Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-sxzjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T00:15:37.400Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

FINDING THE BRITISH GOOGLE: RELAXING THE PROHIBITION OF DUAL-CLASS STOCK FROM THE PREMIUM-TIER OF THE LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 June 2020

Abstract

There is a dearth of British tech-companies listing on the London Stock Exchange (LSE), and the LSE lacks a large, innovative tech-company such as Google. The UK Government, concerned as to the loss of UK tech-companies to foreign acquirors, views the encouragement of UK tech-firm listings as a policy priority. Dual-class stock, currently prohibited from the LSE Main Market's premium-tier, allows founders to list their firms, and retain majority-control, while holding significantly less of the cash-flow rights in the company. This article will broach the potential for dual-class stock to attract UK tech-company listings, and explore the benefits that dual-class stock can engender for UK tech-companies and their public shareholders. The risks of dual-class structures will also be discussed, but it will be shown that in a UK regulatory context, in relation to high-growth tech-companies, the risks may not be as severe as presumed, and easily moderated through judicious controls.

Type
Articles
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge Law Journal and Contributors 2020

I. Introduction

The tech-industry loves an acronym. Google is a constituent of “GAFA”, a cabal of four US tech-company behemoths – Google,Footnote 1 Apple, Facebook and Amazon. The Chinese equivalent is “BATX” – Baidu, Alibaba, Tencent and Xiaomi. These companies represent “Big Tech” – a term referring to the current trend of major tech-companies with inordinate market, public and societal influence.Footnote 2 As of October 2019, the total market capitalisation of the eight companies was nearly $4.4 trillion,Footnote 3 greater than the GDP of all but the largest three or four world economies. Perhaps more noteworthy is the manner in which such companies dominate the technology scene worldwide, consistently developing new technologies, software and hardware, and rampantly acquiring other innovative businesses. Furthermore, all of these companies are publicly-listed, giving them access to a source of equity capital for expansion and research and development (R&D), as well as allowing public shareholders to participate in their success and growth.Footnote 4

The UK Government has identified that innovation and investment in R&D are critical to the future competitiveness and growth of the UK economy,Footnote 5 and, to that end, has pinpointed attracting tech-firms to the London Stock Exchange (LSE) as a policy priority.Footnote 6 However, the search for a “British Google” has proved elusive. Although numerous UK “unicorns”, that is, private, independent start-ups valued at over $1 billion, exist,Footnote 7 only two tech-companies have been consistent members of the FTSE-100Footnote 8 since the dotcom bubble burst in the early 2000s.Footnote 9 Those two companies, Micro Focus plc. and Sage Group plc., were first listed in the 1980s, further highlighting the dearth of new, large tech-companies listing on the LSE.

Many factors could explain the reluctance of UK tech-company founders to list their companies, but one aspect is the fear of losing control of the company as a result of the shares becoming dispersed amongst public investors upon the company's initial public offering (IPO). Interestingly, six of the eight GAFA and BATX companies (and all of those that have listed in the twenty-first century) have utilised mechanisms that allow the founders to continue to control the composition of the board of directors and insulate the firm from takeovers (unless the founders consent) notwithstanding a dispersion of the equity upon IPO. The most common mechanism implemented is dual-class stock.Footnote 10 The use of dual-class stock allows the founders to hold shares to which are attached enhanced “voting rights” (rights to vote on shareholders’ resolutions, and therefore influence decision-making), while the public shareholders own shares which enjoy lesser, or no, voting rights. A founder is therefore able to retain voting-control of the relevant company, while holding a minority of the equity or “cash-flow rights” (rights to share in the profits of the company, through dividends and other distributions). Google is a case-in-point – the founders, Larry Page and Sergey Brin, as of 31 December 2018, owned 51% of the voting rights of the company, but only 11.3% of the cash-flow rights.Footnote 11 In the UK, on the most prestigious tier of the LSE's Main Market – the premium-tier – dual-class stock is prohibited, and the concept of one-share-one-vote (OSOV) is effectively prescribed. A company with the capital structure of Google would not be admitted to a listing on the premium-tier.

Dual-class capitalisation has been described in the US as “the most important issue in corporate governance today”,Footnote 12 and, accordingly, the literature in the US is saturated with academic studies evaluating the merits of dual-class stock. However, surprisingly, there has been very little academic discussion of the topic in the UK, even though, at one time, long before the redesignation of the tiers of the Main Market into the standard-tier and the premium-tier, dual-class firms were not rare on the LSE, with bastions of the city such as Marks & Spencer, ITV, Whitbread, Shell, Burton Group, Ranks and House of Fraser adopting the structure.Footnote 13 The subject is especially topical, with the Financial Conduct Authority (FCA)Footnote 14 and the UK GovernmentFootnote 15 recognising the potential for dual-class stock to support long-term company performance and investment in tech-companies. Even more recently, speculation has been rife that the UK Government is exploring the use of dual-class stock as a means to attract the listing of tech start-ups on the LSE.Footnote 16 A normative assessment of dual-class stock from a UK perspective is long overdue.

This article will argue that the rules on dual-class stock should be liberalised in order to benefit the UK tech-industry specifically.Footnote 17 In the first section of this article, the dearth of UK tech-company listings on the LSE will be discussed. The next section will outline the journeys taken by UK tech-companies as alternatives to listing. The third section will discuss the potential for dual-class structure to promote listings. The final sections of this article will weigh the benefits that dual-class structure can bring to the success of high-growth tech-companies, against the potential risks to public shareholders. However, it will be argued that the UK's regulatory and market environment mitigates the most extreme risks, and a relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition of dual-class stock could give the UK's tech-industry the boost that it needs.

II. The Shortage of High-Growth Tech-Companies on the LSE

The UK has been, and continues to be, a hotbed for science and technology companies. As of mid-2019, the UK was home to 17 tech unicorns.Footnote 18 However, the emergence of large, privately-owned tech-companies has not been reflected in the publicly-listed sphere. UK technology IPOs on the LSE have lagged behind the US, with firms from “new economy”Footnote 19 industries listing on the LSE between 2007 and 2017 making-up only 14% of total market capitalisation, compared with 60% and 47% on NASDAQ and the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE), respectively.Footnote 20

Attracting tech-firms to the LSE is a policy objective in the UK,Footnote 21 for two main reasons. First, although a comprehensive study of the benefits of equity markets is beyond the scope of this paper, equity can provide a vital source of financing for tech-companies. For instance, innovative tech-companies with long product-cycles may struggle to procure loan finance without a robust profits history. In 2016, 68% of US IPOs involved pre-profit companies, rising to 75% and 92% of technology and biotechnology listings, respectively,Footnote 22 perhaps as a result of those companies lacking access to debt funding. Also, tech-companies seeking finance for long-term, uncertain projects may be shunned by the debt markets.Footnote 23 As such, it has been found that R&D spending can be throttled without access to the equity markets.Footnote 24 External equity investment becomes essential for those pre-profit firms seeking to commercialise R&D.Footnote 25 Strong equity markets, and readily available sources of equity financing for tech-firms, can also have consequential benefits, encouraging innovation, productivity and growth in the economy generally.Footnote 26 Job creation will also be promoted, and the tech-sector is predicted to become one of the largest providers of employment in the UK.Footnote 27 Second, UK individuals, or retail investors, can participate in the growth and success of tech-companies if they are listed.Footnote 28 In contrast, subject to exceptions,Footnote 29 private companies are not easily able to offer securities to the general public.Footnote 30 Although individuals could garner indirect exposure to such companies through their investments in pension plans, insurance products and investment funds, those institutional investors will desire to allocate significant funds to more liquid, publicly-listed investments.Footnote 31 Furthermore, although such institutional investors can invest in tech-companies listed on other exchanges (and will actively seek global diversification), a significant proportion of investments by UK funds remains in the UK,Footnote 32 and, therefore, policy-makers are seeking methods to promote the listing of UK tech-companies on the LSE specifically.

III. What's Happening to UK Tech-Companies?

If UK tech-companies are not listing on the LSE, it begs the question as to how they are operating and raising finance? It is possible that UK tech-companies are able to generate the equity financing that they require without having to resort to the public markets. Traditionally, venture capital (VC) funds have privately financed, through minority investments, new or expanding businesses. The distinction between VC and private equity (which traditionally involves a buy-out of the target entity) is beginning to blur, though, with large funds, such as Softbank, making huge VC investments in more mature tech-companies,Footnote 33 and traditional private equity houses eschewing their usual buy-out strategies in favour of minority investments.Footnote 34 However, even though VC funding for companies that have moved beyond the start-up phase into a high-growth phase (so called “late-stage” funding) has recently increased in the UK, which dominates the European market, it generally lags well behind the levels observed in the US.Footnote 35 Accordingly, in the UK, many tech-companies soon attain a size that is beyond further VC funding,Footnote 36 and the FCA has identified a gap in available financing in the “scale-up” phase during which technology start-ups seek to emerge as large, established businesses.Footnote 37 Although, as above, the UK is home to a number of private company “unicorns”, it has been suggested that the UK, in fact, underperforms in their creation and significantly trails the US and China.Footnote 38

Even for those UK tech-companies that do survive and become established businesses, it seems that the creation of enduring unicorns is the exception rather than the rule. As shown in Table 1, in the last five years, numerous large UK tech-companies, two of which were unicorns and the others were well on their way to becoming unicorns, have been acquired by foreign purchasers. UK tech-companies are disproportionately the subject of mergers and acquisitions (M&A) activity compared with their international peers.Footnote 39

Table 1 Large (over £100m) acquisitions of UK private technology companies between 2014 and mid-2019

bn, billion; m, million. Sources: ONS, “Mergers and Acquisitions Involving UK Companies” (publications from Q3 2014 to Q2 2019); A. Sword, “6 of the Biggest UK Tech Acquisitions by Overseas Giants”, C.B.R., 18 July 2016, available at https://www.cbronline.com/internet-of-things/6-of-the-biggest-uk-tech-acquisitions-by-overseas-giants-4952343/; A. Hern, “Is the Global Desire to Buy British a Bad Thing for UK Tech Firms?”, The Guardian, 16 December 2017, available at https://www.theguardian.com/business/2017/dec/16/uk-tech-companies-bought-by-overseas-giants-apple-shazam.

Therefore, only a handful of UK tech-companies are developing into large, mature businesses and a great number that do are being bought-out by foreign competitors or investment funds. This is concerning from a policy perspective, since UK investors will not be able to share in the success of those firms that are bought-out, and, although such acquisitions may not be associated with the wholesale movement of business abroad, they could see the progressive migration of talent and operations to the foreign jurisdiction. Just as concerning is that, as shown in Table 2, many of those large UK tech-firms that do eventually list in the UK are also subsequently bought-out by foreign acquirors. Either way, it does not appear that the UK public equity markets are providing a stable, long-term home for UK tech-companies.

Table 2 Large (over £100m) foreign buy-outs of UK-listed technology companies between 2014 and mid-2019

bn, billion; m, million. Sources: ONS, “Mergers and Acquisitions Involving UK Companies” (publications from Q3 2014 to Q2 2019); J. Kollewe, “UK Cybersecurity Firm Sophos Agrees £3.1bn Takeover”, The Guardian, 14 October 2019, available at https://www.theguardian.com/business/2019/oct/14/uk-cybersecurity-sophos-takeover-thoma-bravo.

IV. Loss of Control as a Factor in Eschewing Flotations

If the UK regulators aspire to encourage more UK tech-firms to list on the LSE, a reasonable starting point is to question why such companies are disproportionately susceptible to foreign buy-outs compared to their US brethren. The answer may lie in examining the consequences of listing in the UK.

