Econometrica 61, 5784.Google Scholar