The Main Market of the LSE is split into two tiers, and, in 2010, those tiers were redesignated the premium-tier, to which greater corporate governance standards are applied, and the, lower, standard-tier.Footnote 40 After the redesignation, non-voting shares were omitted from the premium-tier. In 2014, in response to a number of high-profile abuses by controlling shareholders,Footnote 41 the Listing Rules sourcebook as published by the FCA exercising its primary market functions (the Listing Rules) was further amended, introducing two new “Premium Listing Principles” to which premium-listed companies would be required to adhere. Essentially the new principles prescribed pure-OSOV on the premium-tier by requiring (i) all equity shares in a class to carry an equal number of votes,Footnote 42 and (ii) the aggregate voting rights of each class of premium-listed shares to be broadly proportionate to the relative equity interests of each class in the company.Footnote 43 In effect, other than inferior-voting preference shares where the shareholders are compensated for a lack of voting rights with enhanced dividend or distribution rights,Footnote 44 the FCA formally proscribed the premium listing of classes of shares where the voting rights attached to such shares are disproportionate to their cash-flow rights. From a strict reading of the Premium Listing Principles, a structure where the enhanced-voting shares (superior shares) are unlisted, and the inferior-voting shares (inferior shares) are premium-listed would not be prohibited. However, where, under the Listing Rules, matters pertaining to premium-listed companies are required to be decided by shareholder-vote, those matters must be approved by a resolution of the holders of shares that have been admitted to a premium listing.Footnote 45 For those matters, the control to which the superior shareholders aspire will be undermined. In any case, notwithstanding the wording of the Premium Listing Principles, it is unlikely that the FCA would admit a firm's inferior shares to the premium-tier where the superior shares are unlisted, since this would deviate from the spirit of the relevant Premium Listing Principles, the purpose of which is to “prevent artificial structures involving multiple classes with different voting powers, which are designed to allow control to rest with a small group of shareholders”.Footnote 46 Even prior to the division of the Main Market into two tiers, and the introduction of the 2014 Premium Listing Principles, since the 1960s, in response to pressure from powerful institutional investors, the LSE had discouraged the quotation of inferior shares, and indicated that it would use its discretionary powers to refuse applications to list inferior shares on its market in the majority of cases.Footnote 47 A combination of the LSE's informal prohibition and institutional investor distaste for dual-class stock (increasing the cost of equity capital for dual-class companies) led to most UK-listed dual-class firms unifying their share structures into OSOV well before the formal premium-tier prohibition of dual-class stock was implemented.Footnote 48

A OSOV-listing on the premium-tier could create complications for a founder. Upon IPO, as the founder sells-down its equity, or dilutes its equity through the issuance of further shares, the founder will see the proportion of its voting rights in the company decline. If the founder's share of the voting rights falls below a majority, for a company incorporated in England and Wales, the founder will no longer possess the ability to determine the composition of the board of directors.Footnote 49 Since, generally, the power to appoint the company's management team will reside with the board,Footnote 50 the loss of majority-control exposes management. If the founder is part of the management team, the founder loses its protected position and could, therefore, be indirectly dismissed from running the company by shareholders holding a majority of the votes. The firm, and, therefore, management, also becomes exposed to a third-party takeover which the founder can no longer block.

A founder could list on the premium-tier and retain voting-control, resulting in a “OSOV controlling shareholder firm”, thereby maintaining its protected position in leading the company. However, this entails other compromises. In order to retain more than 50% of the voting rights, the founder will have to limit both the crystallisation of his/her investment in the company through the sale of shares, and the generation of equity funding for company growth through issuing shares. The founder either lists and loses control, or lists and retains control but forsakes the very reasons for listing in the first place. Milo Minderbinder would struggle to formulate such a clear-cut “catch-22”.Footnote 51

Almost as a deus ex machina, the catch-22 scenario could be solved if the adoption of dual-class stock were permitted on the premium-tier. A founder could retain superior shares, while issuing inferior shares to the public, thereby maintaining control of the company by holding a majority of the voting rights, while still crystallising significant wealth by selling equity in the company. Issuances of further equity, either at IPO or subsequently, can also be engineered through the sale of newly created inferior shares, thereby limiting the dilution of the founder's voting rights. In addition, once listed, a founder holding superior shares can block takeovers, negating concerns that a flotation could result in the firm subsequently being acquired and the founder removed from running the firm. Dual-class stock would, therefore, also attenuate the loss of listed tech-firms from the Main Market.

It should be noted that dual-class stock is only prohibited from the premium-tier. As a matter of corporate law, companies have complete freedom to adopt dual-class structures,Footnote 52 and even in the listed-company sphere, dual-class stock listings are permitted on the Alternative Investment Market (AIM) and the Main Market's standard-tier. However, AIM was established for smaller, growing companies,Footnote 53 with less onerous listing requirements, and therefore embraces an investor-base reflective of the types of companies that list on the exchange. For a unicorn, a growing mid-stage tech-company with high funding requirements, or, indeed, the British Google, it is unlikely that AIM would represent a suitable market to promote the levels of liquidity or raise the levels of finance required.

With respect to the standard-tier, an inferiority-complex pervades. More stringent admission requirements apply to the premium-tier, lending it greater prestige. The stronger corporate governance qualities ascribed to the premium-tier beget greater confidence in the market, attracting superior levels of investment by a larger number of sophisticated investors. As a result, companies issuing listed shares (“issuers”) are themselves attracted to the premium-tier where they can draw greater levels of investment at, potentially, a better price than compared to the standard-tier. Advisers often caution clients against choosing the standard-tier for listing.Footnote 54 Even the FCA has admitted that a standard-listing is often considered unattractive for many potential issuers, with the very name connoting “second-best” status.Footnote 55 One may question whether the “unattractiveness” of the standard-tier could be overcome by the “attractiveness” of a high-quality dual-class share issuer. After all, a sophisticated institutional investor is unlikely to shoot-itself-in-the-foot and pass-up a “hot” IPO merely due to the second-rate perception attached to the “standard-tier” moniker. However, many of the key continuing corporate governance requirements attached to a premium-, but not standard-, listing are exactly the types of protections that an institutional investor would regard as essential prior to investing in dual-class shares in the UK. For example, premium-tier companies are subject to regulations surrounding related-party transactions,Footnote 56 and controlling shareholders of such companies must contractually restrict certain of their actions.Footnote 57 The lower corporate governance standards of a standard-listed company would most likely be even more of a deterrent to investors where the company is issuing dual-class shares. The relevant issuer could voluntarily adopt equivalent protections, but such protections would not be subject to regulatory oversight, and therefore likely to be contractual or implemented through the constitutional documents of the issuer. Investors would be required to examine and analyse the relevant contractual and constitutional provisions themselves to ensure equivalence to premium-tier regulatory requirements – the appetite of investors to make such determinations on a case-by-case basis can be doubted, and it has been suggested that the ability of investors to assess more granular elements of a company's bespoke corporate governance qualities accurately is limited.Footnote 58

A founder could be further discouraged from a standard-listing since such firms are excluded from the FTSE UK Index Series.Footnote 59 Certain funds passively track the indices, slavishly only investing in index constituents on a weighted-basis,Footnote 60 and even some active funds could be considered “closet-indexers”Footnote 61 in that they are either mandated to only invest in specific indices, or they track an index as a hedging strategy where the performance of the relevant fund manager is assessed against the index.Footnote 62 As a consequence of such demand, index-inclusion can be associated with greater liquidity and higher share prices.Footnote 63 If a standard-tier firm were to grow to a size that would otherwise be worthy of index-inclusion, it would not be able to take advantage of the associated benefits. Pertinently, excluding preference shares, there has not been a dual-class share IPO on the standard-tier since the redesignation of the Main Market into premium- and standard-tiers, and the exclusion of non-voting stock from the premium-tier in 2010. Although, three companies, Schroders plc. (Schroders), Hansa Investment Company Limited (Hansa), and Daily Mail & General Trust plc. (Daily Mail), do have inferior shares listed on the standard-tier,Footnote 64 all three were long-time members of the Main Market's former “primary-tier” and found their inferior shares downgraded to the standard-tier upon the prohibition of non-voting stock from the premium-tier becoming effective. The superior shares of Schroders and Hansa continue to be premium-listed, and those of Daily Mail were never listed. The companies’ inferior shares are subject to standard-listings not through choice, but as a result of regulatory exigencies. Given the rise in recent years of large tech-firms listing in the US with dual-class structure,Footnote 65 the rarity of firms taking advantage of dual-class stock on the standard-tier is indicative of the low regard in which the segment is held by issuers.

A UK tech-firm could also adopt dual-class structure by listing on a foreign exchange such as NASDQ or the NYSE. However, in such a case, the foreign exchange and foreign-based advisers will extract the majority of the financial benefits accruing to the listing, which would presumably undermine some of the FCA's policy objectives. Additionally, as described above, a foreign listing would make it more difficult for UK-based retail investors to share in the growth of the relevant company.Footnote 66 In any case, it does not appear that UK tech-firms are racing towards the US exchanges.Footnote 67 A number of factors could explain the reticence, including the fact that the success of the listing may be hindered by an unfamiliarity in the foreign market with the brand and products of the UK company, and the firm will also not be able to leverage the publicity of the listing into better sales in its main product-market.Footnote 68 Higher listing costs, with requirements to instruct foreign as well as local advisers and to ensure that accounts are compatible with the foreign jurisdiction's requirements, may also deter foreign listings,Footnote 69 as may a fear of an unfamiliar litigious culture and increased regulatory costs in the foreign jurisdiction.Footnote 70 The provenance of the pre-IPO investors can also influence the listing jurisdiction, with a bias towards UK listings by UK-based investors.Footnote 71

In summary, there could be many reasons why a particular UK tech-company eschews a UK flotation of its stock, including a distaste for increased regulatory oversight and transparency, but the catch-22 described above will play heavily on the mind of the founder. Control is key. A founder will lose control upon a OSOV-listing if it desires substantially to diversify wealth and grow the firm. Even in circumstances where a founder sells its private company to a third-party, if the acquiror shares a similar vision to the founder, and has a track-record for giving businesses the space to grow long term, the founder may be content to cede voting-control to the acquiror in return for a high purchase price, the award of a non-trivial stake in the acquiror, and a degree of autonomy in running the business. The attractions in betting on a known quantity are obvious compared to being exposed to a disparate, ever-changing group of public shareholders. Dual-class stock, on the other hand, enables founders to pursue the benefits of a listing while retaining control, evidenced by the rising numbers of such listings in the US.Footnote 72

V. How Dual-Class Share Structure Could Benefit UK Tech-Firms

The lure of dual-class stock does not solely lie in its potential to encourage the listing of tech-firms on the LSE. The adoption of the structure by an issuer can also engender separate benefits for the firm itself and its public shareholders. In this section, the benefits of dual-class stock from the perspective of tech-companies will be elucidated. It is assumed for the purposes of this article that a controller or controllers will hold a majority of the voting rights in the relevant dual-class company. Taking the US as an example, if dual-class firms became common on the premium-tier, the prospect for numerous dispersed-ownership, dual-class firms would be vanishingly small.Footnote 73

At IPO, the founders of Google stated, “we have set up a corporate structure that will make it harder for outside parties to take over or influence Google. This structure will also make it easier for our management team to follow the long term, innovative approach emphasized earlier”.Footnote 74 The enabling of taking a long-term approach to business has been oft-cited by academics and regulators alike as a benefit attached to the adoption of dual-class stock.Footnote 75 With control in the hands of the superior shareholders, assuming that the superior shareholders themselves have a long-term outlook, the management team can operate the business without fear that they may be removed if short-term metrics are not positive.Footnote 76 Furthermore, the market for corporate control,Footnote 77 pursuant to which moribund short-term share price can lead to predatory takeover offers by third-party acquirors, is largely eroded, since a takeover can only proceed with the consent of the superior shareholders. In contrast, with a robust market for corporate control, management will be at the behest of those shareholders who may make misjudgments in accepting predatory takeover offers that are not in the best interests of those shareholders or the firm,Footnote 78 which can cause management to be overly preoccupied with short-term share price rather than the long-term interests of the company.Footnote 79 Whether public shareholders are in fact overall short-term oriented is beyond the scope of this article, but studies have shown that even the mere perception that the markets are short-termist can influence the behaviour of management,Footnote 80 and those shareholders with short-term proclivities can have a disproportionate impact on managerial behaviour due to the high turnover of stock generated by their activities.Footnote 81 With dual-class stock, management will be less likely to invest in projects with observable payoffs that will produce lower returns than projects that are more challenging to monitor, or to employ costly signalling devices such as dividend payments, share buy-backs or leverage to inform outsiders that performance is robust where it is otherwise difficult to monitor.Footnote 82

The ability to take a long-term approach can particularly benefit tech-companies. They are often involved in product innovation, and, especially in their early, growth-phase years, seek success through the exploitation of product-cycles, which can increase R&D investment at the expense of short-term profits.Footnote 83 If founders are under pressure from equity market investors to maintain strong short-term profits and distributions, the ability of the founder to pursue such product-cycles will be diminished.Footnote 84 For example, where a firm has a choice between projects with high or low near-term uncertainty, even if the project with high near-term uncertainty will be more profitable in the long term, with a OSOV dispersed-ownership firm, management may be more likely to pursue the less profitable project. Outside shareholders take longer to determine the possible success of projects with high near-term uncertainty, valuing such products less highly, all things being equal, and, as such, management requires insulation from removal, while share price may be undervalued, in order to pursue the more valuable project.Footnote 85 The scenario is likely to occur in industries requiring high R&D investment, and, therefore, those industries can benefit from the utilisation of dual-class stock.Footnote 86

Innovative tech-firms, such a Google and Facebook, also require the investment of firm-specific capital by management and employees. Managers will be more likely to invest in firm-specific human capital, if they are comfortable that their positions are secure in the long term.Footnote 87 The long-term commitment of the controller can also encourage other employees to invest in the firm-specific human capital so essential in companies with high asset-specificity such as high technology industries; the adoption of long-term projects by companies in such industries would give employees comfort that the company is committed to long-term relationships with those employees.Footnote 88 For example, in justifying the company's dual-class structure, Google's founders, in their 2011 Founders’ Letter to Investors, stated: “Our colleagues will be able to trust that they themselves and their labors of hard work, love and creativity will be well cared for by a company focused on stability and the long term.”Footnote 89 The long-term value of intangible assets and human resources may be misjudged by public shareholders,Footnote 90 and commentators have speculated that innovation is promoted in companies where there is greater tolerance of short-term moribund share performance.Footnote 91 Additionally, tech-companies often need to develop other important long-term stakeholder relationships, such as with vital customers, suppliers or partners. A reputation for a long-term approach, which is often associated with controlling shareholder companies,Footnote 92 may send a message to potential contracting parties that the company's management can be trusted since they can be assumed to have a desire to manufacture long-lasting contractual relationshipsFootnote 93; dual-class stock can promote such a reputation and therefore assist in ingraining long-term stakeholder relationships.Footnote 94 Effectively, management insulation creates a permissive environment in which a tech-company can take a long-term view to its business.

The support of long-termism through management insulation is also a quality of OSOV controlling shareholder-structures,Footnote 95 but, even so, if dual-class stock encourages the listing of companies with controllers that would not otherwise list with OSOV-structure (due to the compromises that must be made),Footnote 96 the structure should be promoted. Furthermore, the propensity to take a long-term approach may be amplified with dual-class stock since the controller, if it holds a disproportionately small level of cash-flow rights, will be less concerned by any short-term personal changes in net-worth correlating with share price fluctuations. With OSOV, share price is apposite if the controlling shareholder intends to sell-down equity, but with dual-class stock, it is likely that the controller will already have disposed of a substantial proportion of its equity. Of course, if the market is indeed overall short-term oriented, inferior share price may decline if short-term performance is poor, particularly if long-term value is not easily observable, but a diversified superior shareholder controller will be able to stay the course, and those inferior shareholders who are also long-term oriented and continue on the journey with the controller will be able to enjoy those long-term profits along with the controller.

Another benefit of dual-class stock for tech-companies, very much related to the concept of long-termism, is that it can support risk-taking. With OSOV dispersed-ownership firms, a regulatory prioritisation of robust monitoring (resulting in various mechanisms, such as independent directors, being implemented to substitute for a lack of scrutiny by dispersed-shareholders) has been accused of blunting innovation in favour of curtailing the excesses of unfettered management.Footnote 97 Significantly, calculated risk-taking can be critical to the success of growth-phase tech-companies desiring to develop transformational and disruptive technologies.Footnote 98 Two aspects of dual-class structure can encourage greater risk-taking and innovation, that could benefit all the shareholders in the company.

First, even though the corporate governance requirements that seemingly inhibit risk-taking will still apply to premium-listed dual-class firms, their impact on the controller's decision-making (and risk-taking) will be reduced where the management team is insulated.Footnote 99 The effectiveness of independent directors,Footnote 100 and the UK Corporate Governance Code (UK CGC),Footnote 101 in controlling shareholder firms generally is lessened. This can be viewed negatively in not constraining the acts of controllers, but it can also be viewed positively by giving controllers greater freedom to take risks.

Second, dual-class structure can enhance risk-taking from the perspective of the economic incentives of the controller. In a OSOV dispersed-ownership firm, management will be cautious in gambling on a risky, although potentially highly profitable, project if their employment could be imperilled by the project resulting in failure. Even in a OSOV controlling shareholder firm, where management is insulated from outside shareholders, management may still exercise caution, since a single large failure could result in a sizeable diminishment in wealth of the controller, to whom they owe their employment (or the controller itself will be part of management).Footnote 102 This wealth consideration in fact seems to dominate over outside shareholder insulation, since OSOV controlling shareholder firms have been shown to be more, rather than less, risk-averse than OSOV dispersed-ownership firms.Footnote 103 In contrast, with dual-class stock where the founder has disposed of substantial equity, the managers are still insulated from public shareholders by the controller's voting-power, but are also less pre-disposed to considering the wealth effects of individual decisions since they will affect the founder less than would have been the case if it had retained a proportionate level of cash-flow rights. As such, so long as the single risk does not pose a seismic or terminal threat to the health of the company, by making many calculated risks over a long period of time, a talented founder can overcome the loss-aversion to individual gambles by assessing the possibility of more “winners” than “losers” over time.Footnote 104 Hence, empirically, firms adopting dual-class stock, concurrently with the controller selling down substantial equity, have been found to be associated with greater risk-taking which was beneficial to firm-wealth and all shareholders.Footnote 105

Inferior shareholders in dual-class firms can also garner significant benefits from a talented founder being “bonded” to the firm.Footnote 106 If the controller has already divested of the majority of its equity, it has more to lose than gain by selling its shares, since the controller will lose the pecuniary and non-pecuniary benefits that it accrues from being in controlFootnote 107 in return for only the price of a sliver of equity.Footnote 108 The strength of the bond would be additionally reinforced in the UK, where takeover regulations could make the superior shares somewhat illiquid (not easily sold to generate cash) – a possible purchaser of shares may be deterred from acquiring the superior shares, since an acquisition of 30% or more of the voting rights would require the bidder to make an offer for all the shares in the company under the UK's mandatory bid rules.Footnote 109 Accordingly, a purchaser not wishing to obtain control of the company (but wishing to acquire a significant equity stake) would be more likely to acquire inferior shares and avoid triggering the mandatory bid requirement. Additionally, much in the same way as a reputation for taking a long-term approach can ingrain stakeholder relationships,Footnote 110 the attachment of a respected founder to a business can generate trust by, and signal quality to, customers and other stakeholders.Footnote 111

In fact, the controller-bonding hypothesis could be a crucial benefit for inferior shareholders in tech-firms where the vision of the founder is fundamental to the success of the company. Inferior shareholders can garner significant long-term benefits by the founder being bonded to the firm and incentivised to develop the firm's vision over the long-run. The way in which the company differentiates itself from the rest of the market and the founder's self-perceived ability to outperform the market in the long term has been described as the founder's “idiosyncratic vision”.Footnote 112 A juxtaposition can be drawn between the decade-and-a-half of financial problems that beset Apple, a OSOV-firm, after one of the founders, Steve Jobs, left in 1985 following a dispute with the board,Footnote 113 and the continued incumbency of Mark Zuckerberg at Facebook, a dual-class firm, in the face of opposition from the board and shareholders to the acquisition of Instagram, Inc. for $1 billion in 2012 (which, by 2018, was valued at $35 billion).Footnote 114

Of course, if the relevant founder is not talented, given the wide scope granted to him/her through dual-class stock to run the business, the bonding effect could, instead, be viewed negatively.Footnote 115 However, with dual-class stock, the faith that the public investors possess in the relevant founder is critical. It is less likely that a dual-class IPO of a firm will be successful if potential investors do not have faith in the talents and ability of the superior shareholders. It is acknowledged that, in certain cases, investors may face a “Hobson's Choice”,Footnote 116 where, in a competitive market between fund managers, investors will be reticent to miss-out on an investment in a company with potentially excellent growth prospects,Footnote 117 especially in a generally weak or small market for IPOs.Footnote 118 However, it is difficult to foresee that an IPO of a tech-firm will proceed with dual-class structure if the investors do not have at least a modicum of conviction in the abilities of the founder. For example, although the decision by The We Company (WeWork) to abandon its IPO on short-notice will have been based partly upon misgivings about the company's business plan and finances, an underlying distrust of the founder's abilities was exposed when, soon after, it was announced that the founder would resign as CEO and potentially relinquish his superior shares.Footnote 119 Similarly, it is unlikely that Uber would have countenanced a listing prior to the removal of Travis Kalanick, whose behaviour had been very publicly denounced, as CEO, and unification of the dual-class structure to OSOV.Footnote 120 Although dual-class shares in the UK previously died-a-death in the last millennium partly as a result of institutional investor aversion to the structure,Footnote 121 the UK boards adopting the structure at the time were doing so primarily to protect themselves from a burgeoning hostile takeover market and were mainly industrial and retail companies with easily observable long-term growth prospects, not redolent of contemporary, high-growth tech-firms which, as discussed, can particularly benefit from the adoption of dual-class stock. Today, notwithstanding the regular derision levelled at dual-class firms by institutional investors in the US,Footnote 122 evidence is mixed as to whether institutional investors actually shun such firms.Footnote 123 It is likely that if a tech-firm conducts an IPO with dual-class structure, the founder will be an individual that the market views as fundamental to the success of the business, and public investors will derive value from a founder with an idiosyncratic vision being bonded to the firm.

A counterargument, though, is that even if institutional investors avoid those IPOs where the relevant business of the company and the qualities of the founder do not justify dual-class structure, permitting dual-class firms on the premium-tier could give them an implicit regulatory seal of approval that could attract unsuspecting retail investors. However, retail investors constitute a nominal presence in the UK public equity markets,Footnote 124 and, as such, an IPO will not proceed, as was the case with WeWork in the US, without institutional investor support. Index trackers that are required to invest in the constituents of specific indices (which must be premium-listed to be included in the FTSE UK Index Series) will also not be prejudiced, since they will only be compelled to invest in a firm after it has become a member of the relevant index, which can only occur after the IPO has completed, which, in turn, is contingent upon substantive non-index-tracker institutional investor support.

VI. Why Prohibit Dual-Class Stock from the Premium-Tier?

Above, it was argued that dual-class stock can encourage founders of UK tech-firms to list their companies on the LSE, and, having listed, can present substantive benefits to tech-firms, and, therefore, long-term shareholder (including public shareholder) value. One may therefore ponder why the FCA has prohibited such structures from the premium-tier? The answer lies in the enigmatic nature of dual-class stock – for all the benefits that they present, they can also present risks to public shareholders. In this section, the downside to public shareholders of dual-class structure will be outlined, but also challenged in the context of high-growth tech-firms, and the UK's regulatory and market environment. It will be argued that the fear held by institutional investors of UK dual-class firms is unwarranted.

Since OSOV controlling shareholder firms are not prohibited from the premium-tier, the mere fact that a founder holds the balance of power within the firm and that the management team is insulated from removal by the public shareholders, cannot be the sole motivation for the dual-class stock prohibition. Motivation lies, rather, in the distortion to the controlling shareholder dynamic caused by the disconnect between voting rights and cash-flow rights. As the founder progressively reduces its cash-flow rights, any exercise by the founder of its control over the company that harms the financial health of the company will have less of an impact on the founder's wealth, since the founder's exposure to the company's financial prospects correspondingly reduces. In essence, the founder will fail to feel the full consequences of its actions.Footnote 125 The concern is that the founder will be incentivised to take actions that benefit the founder personally to the detriment of the interests of the company and the other shareholders. Such personal benefits are known as “private benefits of control”. The extraction of private benefits can, as follows, manifest itself in a number of actions that could be detrimental to inferior shareholders.

An obvious potential mischief is where the founder “tunnels” assets and profits out of the firm for its own benefit.Footnote 126 Such “tunnelling” could occur through sweetheart deals, the simple withdrawal of corporate funds,Footnote 127 or the appropriation of corporate opportunities.Footnote 128 In addition, a founder could cause the company to enter into transactions with other entities, in which the founder owns a greater proportion of the cash-flow rights than in the relevant company, on non-arm's length terms unfavourable to the relevant company. Since profits or assets are being diverted to, essentially, the founder, inferior shareholders in the first entity are being expropriated.Footnote 129 Aspects of English law and regulation should, though, curtail tunnelling of this nature. Out-and-out stealing would clearly be fraudulent,Footnote 130 and the laws in relation thereto are bolstered by the UK's strong accounting regime and financial press, both of which should aid the discovery of blatantly fraudulent acts. Short of outright theft, Chapter 11 of the Listing Rules introduces related-party transaction regulations for premium-listed companies.Footnote 131 If a founder holding control as a superior shareholderFootnote 132 were to cause a dual-class firm to enter into a transaction with the founder or one of its associates (including another company controlled by that founder), unless the transaction is in the ordinary course of business or below the size-threshold that triggers the regulations, prior to entering into the transaction, the company's sponsorFootnote 133 must confirm that it is fair and reasonable to all shareholders. If the transaction exceeds a further threshold, it must be pre-approved by a vote of the shareholders independent of the related-party (the founder, as the superior shareholder, in this case).Footnote 134 Furthermore, in the presence of a controlling shareholder,Footnote 135 a premium-listed company must enter into a “relationship agreement” with the controlling shareholder,Footnote 136 under which, inter alia, the controlling shareholder must agree to conduct all transactions with the company under arm's length and normal commercial terms.Footnote 137 If that relationship agreement is breached by, for example, a related-party transaction being entered into between the founder and the company on non-arm's length terms, the thresholds for related-party transactions are disapplied,Footnote 138 and the relevant transaction would require independent shareholder pre-approval no matter its size or whether or not the transaction is in the ordinary course of business. Related-party transaction regulations of this nature should at least limit the most egregious forms of tunnelling.

The US, where the largest dual-class firms reside, also employs related-party transaction protections,Footnote 139 and it is not a coincidence that truly insidious examples of tunnelling are rare.Footnote 140 A note of caution, though, is that in the OSOV-sphere, related-party transaction controversies have still occurred at controlling shareholder companies in the UK.Footnote 141 Those controversies arose from the related-party regulations not covering the relevant transactions, the nature of the transactions creating obfuscation as to whether the relevant thresholds had been satisfied, or the narrow definition of “associate” under the Listing Rules not covering the family member of the controlling shareholder transacting with the company.Footnote 142 As a result, transactions were unintentionally or, perhaps even intentionally, not treated as related-party transactions. Therefore, as has been suggested elsewhere by this author, it may be advisable to tighten-up related-party regulations for controlling shareholder firms (including dual-class firms if they were permitted on the premium-tier) by broadening the definition of associate as it pertains to controlling shareholder family-members, and by requiring that all related-party transactions, regardless of size, be confirmed by the firm's sponsor as fair and reasonable to all shareholders.Footnote 143

The extraction of private benefits could, though, occur more subtly in a manner that does not trigger related-party transaction regulations. For example, a founder may cause a dual-class firm to acquire assets or pursue projects that generate personal benefits for the founder, but are not shareholder-wealth-maximising. Those benefits may not just be financial in nature. Non-pecuniary benefits could also subsist, such that, in the context of tech-firms, the project is detrimental to shareholder wealth, but represents a “pet-project” for the founder or generates significant publicity and fame for the founder owing to its ambition or innovation.Footnote 144 Similarly, the founder may retain assets or persist with projects rather than selling or abandoning them, due to the substantial private benefits that the founder can extract. Inefficient decision-making of this kind has classically been cited by advocates of OSOV,Footnote 145 and could even theoretically lead to dual-class firms becoming inefficiently large and evolving into unwieldy conglomerates.Footnote 146 It is therefore accepted that subtle private benefit extraction leading to inefficient decision-making could still exist in UK dual-class firms if they were permitted on the premium-tier.

In the context of tech-firms, though, two aspects bear consideration. First, the types of tech-firms that are likely to benefit from dual-class stock are growth-phase companies that need to invest heavily in R&D. With debt funding scarce,Footnote 147 such companies may, post-IPO, have to make regular excursions to the equity markets for further financing. If the founder has, in the interim, developed a reputation for extracting substantial private benefits (assuming that those private benefits have not been obscured, and have had a detrimental effect on firm-wealth), the cost of capital will have increased, making such equity financing much more expensive.Footnote 148 Therefore, although the management team's insulation from the public markets can engender a long-term approach to the business, management can not completely disregard short-term consequences. Of course, a wholesale relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition of dual-class firms could open-up the market to non-high-growth firms, in relation to which the benefits of dual-class stock outlined in this article are possibly less relevant, and, therefore, could be overshadowed by the hazards. Although it is outside the scope of this article to discuss in detail the specific mechanisms that should be implemented alongside a relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition of dual-class structure to ensure that it is not utilised primarily to expropriate public shareholders, consideration could be given to restricting dual-class stock to certain types of companies, or requiring the issuer to justify the need for, and benefits of, dual-class stock on a firm-specific basis. The Hong Kong stock exchange, acting through Hong Kong Exchanges and Clearing Limited (HKEX), requires dual-class firms seeking admission to evidence their “innovative” credentials,Footnote 149 and the exchanges of Singapore (SGX)Footnote 150 and Tokyo (TSE)Footnote 151 require justifications based upon the qualities of the firms that make dual-class stock beneficial. The Shanghai stock exchange (SSE) is more granular and only permits dual-class listings on a separate board for science or technology companies (the STI Board).Footnote 152 The FCA should consider whether some form of restriction would be germane, although it is accepted that, in such a case, the existing expertise and capacity of the FCA in making such determinations on an ongoing basis may need to be enriched. An alternative approach would be for the FCA to play an intrinsic role in ensuring that the proposed issuer publicly discloses sufficient information prior to IPO which would enable the market to make a fully-informed decision as to whether the rationale for adoption of dual-class structure is justified based upon the nature of the company's business, the company's growth-profile and the importance of the superior shareholders to the success of the company.

Second, a founder will not have disposed of equity in the dual-class firm entirely. To the extent that the founder possesses at least a proportion of equity, it will feel some pain from taking actions that are detrimental to firm-wealth. However, that “pain” palliates at a sharply increasing rate as the controller's cash-flow rights decrease,Footnote 153 and it appears, in the US context, that controllers of dual-class firms reduce their equity holdings over time. Bebchuk and Kastiel (2017)Footnote 154 found that for the 10 largest US dual-class firms (by market capitalisation), at IPO, the controllers of those firms held, on average, 30% of the equity – not an insubstantial level of cash-flow rights. However, post-IPO, as of 2015, the average cash-flow rights held by those controllers, who had retained at least effective control of their firms, had fallen to 11.6%. Therefore, consideration should be given as to whether controllers of dual-class firms should, as a quid pro quo to enjoying enhanced-voting rights, be required to hold a minimum level of equity. HKEX, for example, requires superior shareholders to hold at least 10% of the equity in the company.Footnote 155 Determining the minimum threshold that adequately constrains controllers is a challenging, if not impossible, task, since it will vary on a firm-by-firm or, even, controller-by-controller basis. Furthermore, the level needs to be balanced so that it acts as a constraint on the most serious forms of abuse, but not so great that it undermines the ability of the controller to take risks and a long-term approach to the business. Determining the relevant threshold is an undertaking for future study, but it would be preferable for any such threshold to be sufficiently flexible to be varied on a case-by-case basis.Footnote 156

Management insulation has been described as a positive trait of dual-class firms, but, it could also be described negatively as “management entrenchment”. As long as management satisfies the aspirations of the controller, possibly even in priority to the interests of the shareholders as a whole, they will not have any fear of losing their employment. The inability of the public shareholders to remove directors is an inherent risk for them, since without the deterrent of removal, managers may not perform efficiently or diligently, or, worse, act in a self-serving manner; especially exacerbated where the controller only holds a small level of cash-flow rights, reducing the equity-constraining effect.Footnote 157 Although enabling long-termism and risk-taking have been discussed as benefits accruing to dual-class firms in the tech-sphere, if the founder is untalented, pretensions towards long-termism could simply be masking a malfunctioning strategy that is harmful to shareholder wealth in the short and long term, or risk-taking could be purely speculative and no more calculated than the worst Vegas gambler. With respect to high-growth tech-firms, though, as discussed above, it is likely that the public shareholders have invested in the relevant firm at IPO based upon their confidence in the abilities of the founder to lead the management of the company. Empirical evidence from other jurisdictions suggests that, for high-growth firms, the market recognises that the benefits accruing to the structure outweigh the costs to public investors, since firm valuations for high-growth dual-class firms are greater than for matched OSOV-firms.Footnote 158 If investors had considerable concerns over the future performance of the management team, firm valuations would likely be lower. Of course, outside investors are not infallible in judging the abilities of the founder, but their desire to invest at a premium would be based upon evidence of past-performance, and firm valuation studies are usually conducted over relatively long periods of time, such that if the founder turned-out to be untalented post-IPO, it is unlikely that the valuation premia identified would endure.Footnote 159 This does, though, highlight the potential importance of restricting dual-class structure to specific types of firms.Footnote 160

A critical issue is that the impact of management entrenchment on shareholder-value could transmute over time. Studies have suggested that dual-class firm valuations (and possibly operating performances) decline with age of firmFootnote 161 or time since IPOFootnote 162 at a greater rate than OSOV-firms to the extent that they are eventually performing worse than matched OSOV-firms.Footnote 163 Some have suggested that this characteristic warrants the mandatory imposition of mechanisms that cause dual-class structure to convert to OSOV automatically upon the expiry of a period of time since IPO (“time-dependent sunset clauses”).Footnote 164 On the face of it, in the context of high-growth tech-firms, the rationale is sound – during the growth phase of the firm, dual-class structure enables the founder to invest in R&D and long product-cycles that are beneficial in the long term but the benefits of which are perhaps unobservable to the public markets in the short-term; however, once the company has matured with completed product-cycles and a stable business plan, it becomes more difficult to identify the benefits of the structure to public shareholders, and the risks will begin to dominate. However, rather than the age of the firm itself being the reason for a decline in performance, time is merely a proxy for events that are more likely to occur as time passes.Footnote 165 A key event would be where the original founder, in which the investors had placed their faith, transfers control to a third-party. Even if that transferee were a family member of the founder, numerous studies have shown that controlling shareholder firms perform worse where control is in the hands of heirs as opposed to the original founder.Footnote 166 Again, although a detailed consideration of the restrictions that could be formulated in parallel with a relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition of dual-class stock requires further study, briefly, a relevant consideration would be to ensure that enhanced-voting rights are premised on the original superior shareholders continuing to hold the superior shares (or at least control of the company), with those shares converting into inferior shares upon a relevant transfer. HKEX,Footnote 167 SGX,Footnote 168 TSEFootnote 169 and SSEFootnote 170 all include similar requirements for dual-class firms. Even with such a restriction, other events could also occur over time that cause declining performance, such as where growth prospects decline, the original founder's skills and abilities wane, or the founder sells-down further equity incentivising greater private benefit extraction. A requirement for the founder to hold a threshold level of equityFootnote 171 could alleviate these dangers by ensuring that the founder thinks twice about extracting pernicious private benefits, or even about continuing in day-to-day management when shareholder wealth would be better served by relinquishing management to fresh leadership. By ensuring that the founder retains at least a non-negligible level of “skin-in-the-game”, it will also be less likely to take purely speculative risks. On the other hand, time-dependent sunset clauses are cruder mechanisms, being arbitrary in nature – it is impossible to deduce with accuracy at the time of IPO exactly when the benefits of dual-class structure will begin to be overshadowed by the costs to public shareholders.Footnote 172

Another criticism of dual-class firms that could be considered to be an egregious form of private benefit extraction relates to the generation of “control premia” upon a takeover of the firm. Control premia emerge in two respects: (1) an acquiror solely acquires the superior shares, thereby acquiring control without the inferior shareholders receiving any consideration; or (2) the acquiror acquires all the shares in the company but pays a higher price for the superior shares as compared to the inferior shares.

In the UK, though, the ability to extract control premia is significantly mitigated by mandatory bid and comparable treatment requirements. In relation to public companies registered and traded (or with central management and control) in the UK, the Isle of Man or the Channel Islands, and certain categories of European Economic Area (EEA) companies,Footnote 173 with securities traded on, inter alia, the Main Market, mandatory offer rules apply where any persons acting together in concert acquire shares carrying 30% or more of the voting rights in that company; such persons must make an offer for all the remaining shares of each class in the company, at not less than the highest price offered for a particular class of shares in the 12-month period prior to the offer.Footnote 174 Therefore, with regards to the first scenario, a potential acquiror will not be able to acquire control of the company merely by making an offer for the superior shares; an offer for all the shares in the company, no matter the class or voting rights attached, must be made. With regards to the second scenario, with multiple classes of shares, a bidder must pay to each class of shareholder at least the highest price paid by the bidder for shares of that class during the 12 months prior to the announcement of the offer,Footnote 175 and offers made for each class of shares must be “comparable”.Footnote 176 “Comparable” does not necessarily mean “identical”, and the Takeover Panel must be consulted,Footnote 177 but, prima facie, the Takeover Panel will insist that the ratio of the offer-values be equal to “the average of the ratios of the middle-market quotations [for each class of shares] taken from the Daily Official List over the course of the six months preceding the commencement of the offer period”.Footnote 178 Accordingly, if superior shares and inferior shares were listed in the UK, investors would not be caught off-guard by any potential control premium, since it would be based upon prevailing market prices, and, in any case, it is unlikely that the difference in market price between superior shares and inferior shares would be large.Footnote 179

Of course, where a founder seeks to retain majority-control, in most cases, the superior shares will not be listed.Footnote 180 In the case of a UK mandatory bid, where the superior shares are not listed, the Takeover Panel would not be able to apply the voting premium formula in assessing “comparable” price, if, for instance, a bidder triggers the Takeover Code's mandatory offer requirements by acquiring unlisted superior shares. However, in such circumstances, it is difficult to envisage that the Takeover Panel will not insist that the same price be paid for equal equity interests, requiring that the price paid per listed inferior share be the same as the highest price paid per unlisted superior share.

Although the Takeover Code will likely cease to apply to EEA firms after the end of the UK's post-EU withdrawal transition periodFootnote 181 most EU-jurisdictions have also implemented mandatory offer rules.Footnote 182 Control premia should therefore be irrelevant for the vast majority of premium-listed firms if dual-class stock were permitted.Footnote 183 In fact, when takeovers of dual-class firms do occur (which would require the acquiescence of the controller), since the controller can negotiate directly with the potential acquiror and will not sell-out unless it is compensated for the loss of its private benefits,Footnote 184 takeover prices will be higher than with OSOV dispersed-ownership firms.Footnote 185 Pursuant to the mandatory offer rules, all shareholders can share in those higher takeover prices.

Finally, high executive remuneration has also been identified as a potentially sinister form of private benefit extraction.Footnote 186 Theoretically, a founder involved in management could cause the company to pay himself/herself substantially above-market levels of executive pay, and, with dual-class stock, the founder may be incentivised to do so through a combination of suffering a smaller downside as a result of its smaller equity-holding, and receiving lower regular equity income. However, in jurisdictions which mandate high levels of executive pay disclosure, outrageously high levels of pay would likely attract significant shareholder, public and media opprobrium, which, notwithstanding isolated instances of excessive compensation, should, when purveying the overall picture, act as a moderating mechanism in this regard.Footnote 187 In the UK, quoted companies must prepare a directors’ remuneration report which must disclose detailed information relating to directors’ remuneration.Footnote 188 The contents must be publicly disclosed on the company's website.Footnote 189 Furthermore, in the OSOV-sphere, shareholders have an advisory vote on the implementation of directors’ remuneration, and a binding vote on directors’ remuneration policy.Footnote 190 With dual-class stock, the controller will be able to carry the vote. However, with OSOV-firms, even the loss of non-binding advisory votes can cause companies to re-assess their executive pay practices.Footnote 191 A similar course could be followed with dual-class stock firms, although the Listing Rules would need to be amended to provide that such companies disclose the results of voting by shareholders independent of the superior shareholders if the superior shareholders possess voting-control.Footnote 192 Even if one were sceptical as to the sagacity of “say-on-pay” votes and disclosure requirements, in the US (which also enjoys high levels of executive pay disclosure),Footnote 193 in practice, executive pay at dual-class firms is not excessive compared to OSOV-firms, and, in any case, is very much a drop-in-the-ocean compared to market capitalisation.Footnote 194 As an extreme example, at Google, the founders famously only pay themselves annually $1 in salary.Footnote 195 Although a dual-class firm controller has the legal power to pay itself any sum by way of executive compensation, it is unlikely that high executive remuneration will be a significant issue causing public shareholders harm if dual-class firms were permitted on the premium-tier, and, in any case, the regulators could continue to monitor on an ongoing basis whether further regulatory intervention is required.Footnote 196

In summary, although, from a theoretical perspective, dual-class structure can present a variety of potential risks to inferior shareholders, the most egregious possible acts of controllers are restricted by existing qualities of the UK's market and regulatory environment. Even in relation to more subtle forms of private benefit extraction, with respect to high-growth tech-companies, such extraction is not excessive in practice, and can, with measured regulatory revisions, be limited. For the UK tech-industry, it is unlikely that the potential costs to public shareholders of dual-class structure will outweigh the benefits.

VII. Conclusion

Whereas the US and China have surged ahead in the era of Big Tech, with numerous tech-company behemoths listed on their (and other) exchanges, the UK has lagged behind. Despite policy initiatives by the UK regulators and UK Government, currently, founders of tech-firms may be deterred from listing on the premium-tier of the LSE's Main Market due to its adherence to OSOV. Either they will need to cede control of the company upon flotation, or they can retain control upon IPO but suffer from lower levels of equity fund-raising for growth, and less personal wealth diversification.

Dual-class stock can provide an avenue for UK tech-firm listings, enabling founders to crystallise wealth and raise substantial equity capital for growth, while retaining control. Judging by the plethora of recent US tech-firm dual-class IPOs, the countenance of dual-class stock on the premium-tier could attract further tech-company flotations. Once listed, the insulation that dual-class structure provides against the short-term proclivities of public shareholders and the market for corporate control supports the taking of a long-term approach to the business of the company, allowing the founder to invest in R&D, long product-cycles and innovative ideas which can be profitable in the long term, but not easily observable in the short-term, and continue to pursue his/her idiosyncratic vision. Such a founder can also take the risks essential to the success of companies operating in an innovative sector. To the extent that the public shareholders value the abilities of the founder, they can benefit from the founder being bonded to the firm for the long term, which can also create consequential upside from the perspective of employee and other stakeholder relationships.

A suspicion of dual-class firms persists, though, as a result of the incentives on the controller to extract private benefits to the detriment of the interests of the company. As the cash-flow rights of the controller diminish, it will feel less “pain” from taking actions that reduce share value. However, the existing UK market and UK regulatory environment substantially protects inferior shareholders from the most egregious types of expropriation, and with respect to more subtle levels of expropriation, in practice, the concerns are overblown. Therefore, in the UK, the adoption of dual-class stock should not be feared, and greater consideration should be given to the benefits that could be secured by a relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition. Supplementary regulatory protocols can complete the picture and enhance the prospect that the benefits of dual-class firms will outweigh the costs to public shareholders. Further study will formulate the detailed application of those concepts from a UK regulatory standpoint,Footnote 197 but it is essential that any restrictions do not compromise the underlying benefits of the structure or undermine the ability of a founder to pursue its idiosyncratic vision. If that were the case, a relaxation of the premium-tier prohibition would be a fool's errand, and not attract the listings desired.

The discussion should now evolve from whether or not dual-class shares should be permitted on the premium-tier, to how dual-class structure can be promoted on the premium-tier. The possible regulatory restrictions proposed herein could open the door to premium-tier dual-class firms, while maintaining the market's confidence in the premium-tier as a listing segment to which the highest-levels of corporate governance apply. Consequently, with those supplementary regulatory restrictions in place, those dual-class firms that do list on the premium-tier will see a lower cost of capital than would otherwise be the case, further attracting dual-class listings. Britain should be proud of its tech-sector, and in turbulent political and economic times, the entrepreneurship and innovation of the UK economy needs to be supported and nurtured. With dual-class shares permitted on the premium-tier of the LSE, a supercharged UK tech-industry can flourish, and, finally, the lesser-spotted British Google may appear on the horizon.

Footnotes

*

Faculty of Law, University of Cambridge. Fellow of Churchill College, Cambridge. Fellow, Cambridge Endowment for Research in Finance. Former partner, Latham & Watkins LLP. I thank the two anonymous referees for their insightful comments.

References

1 On 2 October 2015, Alphabet, Inc. became the new listed holding company of Google. Throughout this article, the more common brand name, Google, will be used.

2 R. Foroohar, “We Need to Talk about Big Tech”, The Financial Times, 3 October 2017, available at https://www.ft.com/content/64a20c34-a769-11e7-93c5-648314d2c72c (all URLs were last accessed on 1 April 2020 unless otherwise stated).

3 Data sourced from Bloomberg stock quotes, available at https://www.bloomberg.com/markets/stocks.

4 See text accompanying notes 21–28 below.

5 The Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy's (DBEIS) Green Paper, Building Our Industrial Strategy, January 2017, 25.

6 Ibid., at p. 67; FCA, Review of the Effectiveness of Primary Markets: The UK Primary Markets Landscape, Discussion Paper DP17/2, February 2017, ch. 4; HM Treasury, Financing Growth in Innovative Firms: Consultation, August 2017, p. 33.

7 CBInsights, “The Global Unicorn Club: Private Companies Valued At $1B+”, available at https://www.cbinsights.com/research-unicorn-companies.

8 See note 59 below.

9 N. Fildes, “Busy Buyers Leave Only Two UK Tech Giants Standing”, The Financial Times, 14 January 2018, available at https://www.ft.com/content/39bc9b86-f464-11e7-88f7-5465a6ce1a00.

10 Google, Facebook, Baidu, Xiaomi and Tencent all utilise dual-class stock. Alibaba has implemented a discrete mechanic allowing founders and management to appoint a majority of the board (Form F-1 (Registration Statement) of Alibaba Holding Limited (6 May 2014), 209).

11 Stock ownership information gathered from Schedule 13G/A filings, Form 4 Statement of Changes in Beneficial Ownership filings, and Form 5 Annual Statement of Changes in Beneficial Ownership filings.

12 J. Coffee, “Dual Class Stock: The Shades of Sunset”, CLS Blue Sky Blog, 19 November 2018, available at http://clsbluesky.law.columbia.edu/2018/11/19/dual-class-stock-the-shades-of-sunset/.

13 As far as this author is aware, this is the first article in the era of Big Tech that evaluates dual-class stock purely from a UK standpoint.

14 FCA, Primary Markets, ch. 4 and pp. 8, 22.

15 HM Treasury, Financing Growth, 33.

16 D. Thomas, P. Stafford and P. Jenkins, “UK Seeks Change in Listing Rules to Lure Tech Start-Ups”, The Financial Times, 5 November 2019, available at https://www.ft.com/content/d4d2da5a-fee8-11e9-be59-e49b2a136b8d.

17 The author has conducted further research on the empirical evidence pertaining to dual-class stock in B. Reddy, “More than Meets the Eye: Reassessing the Empirical Evidence on US Dual-Class Stock” (2020), available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3554428.

18 A. Heathman, “London Tech Week: The Unicorn Companies at the Centre of UK Tech”, Evening Standard, 10 June 2019, available at https://www.standard.co.uk/tech/london-tech-week-uk-tech-unicorns-list-2019-a4163366.html; see note 7 above and accompanying text.

19 The “new economy” has been variously defined, but generally references the economic structure resulting from the intersection of globalisation and information technology: M. Pohjola, “The New Economy: Facts, Impacts and Policies” (2002) 14 Information Economics and Policy 133, 134.

20 HKEX (Hong Kong Exchanges and Clearing Limited), Concept Paper, New Board, June 2017, p. 11.

21 DBEIS, Green Paper, Building Our Industrial Strategy, p. 67; FCA, Primary Markets, ch. 4; HM Treasury, Financing Growth, p. 33.

22 HKEX, New Board, p. 15.

23 M. Maher and T. Andersson, “Corporate Governance: Effects on Firm Performance and Economic Growth” (1999) Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development 1, 36.

24 Gugler, K. (ed.), Corporate Governance and Economic Performance (Oxford 2001), 29Google Scholar; Bradley, M., Jarrell, G. and Kim, E., “On the Existence of an Optimal Capital Structure: Theory and Evidence” (1984) 39 The Journal of Finance 857, 874CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

25 HM Treasury, Financing Growth, p. 9.

26 Cipollone, D., “Risky Business: A Review of Dual Class Share Structures in Canada and a Proposal for Reform” (2012) 21 Dalhousie J. Legal Stud. 62, 69Google Scholar; K-H. Bae and J. Kang, “Does the Stock Market Benefit the Economy?” (2017) EFMA Symposium: Finance and Real Economy Accepted Papers (March 2017).

27 UK Tech on the Global Stage: Tech Nation Report 2019 (2019), available at https://technation.io/report2019/.

28 S. Feldman, “BNA Insights: IPOs in 2016 Increasingly Include Dual-Class Shareholder Voting Rights” (2016) Sec. Reg. & L. Rep. 1, 3.

29 See e.g. FSMA 2000 (Financial Promotion) Order 2005, SI 2000/1529 as amended, Arts. 48 and 50.

30 Companies Act 2006 (CA 2006), s. 755; Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 (FSMA 2000), Part II.

31 Using the US as an analogy, there is considerable benefit to public investors in ensuring that the most successful companies are listed – between 1926 and 2016, the net gain for the US stock markets can be attributed to only four percent of listed companies (Bessembinder, H., “Do Stocks Outperform Treasury Bills?” (2018) 129 Journal of Financial Economics 440, 456CrossRefGoogle Scholar). As noted by Sharfman, in the context of sunset clauses (see text accompanying note 164 below), “inhibiting one company from becoming the next Alphabet or Facebook, it is one company too many” (Sharfman, B., “The Undesirability of Mandatory Time-Based Sunsets in Dual Class Share Structures: A Reply to Bebchuk and Kastiel” (2019) 93 S.Cal.L.R. Postscript 1, 10Google Scholar).

32 Office for National Statistics (ONS), MQ5: Investment by Insurance Companies, Pension Funds and Trusts: October to December 2018, March 2019, p. 26.

33 S. Ghosh and P. Leskin, “SoftBank Is Reportedly Taking Control of WeWork: Here's a Running List of All the Japanese Giant's Major Investments in Tech”, Business Insider, 22 October 2019, available at https://www.businessinsider.com/running-list-softbank-investments-2017-7?r=US&IR=T.

34 A. Schneider and C. Henrik, Boston Consulting Group, “Private Equity Minority Investments: Can Less Be More”, 2 April 2015, available at https://www.bcg.com/en-gb/publications/2015/private-equity-minority-investments-can-less-be-more.aspx.

35 KPMG Enterprise, Venture Pulse Q2 2018: Global Analysis of Venture Funding, July 2018, pp. 2, 43, 74; FCA, Primary Markets, p. 26; HM Treasury, Financing Growth, p. 14.

36 S. Rigos, “The UK Equity Gap, ‘Why Is There No Facebook or Google in the UK?’” (2011) Greater London Authority 25.

37 See FCA, Primary Markets, p. 26 – “scale-up companies” are those with average growth in employees or turnover of more than 20% per annum over three years, with a minimum of 20 employees at the start. Also, see HM Treasury, Financing Growth, p. 11; A. Bravo-Biosca, “Firm growth dynamics across countries” (2016), NESTA Working Paper No. 16/03, available at https://media.nesta.org.uk/documents/wp16-03_firm_growth_dynamics-17.pdf.

38 HM Treasury, Financing Growth, p. 12.

39 FCA, Primary Markets, p. 26.

40 Financial Services Authority, Listing Regime Review: Feedback on CP09/24 and CP09/28 with Final Rules, February 2010.

41 Reddy, B., “The Fat Controller: Slimming Down the Excesses of Controlling Shareholders in UK Listed Companies” (2018) 38 O.J.L.S. 733, 743, 757–60Google Scholar.

42 Listing Rules, Premium Listing Principle 3.

43 Listing Rules, Premium Listing Principle 4.

44 Non-voting preference shares are potentially permitted under Listing Rule (LR) 7.2.4G.

45 LR 9.2.21R.

46 FCA Policy Statement PS14/8, Response to CP13/15 – Enhancing the effectiveness of the Listing Regime, May 2014, p. 31.

47 Cheffins, B. (ed.), Corporate Ownership and Control: British Business Transformed (Oxford 2008), 317, 32CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cheffins, B. (ed.), Company Law: Theory, Structure and Operation (Oxford 1997), 472, 475Google Scholar.

48 Cheffins, Corporate Ownership and Control, pp. 309, 317; J. Franks and C. Mayer, “Evolution of Ownership and Control Around the World: The Changing Face of Capitalism” (2017), ECGI Finance Working Paper No. 503/2017 1, at 13.

49 See CA 2006, s. 168, and Companies (Model Articles) Regulations 2008, SI 2008/3229 (the Model PLC Articles), art. 20. In the absence of bespoke articles of association, the Model PLC Articles will apply (CA 2006, s. 20) and, commonly, public companies adopt an amended version of the Model PLC Articles.

50 Model PLC Articles, art. 3.

51 Heller, J., Catch-22 (New York 1961)Google Scholar; also see Wasserman, N., “The Founder Dilemma” (2008) 86 H.B.R. 102Google ScholarPubMed.

52 See e.g. Bushell v Faith [1970] A.C. 1099.

53 White Page Ltd. in association with the London Stock Exchange, A Guide to AIM (London 2010), 4.

54 FCA, Primary Markets, p. 19.

55 Ibid., at p. 19.

56 See notes 131–134 below and accompanying text. In the US, investors can also take some comfort from constraints on related-party transactions (see note 139 below).

57 Controlling shareholders must enter into “relationship agreements” with their companies (see notes 136–138 below and accompanying text).

58 L. Bebchuk, “Asymmetric Information and the Choice of Corporate Governance Arrangements” (2002), Harvard Law School Discussion Paper No. 398, 1; Bebchuk, L. and Kastiel, K., “The Untenable Case for Perpetual Dual-Class Stock” (2017) 4 Va. Law Rev. 585, 623Google Scholar.

59 The FTSE UK Index Series is a series of “indices” that rank UK premium-listed companies according to various measures of performance, sometimes further sub-divided into industry sectors. An example is the FTSE-100, which comprises the 100 largest UK premium-listed companies by market capitalisation.

60 L. Bebchuk and S. Hirst, “Index Funds and the Future of Corporate Governance: Theory, Evidence, and Policy”, November 2018, 15, available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3282794.

61 Hirst, S. and Kastiel, K., “Corporate Governance by Index Exclusion” (2019) 99 B.U.L.R. 1229, 1250Google Scholar.

62 Cheffins, B., “The Undermining of UK Corporate Governance (?)” (2013) 33 O.J.L.S. 503, 513Google Scholar; Hirst and Kastiel, “Corporate Governance”, p. 1256.

63 Sharfman, B., “A Private Ordering Defense of a Company's Right to Use Dual Class Share Structures in IPOs” (2018) 63 Villanova Law Rev. 1, 4Google Scholar; Lund, D., “Nonvoting Shares and Efficient Corporate Governance” (2019) 71 Stanf. Law Rev. 687, 711Google Scholar; Hirst and Kastiel, “Corporate Governance”, pp. 1253–54.

64 FCA's “The Official List” as of 25 November 2019.

65 Taking IPOs on NYSE America, NASDAQ and the NYSE with offer prices of at least $5.00, the proportion of tech-company IPOs adopting dual-class structure rose from 4.9% in 2004, the year of Google's IPO, to 34.2% in 2018 (J. Ritter, “Initial Public Offerings: Dual Class IPOs” (updated as of 19 December 2018), available at https://site.warrington.ufl.edu/ritter/files/2019/04/IPOs2018DualClass.pdf).

66 See note 32 above and accompanying text. Additionally, if UK retail investors desire to invest in foreign listed companies directly (rather than indirectly through institutional funds) it will involve foreign-based investment accounts and unfamiliar regulations.

67 As of 31 October 2019, only three UK tech-companies had stock listed exclusively on the NYSE – Farfetch Ltd. (Farfetch), International Game Technology plc., and Delphi Technologies plc. (NYSE, “Current List of All Non-U.S. Issuers” (2019), availalble at https://www.nyse.com/publicdocs/nyse/data/CurListofallStocks.pdf). Farfetch adopted a dual-class stock structure at IPO. From a search of NASDAQ's “company list” as of 25 November 2019 (available at https://old.nasdaq.com/screening/company-list.aspx), only two UK tech-companies had stock listed exclusively on NASDAQ – Mimecast Ltd. and IHS Markit Ltd.

68 Pagano, M., Röell, A. and Zechner, J., “The Geography of Equity Listing: Why Do Companies List Abroad?” (2002) 57 Journal of Finance 2651, 2658–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

69 Fanto, J. and Karmel, R., “A Report on the Attitudes of Foreign Companies Regarding a U.S. Listing” (1997) 3 Stan.J.L.Bus.Fin. 51, 66Google Scholar.

70 Ibid., at p. 67.

71 C. Silva, “Why the LSE Can Serve Tech Startups Better than Nasdaq or the NYSE”, The Guardian, 10 November 2016, available at https://www.theguardian.com/business/blog/2016/nov/10/lse-tech-startups-nasdaq-nyse-investors.

72 See note 65 above.

73 Bebchuk, L. and Kastiel, K., “The Perils of Small-Minority Controllers” (2019) 107 Geo.L.J. 1453, 1496Google Scholar, found that 83.6% of Russell-3000 dual-class companies have a controlling minority shareholder (an earlier draft noted the figure as 96.7% of S&P-1500 dual-class firms).

74 Google Inc. Amendment No. 8 to Registration Statement (filed on 16 August 2004), 29.

75 See e.g. Fischel, D., “Organized Exchanges and the Regulation of Dual Class Common Stock” (1987) 54 U.Chi.L.Rev. 119, 139CrossRefGoogle Scholar; DeAngelo, H. and DeAngelo, L., “Managerial Ownership of Voting Rights, A Study of Public Corporations with Dual Classes of Common Stock” (1985) 14 Journal of Financial Economics 33, 35Google Scholar; Dent, G., “Dual Class Capitalization: A Reply to Professor Seligman” (1987) 54 Geo.Wash.L.Rev. 725, 764Google Scholar; Choi, A., “Concentrated Ownership and Long-Term Shareholder Value” (2018) 8 Harv.Bus.L.Rev. 53, 59Google Scholar; Goshen, Z. and Hamdani, A., “Corporate Control and Idiosyncratic Vision” (2016) 125 Yale L.J. 560Google Scholar; SGX (Singapore Exchange), Consultation Paper on Possible Listing Framework for Dual Class Share Structures, February 2017, p. 9; HKEX, Concept Paper, Weighted Voting Rights, August 2014, p. 23.

76 Narayanan, M., “Managerial Incentives for Short-Term Results” (1985) 40 Journal of Finance 1469, 1479CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

77 For a description of the market for corporate control, see the seminal work by Henry Manne: Manne, H., “Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control” (1965) 73 Journal of Political Economy 110CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

78 Lund, “Nonvoting Shares”, p. 687; Goshen, Z. and Squire, R., “Principal Costs: A Theory for Corporate Law and Governance” (2017) 117 Colum.L.Rev. 767, 784Google Scholar; Gordon, J., “Ties that Bond: Dual Class Common Stock and the Problem of Shareholder Choice” (1988) 76 Cal.L.Rev. 1, 44CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

79 Stein, J., “Takeover Threats and Managerial Myopia” (1988) 96 Journal of Political Economy 61CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

80 Moore, M. and Walker-Arnott, E., “A Fresh Look at Stock Market Short-termism” (2014) 41 J. Law Soc. 416, 430, 438CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Brandenburger, A. and Polak, B., “When Managers Cover Their Posteriors: Making the Decisions the Market Wants to See” (1996) 27 RAND Journal of Economics 523CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mizik, N., “The Theory and Practice of Myopic Management” (2010) 47 Journal of Marketing Research 594, 594CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

81 The Kay Review of UK Equity Markets and Long-Term Decision Making: Final Report (July 2012), 38.

82 Lehn, K., Netter, J. and Poulsen, A., “Consolidating Corporate Control: Dual-Class Recapitalizations versus Leveraged Buyouts” (1990) 27 Journal of Financial Economics 557, 564CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Fischel, “Organized Exchanges”, p. 138; Alchian, A. and Demsetz, H., “Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization” (1972) 62 American Economic Review 777, 789Google Scholar.

83 S. Kupor, “Sorry CalPERS, Dual Class Shares Are A Founder's Best Friend”, Forbes CIO Network, 14 May 2013, available at https://www.forbes.com/sites/ciocentral/2013/05/14/sorry-calpers-dual-class-shares-are-a-founders-best-friend/#5e896b6412d9.

84 Google's founders, in justifying its capital structure, stated: “Technology products often require significant investment over many years to fulfill their potential. For example, it took over three years just to ship our first Android handset, and then another three years on top of that before the operating system truly reached critical mass. These kinds of investments are not for the faint-hearted. We have protected Google from outside pressures and the temptation to sacrifice future opportunities to meet short-term demands” (Alphabet's 2011 Founders’ Letter, 31 December 2011, available at https://abc.xyz/investor/founders-letters/2011/).

85 Chemmanur, J., “Dual Class IPOs: A Theoretical Analysis” (2012) 38 Journal of Banking and Finance 305, 306Google Scholar.

86 Ibid., at p. 315; M. Burkart, D. Gromb and F. Panunzi “Large Shareholders, Monitoring, and the Value of the Firm” (1997) Quarterly Journal of Economics 693, 718; Davies et al., “Measuring the Costs of Short-Termism” (2014) 12 Journal of Financial Stability 16, 18.

87 Denis, D. and Denis, D., “Majority Owner-Managers and Organizational Efficiency” (1994) 1 Journal of Corporate Finance 91, 106CrossRefGoogle Scholar; DeAngelo and DeAngelo, “Managerial Ownership”, p. 62; Fischel, “Organized Exchanges”, p. 137; Smart, S. and Zutter, C., “Control as a Motivation for Underpricing: A Comparison of Dual and Single-Class IPOs” (2003) 69 Journal of Financial Economics 85, 103CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Böhmer, E., Sanger, G. and Varshney, S.The Effect of Consolidated Control on Firm Performance: The Case of Dual-Class IPOs” in Levis, M. (ed.), Empirical Issues in Raising Equity Capital (Indiana 1996), 111Google Scholar.

88 Mayer, C., “Corporate Governance, Competition, and Performance” (1997) 24 J. L. & Soc. 152, 168Google Scholar; Maher and Andersson, “Corporate Governance”, p. 28.

89 Alphabet's 2011 Founders’ Letter.

90 Gilson, R., “Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance: Complicating the Comparative Taxonomy” (2006) 119 L.R. 1642, 1669Google Scholar.

91 GUBERNA, “Re-Designing Corporate Governance to Promote Innovation” (2016) GUBERNA Position Paper January 2016 1, at 7; Manso, G., “Motivating Innovation” (2011) 66 Journal of Finance 1823, 1852CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

92 This is particularly true of family controlled companies – see Cheffins, B., “Corporate Law and Ownership Structure: A Darwinian Link?” (2002) 25 U.N.S.W.L.J. 346, 363Google Scholar. Also, see Mayer, “Corporate Governance”, p. 168; Maher and Andersson, “Corporate Governance”, p. 9.

93 Gilson, R., “Controlling Family Shareholders in Developing Countries: Anchoring Relational Exchange” (2007) 60 Stan.L.Rev. 633, 643Google Scholar; Cheffins, “Corporate Law and Ownership Structure”, p. 363.

94 In the context of takeover defences, see generally Cremers, Litov, L. and Sepe, S., “Staggered Boards and Long-Term, Firm Value, Revisited” (2017) 126 Journal of Financial Economics 422, 442Google Scholar; W. Johnson et al., “The Lifecycle Effects of Firm Takeover Defenses” (2018) 1, 29, available at http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2808208; Mayer, “Corporate Governance”, p. 168.

95 Reddy, “Fat Controller”, p. 739.

96 See text accompanying note 51 above.

97 E.g., S. Bianchini, J. Krafft, F. Quatraro and J. Ravix “Corporate Governance, Innovation and Firm Age: Insights and New Evidence” (2015) GREDEG Working Papers Series 2015-05, 1; GUBERNA, “Re-Designing Corporate Governance”; Reddy, B., “Thinking Outside the Box – Eliminating the Perniciousness of Box-Ticking in the New Corporate Governance Code” (2019) 82 M.L.R. 692CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

98 B. Nagji and G. Tuff, “Managing Your Innovation Portfolio”, Harvard Business Review, reprint by Monitor Deloitte, May 2012, 9.

99 Smart and Zutter, “Control as a Motivation”, p. 103.

100 In the presence of a controlling shareholder, since, ultimately, the controller can determine the composition of the board, the true independence of the independent directors has been questioned: Reddy, “Fat Controller”, p. 754.

101 The UK CGC is premised on the concept of disclosure of corporate governance arrangements, giving outside shareholders the information they need to instigate change if desired. However, in the presence of a controlling shareholder, corporate governance measures will have been implemented at the behest, or at least with the tacit approval, of the controller.

102 Edmans, A., “Blockholders and Corporate Governance” (2014) 6 Annual Review of Financial Economics 23, 33CrossRefGoogle Scholar; also see Cheffins, “Corporate Law and Ownership Structure”, p. 357; C. Holderness, “A Survey of Blockholders and Corporate Control” (2003) Economic Policy Review – Federal Reserve Bank of New York 51, 56; Ashton, D., “Revisiting Dual-Class Stock” (1994) 68 St. John's L.Rev. 863, 927Google Scholar; Gilson, R. and Black, B. (eds.), The Law and Finance of Corporate Acquisitions (New York 1995), 784Google Scholar.

103 Faccio, M., Marchica, M. and Mura, R., “Large Shareholder Diversification and Corporate Risk-Taking” (2011) 24 Review of Financial Studies. 3601, 3621CrossRefGoogle Scholar (risk was measured by the volatility of profitability).

104 By analogy, see the wager formulation in Kahneman, D. (ed.), Thinking, Fast and Slow (New York 2011), 336Google Scholar.

105 Bauguess, S., Slovin, M. and Sushka, M., “Large Shareholder Diversification, Corporate Risk Taking, and the Benefits of Changing to Differential Voting Rights” (2012) 36 Journal of Banking and Finance 1244, 1251CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

106 Fischel, “Organized Exchanges”, p. 137; SGX, “Possible Listing Framework”, p. 9. Also see note 111 below.

107 See Section VI below.

108 Choi, “Concentrated Ownership”, p. 68. This assumes the absence of a control premium, as would be the case in the UK (see text accompanying notes 173–183 below).

109 The Takeover Code as published by the UK's Panel on Takeovers and Mergers (Takeover Code), Rule 9. Also, see note 174 below and accompanying text.

110 See notes 92–94 above and accompanying text.

111 The attachment of named figures to businesses is particularly felicitous in certain jurisdictions, such as Italy (Santoro, A., Guarneri, C. Palma, P. and Capogrosso, A., “Deviations from the ‘One Share – One Vote’ Principle in Italy: Recent Developments – Multiple Voting Rights Shares and Loyalty Shares” (2015) 5 Bocconi Legal Papers 141, 164Google Scholar) and India (“Ratan Tata's Legacy”, The Economist, 1 December 2012, available at https://www.economist.com/leaders/2012/12/01/ratan-tatas-legacy).

112 Goshen and Hamdani, “Corporate Control and Idiosyncratic Vision”, p. 577.

113 M. Weinberger, “This Is Why Steve Jobs Got Fired from Apple – and How He Came Back to Save the Company”, Business Insider, 31 July 2017, available at https://www.businessinsider.com/steve-jobs-apple-fired-returned-2017-7?r=US&IR=T.

114 M. Leung and R. Tung, “Dual Class Shares: The Good, The Bad and The Ugly” (2018) CFA Institute 1, at 8.

115 See text accompanying note 157 below.

116 ISS M&A Deal Note (North America), “The Tragedy of the Dual Class Commons”, 13 February 2012, 1, at 1, available at http://online.wsj.com/public/resources/documents/facebook0214.pdf.

117 Wen, T., “You Can't Sell Your Firm and Own It Too: Disallowing Dual-Class Stock Companies from Listing on the Securities Exchanges” (2014) 162 U.Pa.L.R. 1495, at 1505Google Scholar; Winden, A., “Sunrise, Sunset: An Empirical and Theoretical Assessment of Dual-Class Stock Structures” (2018) 3 Col.Bus.L.R. 852, 899Google Scholar.

118 Anand, A., “Governance Complexities in Firms with Dual Class Shares” (2018) 3 Annals of Corporate Governance 184CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

119 A. Edgecliffe-Johnson and E. Platt, “WeWork Founder Trades Voting Power to Back SoftBank Rescue”, The Financial Times, 21 October 2019, available at https://www.ft.com/content/b9312eee-f440-11e9-b018-3ef8794b17c6.

120 M. Isaac, “Uber Sells Stake to SoftBank Valuing Ride-Hailing Giant at $48 Billion”, The New York Times, 28 December 2017, available at https://www.nytimes.com/2017/12/28/technology/uber-softbank-stake.html.

121 See note 48 above.

122 See e.g. Council of Institutional Investors (CII), “Dual-Class Stock”, available at https://www.cii.org/dualclass_stock; ProxyInsight, “An Interview with W. Robert Main III, Head of Portfolio Company Engagement, Analysis and Voting at Vanguard”, Proxy Monthly, July 2017, 4; Calpers Investment Committee, “Dual Class/Non-Voting Shares Update” (2018) 1, at 10, available at https://www.calpers.ca.gov/docs/board-agendas/201804/invest/item06a-01_a.pdf. A. Mooney, “Big Investors Fight Back over Dual-Class Shares”, The Financial Times, 24 November 2019, available at https://www.ft.com/content/bc220535-5055-47ce-811d-fc4a56d32937.

123 Finding that institutional investor ownership in dual-class firms was the same or greater than such ownership in OSOV-firms: R. Anderson, E. Ottolenghi and D. Reeb, “The Dual Class Premium: A Family Affair” (2017), 1, 28, available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3006669; Smart, et al. , “What's in a Vote? The Short- and Long-Run Impact of Dual-Class Equity on IPO Firm Values” (2008) 45 Journal of Accounting and Economics 94, 99CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Finding slightly less institutional ownership in dual-class firms: Li, K. et al. , “Do Voting Rights Affect Institutional Investment Decisions? Evidence from Dual-Class Firms” (2008) 37 Financial Management 713, 720CrossRefGoogle Scholar; J. Kim et al., “Multi-Class Shares Around the World: The Role of Institutional Investors”, November 2018, unpublished, 1, 19.

124 As of 31 December 2018, individual investors only owned 13.5% of UK quoted shares: ONS, Ownership of UK Quoted Shares: 2018, January 2020, p. 4.

125 Easterbrook, F. and Fischel, D., “Voting in Corporate Law” (1983) 26 J. Law Econ. 395, at 409CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hu, H. and Black, B., “The New Vote Buying: Empty Voting and Hidden (Morphable) Ownership” (2006) 79 S.Cal.L.Rev. 811, 851Google Scholar; HKEX, New Board, p. 18.

126 S. Johnson, R. La Porta, F. Lopez-de-Silanes and A. Shleifer, Tunneling (2000), NBER Working Paper 7523, 1, at 2. The authors attribute the genesis of the term to the expropriation of minority shareholders in the Czech Republic (“as in removing assets through an underground tunnel”).

127 Ashton, “Revisiting Dual-Class Stock”, p. 916.

128 D. Solomon, “The Importance of Inferior Voting Rights in Dual-Class Firms” (2017), 1, 15, 16, available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3179375.

129 Johnson et al., Tunneling, p. 7; Bertrand, M., Mehta, P. and Mullainathan, S., “Ferreting Out Tunneling: An Application to Indian Business Groups” (2002) 117 Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, 139CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

130 Fraud Act 2006; also see Theft Act 1968, ss. 17, 19.

131 Disclosure requirements also apply to related-party transactions under the International Accounting Standards (IAS 24) and, if material, under the FCA's Disclosure Rules and Transparency Rules sourcebook (DTR) (DTR 7.3) and LR 21.8.17BR. For companies incorporated in England and Wales, board approval requirements (excluding the founder and associates) would also be required for material related-party transactions (DTR 7.3.8R).

132 A founder holding a majority of the votes in the company would be a related-party as a “substantial shareholder”, being, broadly, a shareholder holding 10% or more of the votes (LR 11.1.4R).

133 Premium-listed companies must appoint a person, who must be an authorised person (see FSMA 2000, s. 31) or member of a designated professional body (LR 8.6), approved by the FCA to provide sponsor services (LR 8.2), to advise the issuer on its listing obligations, and to give assurances to the FCA that the issuer's responsibilities thereunder are being met.

134 In relation to the thresholds pertaining to related-party transactions, see LRs 11.1.5R and 11.1.7, and LR 10 Annex 1.

135 A founder with majority-control would be a “controlling shareholder” for these purposes, being, broadly, a shareholder holding 30% or more of the votes (LR App 1.1).

136 LRs 6.5.4R and 9.2.2ADR(1).

137 LR 6.5.4R.

138 LR 11.1.1AR.

139 In Delaware, upon a challenge that directors have breached their fiduciary duties, the Courts may require the company to prove that a conflicted transaction was made on the basis of fair price and process, and fair to the public shareholders: Weinberger v UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 703 (Del. 1983).

140 The only examples of extreme, criminal, tunnelling at US dual-class firms have been at Adelphia Communications Corporation: S. Gilson and B. Villalonga, “Adelphia Communications Corp.'s Bankruptcy” (2010) Harvard Business School Case 208-071, 6; and Hollinger International: Cipollone, “Risky Business”, p. 75.

141 E.g., at the companies Eurasian Natural Resources Corporation plc. (ENRC), Bumi plc., Exillion Energy plc., Sports Direct International plc. (Sports Direct) and Ferrexpo plc.: Reddy, “Fat Controller”, pp. 757ff.

142 Ibid., at pp. 751, 760, in relation to Sports Direct and ENRC, respectively.

143 Ibid., at p. 760.

144 Dyck, A. and Zingales, L., “Private Benefits of Control: An International Comparison” (2004) 59 J.Fin. 537, at 540CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gilson, “Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance”, p. 1664.

145 Easterbrook and Fischel, “Voting in Corporate Law”, p. 409.

146 Bebchuk, L., Kraakman, R. and Triantis, G., “Stock Pyramids, Cross-Ownership, and Dual Class Equity: The Mechanisms and Agency Costs of Separating Control from Cash-Flow Rights” in Morck, R. (ed.), Concentrated Corporate Ownership (Chicago 2000), 303Google Scholar.

147 See note 23 above and accompanying text.

148 In relation to controlling shareholders, see generally Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R., “A Survey of Corporate Governance” (1997) 52 Journal of Finance 737, 749CrossRefGoogle Scholar; La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R.Legal Determinants of External Finance” (1997) 52 Journal of Finance 1131, 1149CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

149 HKEX, Guidance Letter HKEX-GL93-18, Suitability for Listing with a WVR Structure, April 2018, para. 4.2.

150 SGX, Consultation Paper: Proposed Listing Framework for Dual Class Share Structures, March 2018, p. 2.

151 TSE, New Listing Guidebook: 1st and 2nd Sections, October 2018, p. 142.

152 K. Ho, “Examining the Viability to Allow Dual-Class Share Structure Companies to List in the Financial Market of the People's Republic of China: Lessons and Experiences from Hong Kong” (2019), 1, 26, available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3408873&download=yes.

153 See Bebchuk et al., “Stock Pyramids”, p. 295; Bebchuk and Kastiel, “The Perils”, p. 1473.

154 Bebchuk and Kastiel, “The Untenable Case”, p. 608.

155 HK Listing Rules, Rule 8A.12.

156 HKEX, for example, recognises that the 10% threshold may be lowered for firms with market capitalisation of HK$80 billion or more.

157 See note 125 above and accompanying text.

158 Jordan, B., Kim, S. and Liu, M.Growth Opportunities, Short-Term Market Pressure, and Dual-Class Share Structure” (2016) 41 Journal of Corporate Finance 304CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bozec, Y. and Laurin, C., “Large Shareholder Entrenchment and Performance: Empirical Evidence from Canada” (2008) 35 Journal of Business Finance and Accounting 25CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

159 For a detailed exposition of the empirical evidence pertaining to US dual-class firms, see Reddy, “More than Meets the Eye”.

160 See the text accompanying notes 149–152 above.

161 H. Kim and R. Michaely, “Sticking Around Too Long? Dynamics of the Benefits of Dual-Class Structures” (2018), 1, available at https://ssrn.com/abstract=3145209.

162 M. Cremers, B. Lauterbach and A. Pajuste, “The Life-Cycle of Dual Class Firms” (2018), ECGI Working Paper No. 550/2018, 1.

163 However, the results may also be explained by high-growth firms forming a disproportionately higher percentage of dual-class IPOs, and therefore declining at a greater extent than lower-growth firms as they attain maturity.

164 CII Letter to E. King, Chief Regulatory Officer, International Exchange Inc. (24 October 2018), available at https://www.cii.org/files/issues_and_advocacy/correspondence/2018/20181024%20NYSE%20Petition%20on%20Multiclass%20Sunsets%20FINAL.pdf; also, see Bebchuk and Kastiel, “The Untenable Case”, p. 631; Kim and Michaely, “Sticking Around”, p. 29; Cremers et al., “The Life-Cycle”, p. 41.

165 Johnson et al., “Lifecycle Effects”, p. 5.

166 See e.g. Anderson, R. and Reeb, D., “Founding-Family Ownership and Firm Performance; Evidence from the S&P 500” (2003) 58 Journal of Finance 1301, 1321CrossRefGoogle Scholar; R. Morck, D. Stangeland and B. Yeung, “Inherited Wealth, Corporate Control, and Economic Growth: The Canadian Disease” in R. Morck (ed.), Concentrated Corporate Ownership, p. 319; Bennedsen, M., Nielsen, K., Perez-Gonzalez, F. and Wolfenzon, D., “Inside the Family Firm: The Role of Families in Succession Decisions and Performance” (2007) 122 Quarterly Journal of Economics 647, 669CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Villalonga, B. and Amit, R., “How Do Family Ownership, Control and Management Affect Firm Value?” (2006) 80 Journal of Financial Economics 385, 403CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Essen, M. van, Carney, M., Gedajlovic, E. and Heugens, P., “How Does Family Control Influence Firm Strategy and Performance? A Meta-Analysis of US Publicly Listed Firms” (2015) 23 Corporate Governance 3, 18Google Scholar.

167 HK Listing Rules, Rule 8A.18.

168 SGX Mainboard Rules, Rule 210(10).

169 TSE, New Listing Guidebook, p. 145.

170 STI Board Rules, Art. 4.5.10.

171 See the text accompanying notes 155–156 above.

172 J. Fisch and S. Solomon, “The Problems of Sunsets” (2019), U. of Penn., Law School Research Paper No. 19-04, 17; Sharfman, “Undesirability”; M. Moore, “Designing Dual Class Sunsets: The Case for a Transfer-Centered Approach” (2019), 27, available at https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3478572.

173 Takeover Code, Section A3.

174 Ibid., at Rule 9.

175 Ibid., at Rule 9.5.

176 Ibid., at Rule 14.1.

177 Ibid., at Rule 9.5.

178 Ibid., at Notes to Rule 14.1.

179 If inferior shares and superior shares were premium-listed, where a controller holds a majority of the voting rights, as a result of mandatory offer rules, a minority holding of superior shares is unlikely to be of substantially greater value to a third party as compared to a minority interest in the inferior shares (A. Stumpf and A. Cline, “Price Differentials Between Voting and Nonvoting Stock”, Stout Advisory Services 1, at 4, available at https://www.stout.com/en/insights/article/price-differentials-between-voting-and-nonvoting-stock/).

180 With respect to the US: P. Gompers, J. Ishii and A. Metrick, “Extreme Governance: An Analysis of Dual-Class Firms in the United States” (2010) 23 Review of Financial Studies 1051, 1056.

181 The Takeover Panel, Code Committee Response Statement RS2018/2, “The United Kingdom's Withdrawal from the European Union”, 6 March 2019, p. 10. In relation to the transition period, see Agreement on the withdrawal of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland from the European Union and the European Atomic Energy Community, OJ L 29 31.1.20, p. 7-187, Arts. 126–132.

182 Bonellierede, Bredin Prat, De Brauw, Hengeler Mueller, Slaughter and May and Uri´a Mene´ndez, “Guide to Public Takeovers in Europe” (June 2016), available at https://www.debrauw.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/Guide-to-Public-Takeovers-in-Europe-2016.pdf.

183 Out of 1161 Main Market-listed companies, 852 were registered in the UK, Channel Islands or Isle of Man, and 107 were registered in another EEA country (LSE, “Company List”, 31 December 2018, available at https://www.londonstockexchange.com/statistics/companies-and-issuers/companies-and-issuers.htm).

184 Barclay, M. and Holderness, C., “Private Benefits from Control of Public Corporations” (1989) 25 Journal of Financial Economics 371, 380CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Gilson, “Controlling Shareholders and Corporate Governance”, p. 1672.

185 Empirically, see Bauguess et al., “Shareholder Diversification”, p. 1249; Smart and Zutter, “Control as a Motivation”, p. 102.

186 Amoako-Adu, B., Baulkaran, V. and Smith, B., “Dual Class Discount, and the Channels of Extraction of Private Benefits” in Ferris, S., John, K. and Makhija, A. (eds.), Advances in Financial Economics Vol. 16 (Bingley 2013) 165, 195CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

187 Outrage costs and constraints” as coined by Bebchuk, L. and Fried, J. (eds.), Pay Without Performance (Cambridge 2004), 5Google Scholar.

188 CA 2006, ss. 420, 421.

189 CA 2006, s. 430.

190 CA 2006, ss. 439, 439A.

191 E.g., in 2016, the remuneration committee of BP plc used its discretion to reduce performance-related pay to which the CEO was otherwise entitled to avoid “formulaic outcomes”, after the company had lost the advisory vote on the implementation of the remuneration policy in the previous financial year; and at Persimmon plc, in 2017 the chair, and in 2018 the CEO, resigned after shareholder and public outrage towards the CEO's £110 million pay package.

192 Potentially in a similar manner as currently exists under the Listing Rules with respect to the election of independent non-executive directors of premium-listed companies in the presence of a controlling shareholder (LR 9.2.2ER).

193 Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act (Pub. L. 111–203 (2010)), Subtitle E of Title IX.

194 E.g., between 2001 and 2007, the average CEO compensation for dual-class firms was $5.2 million compared to $4.7 million for matched OSOV-firms (Amoako-Adu et al., “Dual Class Discount”, p. 183). Although, Masulis, R., Wang, C. and Xie, F., “Agency Problems at Dual-Class Companies” (2009) 64 Journal of Finance 1697, 1707CrossRefGoogle Scholar, found more striking results showing that average US CEO total compensation between 1995 and 2003 increased by $1.054 million as the ratio of insiders’ voting rights to cash-flow rights rose by one standard deviation, this should be considered in the context of average market capitalisation – in 2017, the average market capitalisation of a US-listed company was $7.3 billion, and even in 2001, the average was above $3 billion (Ernst & Young, Looking Behind the Declining Number of Public Companies, May 2017, pp. 3, 2).

195 Proxy Statement Schedule 14(A) of Alphabet Inc., 30 April 2019, 43.

196 E.g., all shares could be treated on a OSOV basis for the purposes of “say-on-pay” votes. However, dual-class firm controllers will be partly adopting the structure to insulate themselves from exactly such forms of shareholder pressure.

197 The author is conducting further research on this topic.

Figure 0

Table 1 Large (over £100m) acquisitions of UK private technology companies between 2014 and mid-2019

Figure 1

Table 2 Large (over £100m) foreign buy-outs of UK-listed technology companies between 2014 and mid-2019